Final Report
Prepared by
Merger review in
digital and technology markets:
Insights from national case law
Viktoria H.S.E. Robertson
Competition
EUROPEAN COMMISSION
Directorate-General for Competition
E-mail: comp-publications@ec.europa.eu
European Commission
B-1049 Brussels
[Catalogue number]
Merger review in
digital and technology markets:
Insights from national case law
Final report
(17 October 2022)
LEGAL NOTICE
The information and views set out in this report are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily
reflect the official opinion of the Commission. The Commission does not guarantee the accuracy of the
data included in this study. Neither the Commission nor any person acting on the Commission’s behalf
may be held responsible for the use which may be made of the information contained therein.
More information on the European Union: https://european-union.europa.eu/index_en
Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union, 2022
Catalogue number: KD-04-22-317-EN-N
ISBN: 978-92-76-60451-8
DOI: 10.2763/847448
© European Union, 2022
Reproduction is authorised provided the source is acknowledged.
The reproduction of the artistic material contained therein is prohibited.
Europe Direct is a service to help you find answers
to your questions about the European Union.
Freephone number (*):
00 800 6 7 8 9 10 11
(*) The information given is free, as are most calls (though some
operators, phone boxes or hotels may charge you).
Author: Viktoria H.S.E. Robertson
Professor and Head of the Competition Law and Digitalization Group at the Vienna University of
Economics and Business; Professor of International Antitrust Law at the University of Graz
Abstract
This Report contains an independent expert study on the national assessment of horizontal
and non-horizontal mergers in digital and technology markets. It analyses the substantive
assessment of digital and technology merger cases from selected EU Member States as
well as from a former Member State, the United Kingdom, against the background of the
growing concern about the market power of Big Tech. The Report identifies theories of
harm repeatedly relied upon in the national decisional practice, sets out remedies adopted
to address these competition concerns, and draws conclusions therefrom for merger
assessment in Europe.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
2
Table of contents
Executive summary .......................................................................................................... 5
I. Introduction: Purpose and organisation of the Report ........................................ 11
II. Case selection ......................................................................................................... 14
1. Legal background ......................................................................................................... 14
2. Jurisdictions covered by the analysis .......................................................................... 14
3. Case selection criteria ................................................................................................... 15
4. Identification and analysis of cases .............................................................................. 18
III. A short primer on the law and economics applicable to digital merger control . 20
1. The nature of digital mergers....................................................................................... 20
2. Digital mergers and conglomerate theories of harm ................................................. 21
3. Digital mergers and digital ecosystems ....................................................................... 24
4. The appropriate legal framework for assessing digital mergers .............................. 25
IV. National digital and technology merger cases in selected EU Member States
and the UK: Quantitative insights ....................................................................... 28
V. National digital and technology merger cases in selected EU Member States
and the UK: Qualitative insights and mapping the theories of harm ................ 34
1. Horizontal theories of harm ......................................................................................... 34
i. Non-coordinated effects: Loss of an actual competitor.............................................. 35
a. Specificities of the theory of harm ................................................................................ 35
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers ................... 35
c. Discussion ......................................................................................................................... 42
ii. Coordinated effects ..................................................................................................... 45
a. Specificities of the theory of harm ................................................................................ 45
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers ................... 45
c. Discussion ......................................................................................................................... 45
iii. Loss of a potential competitor non-coordinated or coordinated effects ................. 46
a. Specificities of the theory of harm ................................................................................ 46
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers ................... 46
c. Discussion ......................................................................................................................... 49
iv. Other horizontal theories of harm .............................................................................. 50
a. Specificities of the theory of harm ................................................................................ 50
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers ................... 50
c. Discussion ......................................................................................................................... 52
2. Vertical theories of harm .............................................................................................. 52
i. Non-coordinated effects: Input foreclosure ................................................................ 53
a. Specificities of the theory of harm ................................................................................ 53
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers ................... 53
c. Discussion ......................................................................................................................... 59
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
3
ii. Non-coordinated effects: Customer foreclosure......................................................... 61
a. Specificities of the theory of harm ................................................................................ 61
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers ................... 61
c. Discussion ......................................................................................................................... 63
iii. Other non-coordinated effects .................................................................................... 64
a. Specificities of the theory of harm ................................................................................ 64
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers ................... 64
c. Discussion ......................................................................................................................... 65
iv. Coordinated effects ..................................................................................................... 66
a. Specificities of the theory of harm ................................................................................ 66
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers ................... 66
3. Conglomerate theories of harm ................................................................................... 66
i. Non-coordinated effects: Foreclosure ........................................................................ 66
a. Specificities of the theory of harm ................................................................................ 66
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers ................... 67
c. Discussion ......................................................................................................................... 72
ii. Coordinated effects ..................................................................................................... 73
a. Specificities of the theory of harm ................................................................................ 73
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers ................... 73
iii. Other effects ................................................................................................................ 73
a. Specificities of the theory of harm ................................................................................ 73
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers ................... 73
c. Discussion ......................................................................................................................... 74
4. Theories of harm largely absent in the decisional practice ....................................... 74
i. Building and reinforcing a digital ecosystem ............................................................. 74
ii. Data advantages ......................................................................................................... 77
iii. Concentration and abuse of dominance ..................................................................... 79
5. Remedies ........................................................................................................................ 80
i. Structural remedies..................................................................................................... 81
ii. Behavioural remedies: access and interoperability ................................................... 82
iii. Further types of behavioural remedies ....................................................................... 83
iv. Discussion ................................................................................................................... 86
6. Prohibition decisions ..................................................................................................... 88
VI. Conclusions ............................................................................................................ 91
References ...................................................................................................................... 94
Table of legislation and soft law documents ................................................................. 99
European Union legislation ................................................................................................... 99
National legislation ................................................................................................................ 99
European Union soft law ....................................................................................................... 99
National soft law .................................................................................................................. 100
Table of cases ............................................................................................................... 101
Australia ............................................................................................................................... 101
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
4
Austria .................................................................................................................................. 101
Bulgaria ................................................................................................................................ 101
China ..................................................................................................................................... 101
Cyprus ................................................................................................................................... 101
Czechia .................................................................................................................................. 101
Estonia .................................................................................................................................. 102
European Union ................................................................................................................... 102
France ................................................................................................................................... 103
Germany ............................................................................................................................... 103
Greece ................................................................................................................................... 104
Hungary ................................................................................................................................ 104
Ireland ................................................................................................................................... 104
Italy ....................................................................................................................................... 105
Malta ..................................................................................................................................... 105
Netherlands .......................................................................................................................... 105
Poland ................................................................................................................................... 105
Portugal ................................................................................................................................ 105
Romania ................................................................................................................................ 105
Singapore .............................................................................................................................. 106
Slovenia ................................................................................................................................. 106
Spain ..................................................................................................................................... 106
Sweden .................................................................................................................................. 106
United Kingdom ................................................................................................................... 106
United States ........................................................................................................................ 108
List of figures ............................................................................................................... 109
Annex I: 97 national cases on digital and technology mergers, coded by outcome . 110
Annex II: 69 particularly relevant national cases on digital and technology
mergers, coded by theories of harm ................................................................... 115
Annex III: Concise summaries of 69 national cases on digital and technology
mergers ............................................................................................................... 120
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
5
Executive summary
In the present Report, I provide an independent expert study on the assessment of
horizontal and non-horizontal mergers in digital and technology markets, commissioned
by the European Commission. I analyse the substantive assessment of digital and
technology merger cases from selected European Union (EU) Member States as well as
from a former Member State, the United Kingdom, against the background of the growing
concern about the market power of Big Tech. Due to the one-stop-shop principle
contained in the EU Merger Regulation 139/2004, it is possible that national merger
control and EU merger control may not be as aligned as the law and practice on anti-
competitive agreements and abuses of a dominant position. While this can give rise to
inconsistencies, it can also represent a learning opportunity to allow for best practices on
digital mergers to emerge.
I organised the Report as follows: After an introduction setting out the purpose of the
Report (Chapter I), I provide an insight into the way in which the national cases that
constitute the basis for this Report were selected (Chapter II). Then, I give a brief
overview of the law and economics applicable to digital mergers (Chapter III). Chapter
IV contains first quantitative insights from the analysis of 97 national cases. Chapter V
contains the main body of the Report and provides qualitative insights from the in-depth
analysis of 69 national digital and technology merger cases in selected EU Member States
and the United Kingdom. It focuses on theories of harm relied upon and remedies adopted
by national competition authorities. Chapter VI concludes. The Annex contains a list of
all 97 national cases analysed for this Report (Annex I), as well as a detailed coding of
69 national cases as concerns the theories of harm addressed and the remedies adopted
(Annex II). Annex III contains concise case summaries of the 69 national cases on digital
and technology mergers.
The present Report is based on a selected number of national merger cases in digital
and technology markets. Case selection criteria included the jurisdiction in which the
case was decided (EU Member State or United Kingdom), the relevant timeframe (1
January 2015 to 31 December 2021), and the digital or technology nature of the case. In
order to identify the latter, criteria such as lists of digital companies, NACE codes and
the relevant market of a case were relied upon (Chapter II).
While digital mergers are often associated with Big Tech, the digitalisation of all
aspects of business and private life has meant that digital markets and digital mergers
have proliferated. Digital platforms are building ever more comprehensive digital
ecosystems, and the question arises whether merger control is flexible enough to meet the
new anti-competitive threats that digital mergers bring with them (Chapter III).
97 national digital and technology merger cases from 19 different EU Member States
and the United Kingdom, from the time period 1 January 2015 to 31 December 2021,
were assessed for the present Report (Chapter IV). A number of quantitative insights
can be drawn from this analysis. Of the 97 cases identified, 74 were unconditionally
cleared (65 in phase 1, 9 in phase 2), 15 cases were cleared subject to conditions (10 in
phase 1, 5 in phase 2), 6 concentrations were prohibited, one was withdrawn following
the national competition authority voicing serious competition concerns, and in one case
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
6
merger control was found to be inapplicable. The ratio of unconditionally cleared to
conditionally cleared or prohibited mergers already provides a first indication that most
digital and technology mergers are understood to be unproblematic by national
competition authorities.
Of the 97 cases identified, 69 cases were selected for an in-depth analysis including
all cases that were conditionally cleared, reached phase 2, or were prohibited or
withdrawn. Based on their relevance for this Report, a number of unconditionally cleared
cases were also included in this sample. It is notable that of the 69 mergers, 30 cases (i.e.,
over 40%) exclusively assessed horizontal effects. A further 18 cases assessed horizontal
and vertical effects, while 5 cases only assessed vertical effects. 8 cases assessed
horizontal and conglomerate effects, 3 cases assessed vertical and conglomerate effects,
and 2 cases only assessed conglomerate effects. A total of 3 cases assessed horizontal,
vertical and conglomerate effects.
67%
9%
11%
5%
6%
1%
1%
97 national merger cases, by outcome
Unconditional clearance in phase 1
Unconditional clearance in phase 2
Conditional clearance in phase 1
Conditional clearance in phase 2
Prohibition
Withdrawal
Non-applicability
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
7
Of the 6 cases in which concentrations were prohibited, all cases assessed horizontal
effects, and in addition, 4 assessed vertical foreclosure effects. None assessed any
conglomerate effects. Of the 16 cases in which concentrations were conditionally cleared,
8 only related to horizontal effects and 2 only related to vertical effects. 2 further cases
related to horizontal and vertical effects, while 2 cases only related to vertical and
conglomerate effects. 2 conditional clearances related to conglomerate effects only. These
quantitative insights highlight that while conglomerate theories of harm have taken centre
stage in discussions about digital mergers, the merger practice across the European Union
is either still lagging behind these theoretical insights or horizontal effects continue to
represent the number one concern in digital merger control.
69 national digital and technology merger cases in selected EU Member States and the
United Kingdom were relied upon for an in-depth, qualitative analysis. These cases
cover 17 different jurisdictions. To allow for more detailed insights, theories of harm were
categorised along the lines of horizontal effects (loss of an actual competitor, loss of a
potential competitor, coordinated effects, other horizontal effects), vertical effects (input
foreclosure, customer foreclosure, other vertical non-coordinated effects, coordinated
effects) and conglomerate effects (foreclosure, other conglomerate effects). It was notable
that a total of 51 cases raised issues related to the loss of an actual competitor on the
relevant market, and 9 of these mergers were cleared subject to conditions, 4 were
prohibited and one was withdrawn. Where the clearance of a merger was subject to
commitments, the latter sometimes played a role again in later cases (Just Eat/La Nevera
Roja, ES 2016). It was seen how digital markets can differ from country to country,
depending on the success of individual national platforms (e.g., see the analysis of
eBay/Adevinta in the UK, Germany and Austria, all 2021). The presence of Big Tech
companies such as Alphabet, Amazon, Apple, Meta or Microsoft was repeatedly held to
constitute an important factor when concluding that a digital acquisition by a non-Big
Tech company did not raise competition concerns. In already concentrated online
markets, NCAs would sometimes welcome a merger because it could mean that the
market would not tip. Multi-homing by users or customers was equally seen as a ‘natural’
remedy against market tipping.
The loss of a potential competitor was brought up in 6 cases, of which 5 came from
the UK. Recently, this theory of harm was tested both before Austrian and UK courts in
the merger of Meta/Giphy (AT 2022; UK 2022). The concern here was that the acquisition
could stifle potential competition between Meta (formerly: Facebook) and GIF library
Giphy for advertising clients, as Giphy had rolled out a promising advertising service
prior to the acquisition that allowed it to monetise its services and that could have
competed with Meta’s display advertising. While the UK Competition Appeal Tribunal
upheld the national authority’s prohibition of the merger on substance, the Austrian
Supreme Cartel Court upheld the Austrian Cartel Court’s conditional clearance of the
same concentration.
Input foreclosure was the most relied-upon vertical theory of harm in all cases
analysed. 27 cases related to this type of concern. The Swedish Swedbank
Franchise/Svensk Fastighetsförmedling case (SE 2014) about online property portal
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
8
Hemnet led to the first Swedish prohibition of a merger, also due to a concern about input
foreclosure. The Slovenian merger of Sully System/CENEJE (SI 2018) was only cleared
after commitments, as the authority was concerned that there might be input foreclosure
related to both online advertising through search engines and online price comparison. In
several cases, however, the national competition authorities concluded that vertical input
foreclosure was not a credible theory of harm based on the low market shares post-merger
and/or the competitive constraint expected from competitors that would remain active on
either the upstream or the downstream markets.
Customer foreclosure was assessed in 11 national cases. In CTS Eventim/Four Artists
(DE 2017), the German authority prohibited an acquisition based on the finding that it
would (also) have further strengthened customer foreclosure. In a further case involving
CTS Eventim (AT 2019), the Austrian authority was concerned that, post-merger, the
merged entity could engage in customer foreclosure by providing its ticketing services at
above market prices to companies outside of the CTS Eventim group. This concentration
was cleared subject to conditions. The presence of a sufficient number of competitors on
one of the relevant markets was regularly seen as a factor that could mitigate vertical
effects. Low turnover was also sometimes seen as hindering a company’s ability to
foreclose competitors.
In terms of other vertical theories of harm, the Czech authority was concerned that,
post-merger, comparison shopping site Heureka.cz could ask Rockaway’s online shops
to collect excessive amounts of data about their users, data that could then be used in the
interest of Rockaway Capital’s businesses (Rockaway Capital/Heureka, CZ 2016). In a
number of cases, the national authority also considered whether the acquirer would have
access to commercially sensitive information about competitors post-merger
(esure/Gocompare.com case, UK 2015; Sully System/CENEJE, SI 2018; Sanoma/Iddink,
NL 2019; Uber International/GPC Computer Software, UK 2021).
Conglomerate foreclosure was by far the most frequently relied-upon conglomerate
theory of harm, assessed in 15 cases. In Rockaway Capital/Heureka, the Czech authority
was concerned that, post-merger, comparison shopping site Heureka.cz would give
preferential treatment to online businesses already controlled by the acquirer (CZ 2016).
Bundling strategies combining the previously separate offerings of target and acquirer
were also regularly assessed, with a view to identifying whether or not this type of
strategy would actually be beneficial to the market. In one case, the waning importance
of an offline market meant that no harm was seen in a likely online/offline bundle (Axel
Springer/Concept Multimédia, FR 2018). Advanced Micro Devices/Xilinx (UK 2021) was
one of only two cases that exclusively focused on conglomerate effects, with no
conditions imposed. In Delivery Hero (EL 2022), an acquisition in the area of online food
platforms was only cleared subject to conditions based on conglomerate competition
concerns.
Notably, any detailed consideration of digital ecosystems remained largely absent
from the theories of harm examined in the 69 merger cases that were analysed in-depth.
While Meta/Kustomer (DE 2022) outlined conglomerate concerns related to the
strengthening of a digital ecosystem through the acquisition, the national authority
ultimately cleared it unconditionally. Competition concerns in today’s digital markets
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
9
may arise not so much because of well-defined competition issues arising in specific
relevant markets, and perhaps not even because of every single small merger that is
completed. Instead, competition concerns related to digital platforms can arise from the
combined effects of these mergers in multi-sided markets with strong network effects,
with a great many markets concerned. Furthermore, data advantages that are acquired
through a merger also require careful consideration. Data capabilities relating to both
personal data and non-personal data are central to success in many digital markets and
can therefore also represent a significant competitive advantage to digital platforms
operating across a diverse set of markets. In recent years, multiple aspects of access and
use of data as well as of data integration and data protection have come into play in digital
merger cases. What matters now is to consolidate the lessons learned from these analyses
in order to develop a coherent approach to assessing data aspects in digital merger control.
Finally, a more coherent interaction between merger control and abuse of dominance
in digital markets also seems like a promising avenue in order to make competition law
an even more useful tool to grasp competition concerns in digital mergers.
15 national cases involved remedies that addressed the competition concerns raised
by the national competition authority. A small number of national cases included
structural remedies, namely the divestiture of parts of a business (e.g., Dante
International/PC Garage, CZ 2016; Pug/StubHub, UK 2021; Adevinta/eBay Classifieds
Group, UK 2021). In terms of behavioural remedies, these were found much more often.
First of all, in terms of access and interoperability remedies, such were required in a
number of cases (e.g., CTS Eventim/Barracuda Holding, AT 2019; Sanoma/Iddink, NL
2019; NS Groep/Pon Netherlands, NL 2020; Meta/Giphy, AT 2022). Licenses were also
among proposed remedies that could be categorised as a sort of access remedy
(Schibsted/Milanuncios, ES 2014; not accepted in Blocket/Hemnet, SE 2016). Secondly,
a broad range of other types of behavioural remedies could be observed, including the
promise not to impose exclusivity obligations on trading partners (e.g., Just Eat/La
Nevera Roja, ES 2016; CTS Eventim/Barracuda Holding, AT 2019;
Glovoappro/Foodpanda, RO 2021), the promise not to gather excessive data (e.g.,
Rockaway Capital/Heureka, CZ 2016), or the commitment not to discriminate between
trading partners (e.g., Sully System/CENEJE, SI 2018; Meta/Giphy, AT 2022). Only two
cases on conglomerate concerns included a remedy; in Rockaway Capital/Heureka (CZ
2016), the acquirer proposed to include a clear link between Heureka.cz and other
Rockaway Capital activities on the website, and committed not to discriminate against
independent sellers. In Delivery Hero (EL 2022), the acquirer committed not to bundle
food-ordering services with restaurant-reservation, and not to use data from a platform
for targeted advertising on another absent the users’ consent.
A total of 6 concentrations were prohibited. Overall, the picture on prohibitions of
digital mergers is rather straightforward: apart from the special Hungarian case based on
media law (Magyar RTL Televízió/Central Digitális Média, HU 2017), all prohibitions
related to the loss of an actual competitor (plus, in one case, vertical customer foreclosure)
or the loss of a potential competitor plus vertical input foreclosure. This shows that
horizontal theories of harm continue to be regarded as the most credible threat to
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
10
competitive markets, also in digital environments, despite topical research showing that
conglomerate (and vertical) effects resulting from digital mergers merit closer scrutiny.
In Europe, national merger cases in digital and technology markets have proliferated
in recent years. The comparison carried out in this Report has found that the analysis by
national competition authorities still very much runs along the traditional lines of
horizontal vertical conglomerate effects. For the future, it could be useful to frame
theories of harm more in line with the complex and interrelated market realities that we
find in the digital environment, and thereby obtain a clearer view of the three issues that
have, so far, only been assessed in a smaller number of national cases: digital ecosystems,
data advantages and the interaction of mergers with abuse of dominance. A review of the
national decisional practice on digital and technology mergers against the background of
the European decisional practice, such as the one carried out in this Report, may be a good
starting point for further developing merger control in Europe and beyond in order to
enable it to fully capture the anti-competitive effects that certain digital mergers are
capable of producing.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
11
I. Introduction: Purpose and organisation of the Report
(1) The present Report reviews digital
1
and technology
2
mergers in selected European
Union (EU) Member States and in the former EU Member State of the United
Kingdom and assesses the theories of harm that were identified by national
competition authorities (NCAs) in such cases. By focusing on the developing
decisional practice in digital and technology mergers at the national level, the
Report intends to provide a broad basis for the Commission’s reflection in relation
to the review of digital and technology mergers.
(2) The Call for Tenders requires that the expert advice should cover the following
issues:
(i) an identification of theories of harm devised in the decisional practice
and the concrete risks identified by NCAs,
3
and
(ii) an identification of remedies adopted by NCAs to solve these competition
concerns.
(3) Theories of harm are here understood as ‘hypothes[e]s about how the process of
rivalry could be harmed as a result of a merger’.
4
Depending on the type of merger
under investigation, a theory of harm may relate to horizontal effects, vertical
effects or conglomerate effects.
(4) I was commissioned by the European Commission to provide the expert Report
sought by its Call for Tenders, and hereby present my Report.
(5) In preparation of this Report, I have reviewed:
the decisional practice on digital and technology mergers of NCAs of selected
Member States of the EU as well as of the United Kingdom as a former EU
Member State,
the decisional practice of the European Commission on digital and technology
mergers,
relevant guidance on digital and technology mergers, and
relevant academic literature.
(6) Based on a review of hundreds of cases from all EU jurisdictions plus the United
Kingdom, I compiled a sample of 97 national merger cases from 19 jurisdictions
that I coded by outcome. Of these, I ultimately selected a sample of 69 national
cases from 17 jurisdictions for an in-depth analysis (for case selection criteria, see
Chapter II below). The Report categorises these national cases based on the types
of competition concerns that arose in digital and technology mergers
(‘mapping’). For each type of concern, I provide a general overview of the
relevant issues, give a quantitative assessment of national cases relating to the type
of concern, and then provide a more detailed qualitative analysis. In terms of the
1
For a definition of what includes digital mergers, see para (19) below.
2
For a definition of what includes technology mergers, see para (20) below.
3
The term NCA is here understood within the meaning of Article 35 of Regulation 1/2003, meaning that
certain national courts (eg, the Austrian Cartel Court) will also be regarded as NCAs for the purposes of
this Report.
4
Competition & Markets Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines (CMA129, 18 March 2021) para 2.11.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
12
qualitative analyses, I describe the concrete conduct, strategy or behaviour
concerned in the most relevant national cases identified, and include references to
the relevant case law and decisional practice from a comparative perspective. In
addition, for each issue and relevant illustrative case, I provide an indication of
the outcome of the merger review conducted at the national level. Competition
concerns identified by NCAs are examined and put into the context of both the
European Commission’s decisional practice and academic research on digital and
technology mergers.
(7) Where commitments or other remedies were adopted or imposed, I describe,
where available, the type of measure adopted, the main terms, ancillary
requirements, enforcement mechanisms, and duration.
(8) Concerning theories of harm, the Call for Tenders provides that the Report should
include both horizontal and non-horizontal theories of harm. As regards horizontal
theories of harm, a focus of the Report lies on identifying whether NCAs
assessment of the mergers included competitive concerns because the buyer
viewed the target as a potential threat and bought it to either discontinue the
target’s innovation (‘killer acquisition’)
5
or incorporate it into its own portfolio
(‘zombie acquisition’). It is also assessed to what extent the importance of
acquiring data through a merger was considered by NCAs.
(9) As regards non-horizontal theories of harm, the focus of the Report lies on
identifying whether NCAs’ assessment of the mergers included competitive
concerns because of vertical or conglomerate effects that the mergers could entail.
Here, possibilities include the risk of foreclosing (potential) competitors in
various ways, eg through the degradation of interoperability or refusal to supply.
(10) The Report is structured as follows: Chapter II gives an insight into the way in
which national cases were selected, as these constitute the basis for this Report.
Chapter III sets the scene by providing an overview of the law and economics
applicable to digital mergers as discussed in the academic literature. Chapter IV
contains quantitative insights from the analysis of 97 national digital and
technology merger cases in selected Member States of the EU and in the United
Kingdom. Chapter V contains qualitative insights from the analysis of 69 national
digital and technology merger cases in selected Member States of the EU and in
the United Kingdom. It discusses various theories of harm and how they were
applied in national cases, and links them to the European decisional practice.
Chapter VI provides concise conclusions.
(11) In Annex I, I provide an overview of those 97 national cases that I consider
particularly instructive for this Report, coded by the outcome of the case. In Annex
II, I provide a list of those 69 cases that I found to be most relevant for the present
Report based on the case selection criteria (Chapter II), and each case is coded
5
On this term, which was coined in relation to mergers and acquisitions in the pharmaceutical industry, see
Colleen Cunningham, Florian Ederer & Song Ma, ‘Killer Acquisitions’ (2021) 129 Journal of Political
Economy 649.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
13
based on the theories of harm employed in that decision. In Annex III, I provide
concise summaries of those 69 merger cases.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
14
II. Case selection
(12) The following sets out the way in which national cases were selected for this
Report.
1. Legal background
(13) Based on the one-stop-shop principle of the European Union Merger Regulation
(Article 21 EUMR),
6
EU merger control under the auspices of the European
Commission exclusively applies to mergers that come within the jurisdiction of
the EUMR. Article 3 EUMR foresees turnover-based thresholds to decide on the
Commission’s jurisdiction.
(14) Under Article 4 para 5 EUMR, merging parties whose merger would be notifiable
in at least three Member States may make a reasoned submission asking the
Commission to review the merger. This has occurred in digital mergers.
7
Referrals
from NCAs (Article 22 EUMR) can equally lead to the European Commission
assessing a merger, as has occurred in digital markets.
8
In the case of an Article
22 EUMR referral, the Commission can review the merger with respect to the
markets of the referring Member State(s).
9
(15) While the EUMR relies on different turnover thresholds in order to separate
notifiable mergers from those that do not come within the purview of EU merger
control, some national merger control regimes such as the Austrian
10
and
German
11
one have introduced additional transaction value-based thresholds
that require the notification of a merger if the acquirer’s payment for the target
exceeds a certain amount.
2. Jurisdictions covered by the analysis
(16) The literature on digital and technology mergers is frequently focused on cases at
the level of the European Union,
12
or compares the EU and US approaches to
digital mergers.
13
While this focus is justified based on the overall importance of
6
Council Regulation (EC) No 139/2004 of 20 January 2004 on the control of concentrations between
undertakings (EUMR) [2004] OJ L24/1.
7
Eg, see European Commission Decision of 3 October 2014, COMP/M.7217 Facebook/WhatsApp.
8
Although this is a rare occurrence, the recent Meta/Kustomer merger was assessed in parallel by the
European Commission, following an Article 22 EUMR referral from Austria, and by the German
Bundeskartellamt; see European Commission Decision of 27 January 2022, M.10262 Meta/Kustomer;
Bundeskartellamt, Meta/Kustomer (B6-21/22, 11 February 2022).
9
See European Commission, Commission Guidance on the application of the referral mechanism set out
in Article 22 of the Merger Regulation to certain categories of cases [2021] OJ C113/1, para 11 fn 12.
10
§ 9 para 4 Cartel Act, Austrian Federal Law Gazette I 61/2005 as amended.
11
§ 35 para 1a Act against Restraints of Competition, German Federal Law Gazette I 2013/1750 as
amended.
12
Marc Bourreau and Alexandre de Streel, ‘Digital Conglomerates and EU Competition Policy’ (CERRE
Report, March 2019); Tristan Lécuyer, ‘Digital Conglomerates and Killer Acquisitions A Discussion of
the Competitive Effects of Start-Up Acquisitions by Digital Platforms’ (N° 1-2020) Concurrences 42.
13
Yong Lim, ‘Tech Wars: Return of the Conglomerate Throwback or Dawn of a New Series for
Competition in the Digital Era?’ (2020) 19 Journal of Korean Law 47, 57 (speaking of ‘data-driven network
effects’). Sometimes, the UK’s approach to digital mergers is incorporated into the analysis: Anne C. Witt,
‘Who’s Afraid of Conglomerate Mergers’ (2022) 67 Antitrust Bulletin 208.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
15
these two jurisdictions, it nevertheless risks overlooking important developments
in national merger control in EU Member States and misses out on obtaining a
broader picture on digital merger control. With the present Report, I intend to
bridge this gap by analysing digital and technology merger cases from a wider
scope of jurisdictions within the European Union, including the United Kingdom
as a former Member State.
3. Case selection criteria
(17) Cases analysed were chosen based on the following criteria:
(a) the jurisdiction in which the case was decided (EU Member State or United
Kingdom),
(b) the timeframe in which the decision was rendered (1 January 2015 to 31
December 2021), and
(c) the digital or technology nature of the markets analysed in the case.
(18) The timeframe of the Report spans 7 years, from 1 January 2015 to 31 December
2021, with a particular focus on cases emerging over the past five years. This is
due to the fact that digital mergers have proliferated during that time. Furthermore,
the premise is that the most recent cases can give the most profound insights into
adaptations in the substantive merger analysis. A small number of cases were
included that were decided prior to 1 January 2015 or after 31 December 2021,
due to a particular interest in the analysis that was carried out therein.
(19) Digital merger cases can be enormously varied. This is due to several factors.
First of all, a large number of traditional in-person services are moving online.
Second, digital platforms are intensifying their conglomeration strategies,
meaning they are moving into very varied markets ranging from movie production
to restaurant guides. In order to establish which cases should be regarded as
digitaland thus assessed for this Report, a number of selection criteria were
established from multiple angles:
a) Did the case include a well-known digital platform operator? Companies in
this category included Adobe, Alphabet, Airbnb, Amazon, Apple, Activision
Blizzard, Booking.com, Deliveroo, eBay, Facebook, Google, Intuit, Meta,
Microsoft, Netflix, PayPal, Rakuten, Salesforce, Spotify, and Uber. In order
to compile this list, both the Forbes Top 100 Digital Companies list
14
and
European case law
15
were relied upon. The focus was on digital services
14
Forbes, Top 100 Digital Companies <https://www.forbes.com/top-digital-companies/list/3/#tab:rank>.
Telecoms were excluded for the purposes of this Report.
15
In particular, decisions related to Big Tech were regarded as relevant. Big Tech is here understood as the
GAFAM companies, ie Google (Alphabet), Apple, Amazon, Facebook (Meta) and Microsoft.
Meta (formerly Facebook): European Commission Decision of 27 January 2022, M.10262
Meta/Kustomer (NACE M.73.1 - Advertising, J.62 - Computer programming, consultancy and related
activities, J.61.9 - Other telecommunications activities, J.63.12 - Web portals; Article 8(2) with conditions
& obligations; referral from Austria, Belgium, Bulgaria, France, Iceland, Italy, Ireland, the Netherlands,
Portugal and Romania Germany carried out its own investigation); European Commission Decision of 3
October 2014, COMP/M.7217 Facebook/WhatsApp (NACE M.73.1 - Advertising, J.62.09 - Other
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
16
rather than hardware, although several digital platform providers have moved
into offering hardware as well. These cases are covered by the ‘technology
category (see below).
b) What was the NACE code related to the case? NACE codes that were
included in the digital category were identified through a comprehensive case
search of all the Big Tech mergers that the European Commission has
investigated to date.
16
NACE codes that were understood to be particularly
relevant included web portals, computer programming activities, data
information technology and computer service activities, J.61.9 - Other telecommunications activities;
Article 6(1)(b) Non-opposition; assessed under Article 4(5) EUMR).
Alphabet (formerly Google): European Commission Decision of 17 December 2020, M.9660
Google/Fitbit (NACE J.62.01 - Computer programming activities, C.26.4 - Manufacture of consumer
electronics, J.58.2 - Software publishing, J.63.12 - Web portals; Art. 8(2) with conditions & obligations);
European Commission Decision of 23 February 2016, M.7813 Sanofi/Google/DMI JV (NACE C.21 -
Manufacture of basic pharmaceutical products and pharmaceutical preparations, C.32.5 - Manufacture of
medical and dental instruments and supplies, Q.86.9 - Other human health activities; Article 6(1)(b) Non-
opposition); European Commission Decision of 13 February 2012, COMP/M.6381 Google/Motorola
Mobility (NACE C.26.30 - Manufacture of communication equipment, J.61 - Telecommunications, J.61.20
- Wireless telecommunications activities; Article 6(1)(b) Non-opposition); European Commission Decision
of 11 March 2008, COMP/M.4731 Google/DoubleClick (NACE M.73.1 Advertising; Article 8(1)
Compatibility).
Apple: European Commission Decision of 6 September 2018, M.8788 Apple/Shazam (NACE M.73.1
Advertising, J.62 - Computer programming, consultancy and related activities, J.63.1 - Data processing,
hosting and related activities, web portals, J.63 - Information service activities; Article 8(1) Compatibility;
referral from Austria, France, Iceland, Italy, Norway, Spain and Sweden); European Commission Decision
of 25 July 2014, COMP/M.7290 Apple/Beats (NACE C.26.4 - Manufacture of consumer electronics,
J.58.29 - Other software publishing; Article 6(1)(b) Non-opposition).
Microsoft: European Commission Decision of 21 December 2021, M.10290 Microsoft/Nuance (NACE
J.62 - Computer programming, consultancy and related activities; Article 6(1)(b) Non-opposition);
European Commission Decision of 5 March 2021, M.10001 Microsoft/Zenimax (NACE J.58.21 -
Publishing of computer games; Article 6(1)(b) Non-opposition); European Commission Decision of 19
October 2018, M.8994 Microsoft/GitHub (NACE J.62.01 - Computer programming activities, J.63.1 -
Data processing, hosting and related activities, web portals; Article 6(1)(b) Non-opposition); European
Commission Decision of 6 December 2016, M.8124 Microsoft/LinkedIn (NACE J.62 - Computer
programming, consultancy and related activities, J.63.12 - Web portals; Article 6(1)(b) with conditions &
obligations); European Commission Decision of 4 December 2012, COMP/M.7047 Microsoft/Nokia
(NACE C.26.3 - Manufacture of communication equipment; Article 6(1)(b) Non-opposition); European
Commission Decision of 10 February 2012, COMP/M.6474 GE/Microsoft/JV (NACE J.62 - Computer
programming, consultancy and related activities; Article 6(1)(b) Non-opposition); European Commission
Decision of 7 October 2011, COMP/M.6281 Microsoft/Skype (NACE J.63 - Information service
activities; Article 6(1)(b) Non-opposition) (upheld in Case T-79/12 Cisco Systems and Messagenet v
Commission, ECLI:EU:T:2013:635); European Commission Decision of 18 February 2010,
COMP/M.5727 Microsoft/Yahoo! Search Business (NACE J.63.1 - Data processing, hosting and related
activities, web portals; Article 6(1)(b) Non-opposition). Most recently, Microsoft has announced its
acquisition of game developer Activision Blizzard, and a merger filing can be expected in this case: Pietro
Lombardi and Samuel Stolton, ‘Microsoft heads for second big EU showdown this time over gaming’
Politico (24 January 2022) <https://www.politico.eu/article/microsoft-activision-eu-showdown-video-
game/>.
Amazon: European Commission Decision of 15 March 2022, M.10349 Amazon/MGM (NACE J.59 -
Motion picture, video and television programme production, sound recording and music publishing
activities; Article 6(1)(b) Non-opposition).
16
On these, see footnote 15 above.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
17
processing, hosting and related activities and ‘computer programming,
consultancy and related activities’.
17
c) Was the relevant market relied upon in the case related to digital markets?
The following keywords were used as an indicator: AdTech, API, app,
application, cloud computing, display advertising, internet, Internet of
Things/IoT, marketplace, online advertising, online betting/gaming, online
communication services, personalised advertising, platform, price
comparison, software, wearable.
d) Exclusion criteria: Cases involving traditional media were excluded, unless
they primarily related to social media. Broadcasting and pay-TV cases were
also excluded.
(20) Technology merger cases were included as an additional category of cases. The
following selection criteria were established from multiple angles:
a) Did the case include a well-known high-tech company? Companies in this
category included AMD, Broadcom, Cisco, Dell, Ericsson, Huawei, IBM,
Intel, Lenovo, LG Electronics, NEC, Nintendo, Nvidia, NXP
Semiconductors, ON Semiconductor, Oracle, Qualcomm, Samsung, SAP,
Taiwan Semiconductor, Xiaomi, and ZTE. In order to compile this list, the
Forbes Top 100 Digital Companies list,
18
the Thomson Reuters Top 100
Global Tech Leaders list
19
and European case law
20
were relied upon. The
17
In particular, the following NACE codes were identified (if appearing in more than one case, the NACE
code is set in italics):
C.21 - Manufacture of basic pharmaceutical products and pharmaceutical preparations
C.26.3 - Manufacture of communication equipment
C.26.4 - Manufacture of consumer electronics
C.32.5 - Manufacture of medical and dental instruments and supplies
J.58.2 - Software publishing
J.58.21 - Publishing of computer games
J.58.29 - Other software publishing
J.59 - Motion picture video and television programme production, sound recording and music publishing
activities
J.61 - Telecommunications
J.61.20 - Wireless telecommunications activities
J.61.9 - Other telecommunications activities
J.62 - Computer programming, consultancy and related activities
J.62.01 - Computer programming activities
J.62.09 - Other information technology and computer service activities
J.63 - Information service activities
J.63.1 - Data processing, hosting and related activities, web portals
J.63.12 - Web portals
M.73.1 - Advertising
Q.86.9 - Other human health activities
18
Forbes, Top 100 Digital Companies <https://www.forbes.com/top-digital-companies/list/3/#tab:rank>.
19
Thomson Reuters, Top 100 Global Tech Leaders <https://www.thomsonreuters.com/en/products-
services/technology/top-100.html>.
20
AMD: European Commission Decision of 30 June 2021, COMP/M.10097 Advanced Micro
Devices/Xilinx (NACE C.26.1 - Manufacture of electronic components and boards; Article 6(1)(b) Non-
opposition).
Broadcom: European Commission Decision of 23 November 2015, M.7686 Avago/Broadcom (NACE
G.46.52 - Wholesale of electronic and telecommunications equipment and parts, C.26.11 - Manufacture of
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
18
focus was on hardware required for digital services. It is noteworthy that
digital platforms found in the ‘digital’ category are also often producers of
the technology they rely on, meaning they may also be considered high-tech
companies.
b) What was the NACE code related to the case? NACE codes that were
included in the technology category were identified through a case search of
important technology mergers that the European Commission has
investigated to date.
21
NACE codes that were included in the technology
category included manufacture of communication equipment’, ‘manufacture
of consumer electronics’, manufacture of electronic components,
wholesale of electronic and telecommunications equipment and parts and
wholesale of computers, computer peripheral equipment and software.
22
c) Was the relevant market relied upon in the case related to high-tech
markets? The following keywords were used as an indicator: chips, hardware,
patent, and semiconductor.
d) Exclusion criteria: Cases involving technology not directly relevant to
digital markets were excluded. Telecommunications operators were also
excluded.
4. Identification and analysis of cases
(21) Based on the selection and exclusion criteria set out above, a large set of cases
from across EU Member States and from the United Kingdom could be identified
electronic components, N.77.4 - Leasing of intellectual property and similar products, except copyrighted
works; Article 6(1)(b) Non-opposition); European Commission Decision of 12 May 2017, M.8314
Broadcom/Brocade (NACE C.26.3 - Manufacture of communication equipment, C.26.11 - Manufacture of
electronic components; Article 6(1)(b) with conditions & obligations); European Commission Decision of
12 October 2018, M.9054 Broadcom/CA (NACE J.62.01 - Computer programming activities, C.26.11 -
Manufacture of electronic components; Article 6(1)(b) Non-opposition); European Commission Decision
of 30 October 2019, M.9538 Broadcom/Symantec Enterprise Security Business (NACE J.62.01 -
Computer programming activities; Article 6(1)(b) Non-opposition).
Intel: European Commission Decision of 20 May 2021, M.10059 SK Hynix/Intel’s Nano and SSD
Business (NACE C.26.2 - Manufacture of computers and peripheral equipment; Article 6(1)(b) Non-
opposition); European Commission Decision of 14 October 2015, M.7688 Intel/Altera (NACE C.26.1 -
Manufacture of electronic components and boards; Article 6(1)(b) Non-opposition).
Qualcomm: European Commission Decision of 18 January 2018, M.8306 Qualcomm/NXP
Semiconductors (NACE C.26.3 - Manufacture of communication equipment, J.62.09 - Other information
technology and computer service activities; Article 8(2) with conditions & obligations).
21
On these, see footnote 20 above.
22
In particular, the following NACE codes were identified (if appearing in more than one case, the NACE
code is set in italics):
C.26.1 - Manufacture of electronic components and boards
C.26.11 - Manufacture of electronic components
C.26.2 - Manufacture of computers and peripheral equipment
C.26.3 - Manufacture of communication equipment
G.46.52 - Wholesale of electronic and telecommunications equipment and parts
J.62.01 - Computer programming activities
J.62.09 - Other information technology and computer service activities
N.77.4 - Leasing of intellectual property and similar products, except copyrighted works
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
19
based on literature research,
23
database research
24
and outreach to colleagues from
various jurisdictions. This sample was selected after careful consideration of the
selection criteria, of the need to represent a multitude of jurisdictions, of the date
of the decision, of the case’s relevance for digital and technology markets, and of
the Report’s particular interest in cases in which remedies were adopted. From
hundreds of cases reviewed, a sample of 97 cases was derived that were
considered particularly relevant based on the factors set out above, and full text
decisions for all these cases were obtained. All relevant full text decisions are
supplied to the Directorate General for Competition together with this Report. A
list of the 97 NCA decisions identified as particularly relevant can be found in
Annex I. While this list is quite extensive, it can only represent a sample and does
not aim to be comprehensive. Rather, the intention is to represent a wide range of
digital and technology merger cases that showcase the types of cases encountered
in these sectors from a wide range of jurisdictions.
(22) The 97 decisions considered particularly relevant were then coded based on the
type of outcome that the case led to (i.e., cleared/cleared with
conditions/prohibited/withdrawn/non-applicability; phase 1/phase 2). Where a
case led to an outcome in both phase 1 and 2, only the phase 2 outcome was
included. All decisions which led to conditional clearance, a phase 2 investigation,
a prohibition or a withdrawal were selected for an in-depth analysis. A further 38
cases with unconditional clearance in phase 1 were also analysed in depth, based
on the case’s importance and the language capabilities of the expert and her
collaborators. This led to an in-depth analysis of a total of 69 cases. Annex II
provides a list of these 69 cases that identifies the theories of harm employed in
those cases. Annex III provides a concise summary of all those 69 national cases
that were considered particularly relevant for the purposes of this Report.
(23) The 69 national cases that were considered particularly relevant for the purposes
of this Report were then analysed in detail as concerns
(i) the competitive concerns raised by the NCA,
(ii) the theories of harm assessed by the NCA, and
(iii) the remedies (if any) imposed by the NCA or agreed upon between the
merging parties and the NCA.
(24) Where mergers gave rise to cases in multiple jurisdictions, such cases were
particularly focused on for comparative purposes.
23
See, especially, Daniel Mândrescu (ed), EU Competition Law and the Digital Economy: Protecting Free
and Fair Competition in an Age of Technological (R)Evolution (XXIX FIDE Congress 2020).
24
This was carried out on the Caselex.eu platform.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
20
III. A short primer on the law and economics applicable to
digital merger control
(25) In digital and technology markets, conglomerate and vertical mergers are
increasingly coming into the focus of merger control. Conglomerate mergers are
mergers that occur between companies that are not competitors on the same
relevant market, while vertical mergers are mergers that occur between companies
that are in a vertical relationship, eg as suppliers or customers.
25
Together, these
types of mergers will be called non-horizontal mergers to distinguish them from
horizontal mergers, i.e. mergers between companies active on the same relevant
market.
26
(26) The reason for this renewed interest in non-horizontal mergers can be seen in the
specific characteristics that dynamic, digital markets display and that have an
influence on how digital companies compete.
27
This interest in digital mergers
was only heightened by the unprecedented buying spree on which a number of
digital platforms embarked over the past years,
28
leading to noteworthy digital
mergers that were not necessarily considered horizontal and yet understood to be
possibly harmful to competition by the public.
29
1. The nature of digital mergers
(27) Big Tech is increasingly diversifying its portfolio, creating digital ecosystems
with varied offerings for consumers. Over the past few years, the European
Commission alone has investigated well over a dozen Big Tech mergers
30
as well
as an important number of technology mergers, for example in the area of
25
European Commission, Guidelines on the assessment of non-horizontal mergers under the Council
Regulation on the control of concentrations between undertakings (Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines
2008) [2008] OJ C265/6, paras 2-5, 91. The US Vertical Merger Guidelines encompass both vertical
mergers as under the European definition, as well as vertical issues that arise in mergers of complements,
ie conglomerates; US Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission, Vertical Merger Guidelines
(30 June 2020) 1.
26
On the nature of horizontal mergers, see European Commission, Guidelines on the assessment of
horizontal mergers under the Council Regulation on the control of concentrations between undertakings
(Horizontal Merger Guidelines 2004) [2004] OJ C31/5, para 5; US Department of Justice and Federal Trade
Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines (19 August 2010) 1.
27
For an introduction, see Viktoria H.S.E. Robertson, ‘Antitrust Law and Digital Markets’ in Heinz D.
Kurz, Marlies Schütz, Rita Strohmaier and Stella S. Zilian (eds), The Routledge Handbook of Smart
Technologies: An Economic and Social Perspective (2022) 432.
28
Alex Sherman and Lauren Feiner, ‘Amazon, Microsoft and Alphabet went on a buying spree in 2021
despite D.C.’s vow to take on Big Tech’ (22 January 2022) CNBC
<https://www.cnbc.com/2022/01/22/amazon-microsoft-alphabet-set-more-deals-in-2021-than-last-10-
years.html>.
29
Eg, see Cecilia Kang and David McCabe, ‘F.T.C. Broadens Review of Tech Giants, Homing In on Their
Deals’ New York Times (11 February 2020); David McCabe and Jim Tankersley, ‘Biden Urges More
Scrutiny of Big Business, Such as Tech Giants’ New York Times (16 September 2021); Kiran Stacey, James
Fontanella-Khan and Stefania Palma, ‘Big tech companies snap up smaller rivals at record paceFinancial
Times (19 September 2021); Richard Waters and Leo Lewis, ‘Why gaming is the new Big Tech
battleground’ Financial Times (21 January 2022).
30
For a comprehensive list of these cases, see already footnote 15 above.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
21
semiconductors.
31
Digital and technology mergers are not restricted to Big Tech,
however. Another trend that can be noted at the merger stage is that more and
more services and retail activities are (also) moving online, something that can be
seen in travel agency services,
32
in the sale of books and household goods,
33
in
digital property listings
34
or the renting of bicycles through mobile applications,
35
as well as in online betting and gambling.
36
2. Digital mergers and conglomerate theories of harm
(28) In merger control, horizontal mergers are traditionally viewed as a bigger threat
to competition than vertical or conglomerate mergers. This is also how the
European Commission frames the issue in its 2008 Non-Horizontal Merger
Guidelines.
37
The 2021 Merger Guidelines by the UK’s Competition & Markets
Authority highlight that over 80% of its merger investigations in phase 1 relate to
horizontal mergers.
38
In this assessment, however, digital market environments
with their specific market characteristics may be a game-changer.
39
(29) In digital markets, mergers often defy traditional categorisations because a merger
may at the same time be a vertical merger (where the data from an acquired start-
up serves as an additional input), a conglomerate merger (where an aspect of an
acquired start-up complements the offerings of the acquiring platform) and a
horizontal merger (where an aspect of an acquired start-up already competes with
the acquiring platform’s offerings).
40
(30) After a considerable conglomerate merger wave in the 1960s and 1970s,
41
conglomerate mergers have today returned to the forefront of antitrust debate.
31
For a comprehensive list of these cases, see already footnote 20 above.
32
Office of Fair Trading, Web Reservations/Hostelbookers.com (ME/6062/13, 2 August 2013).
33
Autorité de la concurrence, Fnac/Darty (16-DCC-111, 27 July 2016).
34
Bundeskartellamt, Axel Springer/Immowelt (B6-39/15, 20 April 2015); Competition & Markets
Authority, ZPG/Websky (ME/6690/17, 29 June 2017); Autorité de la concurrence, Axel Springer/Concept
Multimédia (18-DCC-18, 1 February 2018).
35
Autoriteit Consument & Markt, NS Groep/Pon Netherlands (ACM/20/038614, 20 May 2020).
36
Eg, see Malta Competition and Consumer Affairs Authority, GVC Holdings/Ladbrokes Coral Group
(COMP-MCCAA/4/18, 21 March 2018); Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Stars
Group/Sky Betting & Gaming (M/18/038, 18 June 2018); Competition and Consumer Protection
Commission, Flutter Entertainment/Stars Group (M/20/001, 12 May 2020).
37
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, para 92.
38
Competition & Markets Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 1.10.
39
On these characteristics, see also Lear, ‘Ex-post Assessment of Merger Control Decisions in Digital
Markets’ (9 May 2019) 3 ff.
40
For instance, in the recently cleared Microsoft/Nuance acquisition, the European Commission identified
and assessed ‘horizontal overlaps between the activities of Nuance and Microsoft in the markets for
transcription software’, a ‘vertical link between Microsoft’s cloud computing and Nuance’s downstream
transcription software for healthcare’, ‘conglomerate links between Nuance's transcription software
products and a number of Microsoft’s products’ and the ‘use of data transcribed with Nuance’s software’;
European Commission Decision of 21 December 2021, M.10290 Microsoft/Nuance; European
Commission, ‘Mergers: Commission approves acquisition of Nuance by Microsoft’ IP/21/7067 (21
December 2021).
41
Eg, see Everette Macintyre, ‘Statement on Conglomerate Mergers and Antitrust Laws’ (2 December
1966)
<https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/public_statements/683731/19661202_macintyre_conglome
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
22
This comeback, it has been argued, is due to the competitive characteristics found
in digital markets, as well as the platform business model popular in that market
environment and the network effects specific to some of those markets.
42
(31) In the 1970s, several theories were advanced on the reasons for conglomerate
mergers. Of these, some still appear relevant in order to understand the intentions
behind digital conglomerate mergers, in particular the market power theory and
the resource theory.
43
Under the market power theory, digital platforms move into
adjacent markets in order to strengthen their stronghold on the initial market.
Under the resource theory, the resources that digital platforms readily have
available allow them to move into adjacent markets with relative ease.
44
(32) In addition, multiple authors have identified factors that specifically explain the
reasons for digital conglomeration that go beyond how conglomerate mergers of
the 1960s and 1970s were understood.
45
These factors directly relate to possible
theories of harm under a substantive merger analysis. Lim (2020), for instance,
argues that while digital conglomeration continues to serve the goal of
diversification, this is ultimately ‘pursued more in fear of displacement rather than
business cyclicality’.
46
(33) Conglomerate mergers in the digital age can bring about a multitude of benefits
for the acquiring platform and its customers, but these benefits can at the same
time constitute new barriers to entry for innovators. On the supply-side, Bourreau
and de Streel (2019) find that the modular design of many digital products allows
digital platforms to make use of their resources for a variety of different purposes,
leading to significant economies of scope. Resources can relate to hardware,
software or data,
47
for instance. On the demand-side, digital platforms can benefit
from consumption synergies that consumers enjoy in multi-product ecosystems.
48
This can directly benefit consumers while at the same time locking them into a
particular digital ecosystem and thereby, in the long run, softening competition.
(34) While tying and bundling are generally recognised as possible anti-competitive
effects of conglomerate mergers, and thus a possibility to be assessed in the
merger review,
49
Bourreau and de Streel (2019) argue that ‘the specific
characteristics of the digital industries may change the effects of conglomerate
diversification and affect the balance between pro- and anti-competitive effects’.
50
They propose that tying and bundling, also through digital ecosystems, need to be
focused on in digital merger control as a particular barrier to entry for innovating
rate_mergers_and_antitrust_laws.pdf>. Conglomerate mergers were then addressed by the 1968 US Merger
Guidelines; US Department of Justice, Merger Guidelines (1968), section III.
42
Lim (n 13) 48.
43
Bourreau and de Streel (n 12) 6 ff.
44
Bourreau and de Streel (n 12) 7 (containing further references).
45
See, in particular, Bourreau and de Streel (n 12); Lim (n 13).
46
Lim (n 13) 55 (containing references to that effect).
47
On the particular importance of data for the analysis of conglomerate mergers, see also Lim (n 13) 57
(speaking of ‘data-driven network effects’); Lécuyer (n 12) 47.
48
Bourreau and de Streel (n 12) 9-13.
49
See European Commission, Non-Horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, para 93.
50
Bourreau and de Streel (n 12) 13.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
23
newcomers.
51
Particular issues they draw attention to include the softening of
competition through increased differentiation and platform envelopment,
whereby ‘a dominant platform enters a new market pioneered by an entrant
platform and forecloses the new entrant’.
52
Here, the issue from a competition law
point of view is that once another company’s product is incorporated into the
buyer’s digital ecosystem, network effects may be able to further strengthen its
market power.
53
Platform envelopment has been described as a possible point of
entry for digital platforms that does not involve ‘offer[ing] revolutionary
functionality to win substantial market share’.
54
(35) While so-called portfolio effects already worried competition authorities in non-
digital cases,
55
digital conglomerates may rely on product proliferation in a
targeted way as a deterrence strategy to keep potential entrants out of the market.
56
Furthermore, digital conglomerates may sometimes act as a gatekeeper for access
to users as well as for access to products and services,
57
a fact that merger control
needs to bear in mind. Where a digital conglomerate keeps an essential component
to itself, access remedies may be appropriate.
58
(36) Pre-emption of potential competitors has been identified as an important driving
force behind digital platforms that buy promising start-ups.
59
While it is
impossible to predict with certainty whether a certain start-up would have
morphed into a credible competitive threat,
60
anecdotal evidence suggests that the
digital platforms themselves seem to think so.
61
Ultimately, the impact of a digital
merger on innovation may need to be assessed more carefully.
62
Here, the focus
may also need to shift to a more long-term view of how a digital market may
develop in the future.
63
51
Bourreau and de Streel (n 12) 29.
52
Bourreau and de Streel (n 12) 16; based on Thomas Eisenmann, Geoffrey Parker and Marshall Van
Alstyne, ‘Platform Envelopment’ (2011) 32 Strategic Management Journal 1270.
53
Jacques Crémer, Heike Schweitzer and Yves-Alexandre de Montjoye, Competition Policy in the Digital
Era (2019) 110-122; Lécuyer (n 12) 47.
54
Eisenmann, Parker and Van Alstyne (n 52) 1270.
55
See Witt (n 13) 212.
56
Based on Richard Schmalensee, ‘Entry Deterrence in the Ready-to-Eat Breakfast Cereal Industry’ (1978)
9 Bell Journal of Economics 305.
57
Bourreau and de Streel (n 12) 13-21.
58
Bourreau and de Streel (n 12) 30.
59
Lim (n 13) 55; Crémer, Schweitzer and de Montjoye (n 53) 110-122; Jason Furman et al., Unlocking
Digital Competition Report of the Digital Competition Expert Panel (2019) paras 1.154 f.
60
Lécuyer (n 12) 45.
61
Eg, see Meta CEO Mark Zuckerberg’s emails about smaller rivals, invoking that ‘These businesses are
nascent but the networks established, the brands are already meaningful, and if they grow to a large scale
they could be very disruptive to us. Given that we think our own valuation is fairly aggressive and that
we’re vulnerable in mobile, I’m curious if we should consider going after one or two of them.’ On reasons
for such an acquisition, Zuckerberg held that it was to neutralize as well as to integrate the target’s services
into Facebook’s. Casey Newton and Nilay Patel, ‘“Instagram can hurt us”: Mark Zuckerberg Emails Outline
Plan to Neutralize Competitors’ The Verge (29 July 2020)
<https://www.theverge.com/2020/7/29/21345723/facebook-instagram-documents-emails-mark-
zuckerberg-kevin-systrom-hearing>.
62
Bourreau and de Streel (n 12) 32.
63
Eg, see European Commission Decision of 27 January 2022, M.10262 Meta/Kustomer.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
24
(37) Based on the far-reaching consequences of some of the competitive threats that
can arise in connection with digital conglomerate mergers, the Furman Report
(2019) proposed that NCAs should be put in a position to apply a ‘balance of
harms’ approach whereby in a merger assessment they could take into account
anti-competitive effects that have a low probability but a high impact.
64
At
present, however, the UK is not following this proposal.
65
(38) Of course, conglomerate mergers in the digital economy can also lead to a number
of efficiencies that merit closer scrutiny. In this respect, economists have
highlighted the realisation of economies of scope, consumption synergies, a
complementarity in capabilities, and the provision of an exit strategy for
innovative start-ups.
66
In addition, they also do not lead to the removal of a
competitor as a horizontal merger would.
67
(39) Frequently, a digital merger will have both conglomerate and vertical aspects to
it. In a vertical merger, companies are already in a (vertical) business relationship
or could be.
68
While vertical mergers are generally thought to have less anti-
competitive effects than horizontal ones, they can lead to reduced output, higher
prices or harm to innovation.
69
Particularly the threat of foreclosure or raising
rivals’ cost may be applicable in the digital economy.
(40) While a look to past vertical and conglomerate mergers can provide valuable
insights, the competitive dynamics in digital markets are noticeably different,
70
meaning that the analysis initially developed for more traditional conglomerate
mergers will not always directly apply to a digital conglomerate merger today.
For this reason, it can be particularly insightful to look at national merger
enforcement in the EU Member States (and a former EU Member State) in order
to get a broad overview on how theories of harm and remedies have evolved in
this particular market context in different regions.
3. Digital mergers and digital ecosystems
(41) While the reasons for digital mergers are manifold, it increasingly emerges that
competition concerns associated with these mergers need to be understood against
64
Furman et al. (n 59) paras 3.88-3.94.
65
In 2021, this proposal was being put into practice at a slightly lower degree of intervention, namely in
the shape of a revised probability standard; see Secretary of State for Digital, Culture, Media & Sport and
Secretary of State for Business, Energy and Industrial Strategy, ‘A new pro-competition regime for digital
markets’ (CP 489, July 2021) paras 187-191
<https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/10039
13/Digital_Competition_Consultation_v2.pdf>. In 2022, however, the Queen’s Speech made clear that no
such change was to be expected; Victoria Ibitoye, ‘UK scraps tougher Big Tech merger-review standard,
stays quiet on law to back digital regulator’ MLex (6 May 2022)
<https://content.mlex.com/#/content/1376156?referrer=email_dailycontentset&dailyId=ecdc6c88629a432
6bbe6bfbb614c0e59>.
66
Lécuyer (n 12) 46-47.
67
Lécuyer (n 12) 46.
68
Herbert Hovenkamp, ‘Competitive Harm from Vertical Mergers’ (2021) 59 The Industrial Organization
Society 139, 158.
69
Hovenkamp (n 68) 142.
70
Lim (n 13) 56.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
25
the background of sophisticated digital ecosystems. In the digital sphere, there is
a noticeable trend towards the creation and development of ever more tight-knit
digital ecosystems that connect goods and services in an intricate, interoperable
system even if the goods and services connected through the ecosystem
themselves are not closely related.
71
However, the orchestrators of these digital
ecosystems have come to realize that this is their chance to lock-in users, prevent
multi-homing and increase their hold on several relevant markets. Conglomerate
and vertical mergers can be one vehicle to expand their digital ecosystems.
(42) Digital ecosystems raise many questions as to how competition law ought to apply
to them.
72
These questions are also pertinent in the context of merger control. As
ecosystem orchestrators, digital conglomerates are often in multi-contact
competition with other digital conglomerates. It can therefore be useful to go
beyond a narrow view of the relevant market to assess these cases,
73
essentially
relying on market definition as a tool to characterise the market rather than
deducing market power from the computed market shares.
74
4. The appropriate legal framework for assessing digital mergers
(43) Against the background of the specific competition dynamics found in digital
markets discussed above, the question arises whether digital and technology
mergers can be assessed under the traditional merger framework, or whether
traditional approaches need to be adapted or even replaced by more suitable ones.
These are also questions that the Furman Report (2019)
75
and the Special
Advisers’ Report (2019)
76
addressed. This applies to substantive as well as
procedural questions, although the present Report focuses on the former.
(44) As Margrethe Vestager, then Commissioner for Competition and today also
Executive Vice-President of the European Commission in charge of Europe fit for
a digital age, pointed out in 2016, EU merger control rules are generally
sufficiently flexible to adjust to the developments that have taken place in digital
markets.
77
However, she also acknowledged that there can nevertheless be a need
to ‘revisit[] theories of harm, so we can intervene in mergers when the owners of
ecosystems buy start-ups before they have a chance to grow.’
78
In line with this
thinking, it has been argued that in applying the flexible rules of merger control,
the specific characteristics and dynamics of digital markets need to be taken into
71
Eg, see Mohan Subramaniam et al., ‘Competing in Digital Ecosystems’ (2019) 62 Business Horizons 83;
Amelia Fletcher, ‘Digital Competition Policy: Are Ecosystems Different?’ (2020)
DAF/COMP/WD(2020)96; Michael G. Jacobides and Ioannis Lianos, ‘Ecosystems and Competition Law
in Theory and Practice’ (2021) 30 Industrial and Corporate Change 1199.
72
This starts with the basic unit of competition law analysis, market definition; eg, see Viktoria H.S.E.
Robertson, ‘Antitrust Market Definition for Digital Ecosystems’ (N° 2-2021) Concurrences 3.
73
Lim (n 13) 61.
74
Viktoria H.S.E. Robertson, Competition Law’s Innovation Factor: The Relevant Market in Dynamic
Contexts in the EU and the US (Hart 2020).
75
Furman et al. (n 59) paras 3.32-3.108.
76
Crémer, Schweitzer and de Montjoye (n 53) 110-124.
77
Margrethe Vestager, ‘Competition in a Big Data World’ (Munich, 17 January 2016).
78
Margrethe Vestager, ‘Shaping Competition Policy in the Era of Digitisation’ (Brussels, 17 January 2019).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
26
account.
79
The present Report enquires to what extent NCAs have already done
so.
(45) The European Union relies on a bifurcated approach to merger control: While the
European Commission is the sole enforcer of the EU Merger Regulation,
80
NCAs
apply national merger rules that foresee lower merger thresholds than the EU
rules. While there is a referral system both from the Commission to NCAs and
vice versa, these two types of merger regimes exist next to each other. This leads
to a situation where a harmonious development of a pan-European approach to
digital mergers requires an effort to bring these two parallel regimes into contact
that based on the rules set out in the EUMR they rarely have.
81
(46) Digital and technology mergers that reach the EU’s turnover thresholds fall within
the exclusive competence of the European Commission and are thus assessed by
it. However, a number of Big Tech mergers were not caught by the jurisdictional
thresholds of EU merger control, often because the target’s turnover was below
the jurisdictional turnover thresholds. Some of these mergers were caught by
national merger control. For instance, some jurisdictions like Austria or Germany
introduced an additional transaction value threshold that is able to capture the buy-
up of promising start-ups that do not yet generate a substantial turnover.
82
Mergers
such as Apple/Shazam were referred to the European Commission by an NCA.
83
In other cases, like Facebook/WhatsApp, the notifying parties submitted a
reasoned submission to the Commission asking it to take the case.
84
Yet other
mergers were exclusively assessed on a national basis, such as the Austrian and
UK investigations of the Meta/Giphy merger
85
or more regional digital platforms.
In other cases, like Meta/Kustomer, the Commission accepted a referral from a
Member State but a non-referring NCA assessed the merger in parallel as it later
decided that its (new) transaction value threshold was met.
86
Such parallel reviews
constitute an inherent risk of divergence in the assessment, as well as duplicating
investigation efforts. For this reason, the one-stop-shop principle contained in the
EUMR strives to avoid such situations as far as possible. Wherever this is not
79
Bourreau and de Streel (n 12) 24.
80
Article 22 EUMR.
81
Contrast this with the parallel application of EU antitrust rules (Articles 101 and 102 TFEU) by the
European Commission and NCAs, as foreseen in Regulation 1/2003; Consolidated Version of the Treaty
on the Functioning of the European Union [2016] OJ C202/47 (TFEU); Council Regulation (EC) No 1/2003
of 16 December 2002 on the implementation of the rules on competition laid down in Articles 81 and 82
of the Treaty [2003] OJ L1/1.
82
Eg, see § 9 para 4 Cartel Act, Austrian Federal Law Gazette I 61/2005 as amended; § 35 para 1a Act
against Restraints of Competition, German Federal Law Gazette I 2013/1750 as amended. See also
Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde and Bundeskartellamt, Leitfaden Transaktionswert-Schwellen fr die
Anmeldepflicht von Zusammenschlussvorhaben 35 Abs. 1a GWB und § 9 Abs. 4 KartG) (January 2022).
83
European Commission Decision of 6 September 2018, M.8788 Apple/Shazam, paras 6-9.
84
European Commission Decision of 3 October 2014, COMP/M.7217 Facebook/WhatsApp, paras 9-12.
85
Competition & Markets Authority, Meta/Giphy (ME/6891/20-II, 6 December 2021); Meta/Giphy, [2022]
CAT 26, 14 June 2022; Kartellgericht, 7 February 2022, 28 Kt 8/21t and 28 Kt 9/21i Meta/Giphy;
Kartellobergericht, 23 June 2022, 16 Ok 3/22k and 16 Ok 4/22g Meta/Giphy.
86
European Commission Decision of 27 January 2022, M.10262 Meta/Kustomer; Bundeskartellamt,
Meta/Kustomer (B6-37/21, 9 December 2021).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
27
possible, close cooperation between the Commission and the NCAs can help
alleviate concerns of divergence.
87
(47) As the EUMR attributes competences rather than introducing a comprehensive
substantive European framework for merger control, a disconnect can also arise
between national cases and EU cases as regards the substantive assessment of
cases. Sometimes, the European and national levels may also not be fully aware
of the plethora of digital and technology cases that other NCAs have already dealt
with. Collaboration among NCAs and with the Commission, e.g., through the
Merger Working Group,
88
serves as an important mechanism to minimise any
such disconnect.
89
This Report aims to further narrow this gap by focusing on
national merger cases in the digital and high-tech sectors. It identifies and analyses
these cases with a view to understanding the theories of harm that NCAs applied
and the remedies that were subsequently imposed (if any).
87
In fact, as the German NCA highlighted in its press release, it took the Commission’s conditional
clearance into account when unconditionally clearing the concentration in Meta/Kustomer;
Bundeskartellamt, ‘Bundeskartellamt clears acquisition of Kustomer by Meta (formerly Facebook)’ Press
Release (11 February 2022)
<https://www.bundeskartellamt.de/SharedDocs/Meldung/EN/Pressemitteilungen/2022/11_02_2022_Meta
_Kustomer.html>.
88
See EU Merger Working Group, ‘Best Practices on Cooperation between EU National Competition
Authorities in Merger Review’ (8 November 2011).
89
The European Competition Network does not extend to merger review.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
28
IV. National digital and technology merger cases in selected
EU Member States and the UK: Quantitative insights
(48) The quantitative analysis of the cases analysed for this Report already allows for
a number of insights into this particular area of merger control.
(49) In preparation for this Report, 97 cases were identified that came within the
parameters set out in Chapter II. Concerning their outcome, the 97 cases were
decided as follows:
- 65 cases: Unconditional clearance in phase 1
90
- 9 cases: Unconditional clearance in phase 2
- 10 cases: Conditional clearance in phase 1
- 5 cases: Conditional clearance in phase 2
- 6 cases: Prohibition
- 1 case: Non-applicability
- 1 case: Withdrawal
This distribution can be seen represented below in figure 1.
1. Quantitative insights: Outcome of 97 national merger cases
(50) Out of these 97 cases, all 22 cases that led to a conditional clearance (phase 1 or
phase 2), a prohibition or a withdrawal were analysed in depth. All 9 cases that
led to a phase 2 investigation were equally analysed in-depth. In addition, based
on the case’s importance and the language capabilities of the expert and her
collaborators, a further 38 cases with unconditional clearance in phase 1 were also
analysed in-depth. This led to an in-depth analysis of a total of 69 cases.
90
In one case, the clearance actually occurred in the pre-phase 1 assessment (‘Vorprfverfahren’); see
Bundeskartellamt, Adevinta/eBay Classifieds Group (B6-41/20, 23 November 2020).
67%
9%
11%
5%
6%
1%
1%
National merger cases, by outcome
Unconditional clearance in phase 1
Unconditional clearance in phase 2
Conditional clearance in phase 1
Conditional clearance in phase 2
Prohibition
Withdrawal
Non-applicability
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
29
(51) Of the 69 cases that were selected for an in-depth analysis, the distribution by
country was as follows:
- 21 cases from the United Kingdom
- 8 cases from Germany
- 7 cases from Ireland
- 6 cases from Spain
- 4 cases from France
- 4 cases from Slovenia
- 3 cases from Austria
- 3 cases from Hungary
- 3 cases from the Netherlands
- 2 cases from Romania
- 2 cases from Sweden
- 1 case from Czechia
- 1 case from Greece
- 1 case from Italy
- 1 case from Malta
- 1 case from Poland
- 1 case from Portugal
This distribution can be seen represented below in figure 2.
2. Quantitative insights: Distribution by country of 69 selected national merger cases
(52) For the remaining 28 cases that were either unconditionally cleared in phase 1 or
where merger control was found to be inapplicable, these were only analysed as
to their outcome. The distribution by country was as follows:
- 6 cases from the United Kingdom
30%
12%
10%
9%
6%
6%
4%
4%
4%
3%
3%
1% each
Selected national merger cases, by country
United Kingdom
Germany
Ireland
Spain
France
Slovenia
Austria
Netherlands
Hungary
Romania
Sweden
Czechia
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
30
- 5 cases from Portugal
- 4 cases from Estonia
- 3 cases from Greece
- 2 cases from Bulgaria
- 2 cases from Cyprus
- 2 cases from Germany
- 1 case from Czechia
- 1 case from Hungary
- 1 case from Ireland
- 1 case from Spain
(53) For all 69 cases analysed in-depth, concise case summaries were prepared that can
be found in Annex III. The theories of harm that the NCA assessed in the cases at
hand were identified for every single case, allowing for a number of insights into
the issues that competition authorities tend to focus on in digital and technology
mergers. It is noteworthy that nearly a third of all cases analysed in-depth came
from the United Kingdom. 10 of the cases analysed in-depth were decided prior
to the UK leaving the EU, while the remaining 11 cases were decided since 1
February 2020.
(54) Of the 69 cases, 30 cases only assessed horizontal effects, 18 cases assessed
horizontal and vertical effects, 8 cases assessed horizontal and conglomerate
effects, 5 cases only assessed vertical effects, 3 cases assessed vertical and
conglomerate effects, and 2 cases only assessed conglomerate effects. A total of
3 cases assessed horizontal, vertical and conglomerate effects. This distribution
can be seen below in figure 3.
3. Quantitative insights: Combinations of theories of harm in 69 selected national merger cases
44%
26%
12%
4%
7%
4%
3%
Selected national merger cases,
by theories of harm
Only horizontal theories of harm
Horizontal and vertical theories of harm
Horizontal and conglomerate theories of harm
Horizontal, vertical and conglomerate
theories of harm
Only vertical theories of harm
Vertical and conglomerate theories of harm
Only conglomerate theories of harm
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
31
(55) The quantitative analysis also allows a glimpse into the specific types of theories
of harm that the authorities investigated (see figure 4). 59 cases included
horizontal theories of harm, while only 10 cases concerned no horizontal theories
of harm at all. In 51 cases, the loss of an actual competitor was assessed, while in
6 cases, the loss of a potential competitor was assessed. In 4 cases, horizontal
coordinated effects were assessed. 5 cases assessed other horizontal theories of
harm. Note that several cases involved two or more horizontal theories of harm.
4. Quantitative insights: Distribution of horizontal theories of harm in 69 selected national merger cases
(56) 29 cases considered vertical theories of harm, while 40 cases addressed no vertical
theories of harm at all. Of these 29 cases, 27 cases assessed input foreclosure,
while 11 cases assessed customer foreclosure. 4 cases addressed other vertical,
non-coordinated effects, while no cases addressed vertical coordinated effects.
Note that several cases involved two vertical theories of harm.
51
6
4
5
10
0 10 20 30 40 50 60
Loss of an actual competitor
Loss of a potential competitor
Coordinated effects
Other horizontal theories of harm
No horizontal theories of harm
Horizontal theories of harm
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
32
5. Quantitative insights: Distribution of vertical theories of harm in 69 selected national merger cases
(57) Finally, concerning conglomerate theories of harm, 15 cases addressed
conglomerate foreclosure through the linking of sales (tying, bundling), while one
further case addressed ecosystem concerns that were considered as a further
conglomerate competition concern.
(58) If one looks at the distribution of theories of harm more closely, it can be seen that
in 25 cases, the only theory of harm explored by the authority in some depth
related to the loss of an actual competitor (horizontal unilateral effects). Of these
mergers, 12 were unconditionally cleared in phase 1, 4 were unconditionally
cleared in phase 2, 5 were cleared subject to conditions in phase 1, 2 were cleared
subject to conditions in phase 2, one was withdrawn, and one was prohibited.
(59) In 4 cases that exclusively focused on horizontal theories of harm, in addition to
the loss of an actual competitor a further theory of harm related to horizontal
effects was assessed. In 2 cases, this was related to horizontal coordinated effects
(once in addition to further horizontal effects), in 2 cases to the loss of a potential
competitor. In one case, only other non-coordinated horizontal effects were
analysed closely.
(60) In 19 cases where horizontal effects were assessed, vertical foreclosure (input or
customer foreclosure) effects were also assessed. Of these, 4 mergers were
prohibited. In 3 cases, conglomerate foreclosure effects were assessed in addition
to the horizontal and vertical effects; all of these mergers were unconditionally
cleared in phase 1.
(61) In only 10 cases, no horizontal effects were assessed at all and the analysis instead
focused on vertical foreclosure effects, other vertical effects, and/or conglomerate
effects. None of these mergers were prohibited, and 3 were conditionally cleared
in phase 1. 2 were conditionally cleared in phase 2, while 5 were unconditionally
cleared in phase 1.
27
11
4
40
Vertical input foreclosure
Vertical customer foreclosure
Other vertical, non-coordinated effects
No vertical theories of harm
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45
Vertical theories of harm
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
33
(62) Of the 6 cases in which concentrations were prohibited, all cases assessed
horizontal effects, and 4 in addition assessed vertical foreclosure effects. None
assessed any conglomerate effects.
(63) 15 concentrations were conditionally cleared, meaning that the competition
authorities either imposed or accepted remedies in these cases. Of these, 10 cases
were cleared subject to conditions in phase 1 and a further 5 were cleared subject
to conditions in phase 2.
(64) Of the 10 cases in which concentrations were conditionally cleared in phase 1, 7
(also) related to horizontal effects, while 3 did not involve an assessment of
horizontal effects.
(65) Of the 5 cases in which concentrations were conditionally cleared in phase 2, 3
(also) concerned horizontal effects, one only concerned vertical and conglomerate
effects, and one only concerned conglomerate effects.
(66) Of the 9 cases in which concentrations were unconditionally cleared in phase 2,
all (also) related to horizontal effects. In addition, one case referred to vertical
effects and two cases to conglomerate effects.
(67) In the one case in which the parties withdrew from the proposed concentration,
the loss of an actual competitor was at stake.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
34
V. National digital and technology merger cases in selected
EU Member States and the UK: Qualitative insights and
mapping the theories of harm
(68) In order to enable qualitative insights on digital and technology merger control by
NCAs, cases were categorised based on the theories of harm that were assessed
by the authority in question in some depth. A single case can also pertain to several
categories in this respect. The following categories and sub-categories were
identified based on the European Commission’s Guidelines on Horizontal
Mergers (2004)
91
and its Guidelines on Non-Horizontal Mergers (2008),
92
the UK
Competition & Market Authority’s Merger Assessment Guidelines (2021)
93
and
the national cases themselves. In particular, the case analysis showed that NCAs
closely stay within this traditional categorisation of theories of harm. This in itself
is noteworthy and can lead to a type of analysis that reinforces old insights and
only gradually adapts to new market environments.
(69) The categories of theories of harm allow for insights into when a merger is thought
to be anti-competitive in digital and technology markets, thereby fulfilling the
tests that are known as the SIEC test in the EU terminology (SIEC standing for a
significant impediment of effective competition) or the SLC test in the UK
(substantially lessening competition). These tests usually ask whether a merger
will lead to the creation or strengthening of a dominant position,
94
or whether it
might lead to other anti-competitive effects that arise. Anti-competitive effects
can arise from non-coordinated (unilateral) or coordinated behaviour. While
national merger regimes can deviate from this terminology, in all cases reviewed,
they by and large stayed within this framework.
1. Horizontal theories of harm
(70) Horizontal mergers are concentrations that involve companies that are active on
the same relevant market, i.e. the companies are actual or potential competitors.
95
A number of theories of harm related to horizontal mergers can be distinguished
that are briefly set out below, followed by an analysis of how these particular
theories of harm were applied in the digital and technology merger cases that were
identified on a national level. Where appropriate, parallels to European
Commission cases are drawn in the discussion that follows.
91
European Commission, Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers under the Council Regulation
on the control of concentrations between undertakings (Horizontal Merger Guidelines 2004) [2004] OJ
C31/5.
92
European Commission, Guidelines on the assessment of non-horizontal mergers under the Council
Regulation on the control of concentrations between undertakings (Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines
2008) [2008] OJ C265/6.
93
Competition & Markets Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines (CMA129, 18 March 2021).
94
European Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines 2004, para 4.
95
European Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines 2004, para 5.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
35
i. Non-coordinated effects: Loss of an actual competitor
a. Specificities of the theory of harm
(71) Where the merging parties are competitors on the same relevant market, a
horizontal merger removes a competitive constraint from the market and the main
competition concern thus relates to the loss of competition between the companies
that are involved in the merger.
96
This can in turn lead to an increase in prices and
a decrease in quality, choice, service and innovation.
97
In addition, other
companies might also feel less competitive pressure once a close competitor is
removed through a merger.
98
(72) Competition authorities take into account a number of factors in order to
determine whether anti-competitive effects might materialise due to the loss of an
actual competitor, such as the parties’ market shares, the closeness of competition
between them, the number of effective competitors providing a competitive
constraint on the market post-merger, the ability of customers to switch suppliers
and related switching costs, the ability and likelihood of expansion by
competitors, the merged entity’s ability to hinder competitors’ expansion, and
whether the merger eliminates an important competitive force (i.e., a maverick).
99
(73) Recent merger guidelines by the UK’s Competition & Markets Authority, which
were published in March 2021, include additional guidance on mergers in digital
markets. With regard to two-sided platforms, they affirm that depending on the
nature of the case, the authority will either look at each side of a platform or
consider it overall. The NCA draws attention to the importance of network effects
and the possibility of tipping in those markets, as well as to often high barriers to
entry, all of which mean that digital mergers may more readily raise competition
concerns.
100
The Special Advisers’ Report (2019) also described digital market
settings in which competitive concerns may arise due to a merger, especially
where a market is already concentrated and there are high barriers to entry. In such
circumstances, the acquisition of a start-up may further strengthen a dominant
platform’s market position by increasing barriers to entry, adding to the ecosystem
orchestrated by the platform, and reduce innovation in the market.
101
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers
(74) Of 69 cases analysed in-depth, a total of 51 cases raised issues related to the loss
of an actual competitor on the relevant market(s). Of these 51 cases, 9
concentrations were cleared subject to conditions (7 in phase 1, 2 in phase 2), 4
concentrations were prohibited and one was withdrawn. The remaining
concentrations were all unconditionally cleared.
96
European Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines 2004, para 24.
97
Competition & Markets Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 4.1.
98
European Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines 2004, para 24.
99
European Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines 2004, paras 26-38; Competition & Markets
Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 4.3.
100
Competition & Markets Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, paras 4.21-4.25.
101
Crémer, Schweitzer and de Montjoye (n 53) 112 ff.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
36
(75) While all 51 cases that focused on the loss of an actual competitor are summarised
in Annex III, the following focuses on those 5 cases that were outright prohibited
or withdrawn, followed by the cases in which the NCA only cleared a
concentration subject to conditions. Furthermore, commonalities that have
emerged among a number of cases that were unconditionally cleared are set out
to provide a frame of reference.
(76) In Blocket/Hemnet (2016), the notifying parties withdrew their merger after the
Swedish NCA voiced considerable concerns related to horizontal unilateral
effects. Blocket was Sweden’s largest online marketplace and was also active in
digital property listings, where it was the second largest player. Blocket wanted
to buy Hemnet, the by far largest player in digital property listings. As Blocket
was Hemnet’s only credible competitor, this proposed acquisition would have
created a single major player on this market. The NCA was concerned this would
lead to higher prices for digital property listings, a decrease in quality of the
products and services provided and increased barriers to entry and expansion. The
commitments proposed by Blocket were not regarded as sufficient (on these, see
below at para (259)).
102
(77) In the case of CTS Eventim/Four Artists (2017), the German NCA prohibited an
acquisition primarily based on horizontal unilateral effects (see also para (279)).
CTS Eventim, a company active in live entertainment, event venues and ticketing,
wanted to acquire a majority stake in Four Artists, a company active in organising
live events and as a booking agent for a range of famous German artists. The NCA
considered that the acquisition would further strengthen CTS Eventim’s already
dominant position on the market for ticket system services for event organisers
and for booking offices. The NCA underlined how the (then) new German
provision of § 18 para 3a ARC
103
on assessing market dominance in multi-sided
markets allowed the conclusion that CTS Eventim was indeed dominant on these
markets, and how indirect network effects worked to the incumbent’s advantage.
It found that high barriers to entry, considerable lock-in effects and limited multi-
homing by the other market side led to a strong market position, while no
innovation-driven competition was discernible. The acquisition would lead to a
strengthening of CTS Eventim’s market position on the market for ticket system
services, thereby significantly impeding effective competition.
104
What is notable
is that another acquisition by CTS Eventim earlier that same year had been
unconditionally cleared by the German NCA in phase 2.
105
(78) Tobii/Smartbox (2019) was a completed acquisition that was prohibited by the UK
NCA. Both companies produced augmentative assistive communication (AAC)
solutions, i.e. communication aids for those that find communication difficult,
e.g., due to a disability or a medical condition. AAC solutions consist of AAC
hardware, AAC software, access means, (e.g., a switch, an eye gaze camera), and
102
Konkurrensverket, Blocket/Hemnet (84/2016, 2016).
103
Act against Restraints of Competition, German Federal Law Gazette I 2013/1750 as amended.
104
Bundeskartellamt, CTS Eventim/Four Artists (B6-35/17, 23 November 2017).
105
Bundeskartellamt, CTS Eventim/FKP Scorpio (B6-53/16, 3 January 2017).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
37
customer support. The concentration was prohibited due to horizontal unilateral
effects and vertical input foreclosure effects. Concerning horizontal unilateral
effects, the NCA considered that the main horizontal overlap between acquirer
and target occurred in the supply of dedicated AAC solutions. It did not accept
the argument that the providers faced strong competition from AAC solutions
based on mainstream consumer devices because this was not consistent with its
market analysis nor with the parties’ internal documents. The NCA assessed the
possibility of horizontal unilateral effects, particularly as regards price increases,
quality deterioration and a reduction in the range of services and/or product
development. It emphasised that, pre-merger, the parties had been close
competitors, and competition among them led to increased innovation and R&D.
Post-merger, the merged entity had a market share of 60-70% in the UK and
competitors did not provide a sufficient constraint. Part of the merger strategy had
indeed been to reduce the range of products available as well as R&D.
106
On the
prohibition, see also paras (281) f.
(79) Sabre/Farelogix (2020) was a further merger that the UK NCA blocked solely
based on horizontal unilateral effects. Sabre, a US company providing technology
solutions to airlines and travel agents, intended to acquire Farelogix, another US
company supplying technology solutions for airlines. Issues raised included
slower rates of innovation and product development, reduced product range or
quality, and higher prices or less favourable terms of service. While Farelogix was
a strong player in merchandising solutions for airlines, Sabre was not (yet).
However, the NCA considered that Sabre would become a strong competitor
absent the acquisition. Post-merger, only one strong competitor would remain,
namely Amadeus. The loss of competition resulting from the acquisition would
be significant. As regarded distribution solutions for airlines, the NCA noted that
the product offerings by the merging parties were differentiated, and that there
were several competitors that posed a credible competitive constraint. Overall,
however, it concluded that Farelogix would play an important role in that market
absent the merger, and the loss of competition resulting from the acquisition
would be significant, with a substantial and long-lasting impact on consumers.
107
On the prohibition, see also paras (283) f.
(80) In Swedbank Franchise/Svensk Fastighetsförmedling (2014), the Stockholm
District Court, upon an application by the Swedish NCA, blocked a concentration
between the two most important players on the Swedish real estate market who
also had high stakes in Hemnet.com, the biggest Swedish portal for real estate
advertisements. The Swedish NCA raised concerns about horizontal unilateral
effects and vertical input foreclosure. For the purposes of this Report, the latter is
of particular interest (see para (148) below).
108
106
Competition & Markets Authority, Tobii/Smartbox (ME/6780/18-II, 15 August 2019).
107
Competition & Markets Authority, Sabre/Farelogix (ME/6806/19-II, 9 April 2020).
108
Stockholms tingsrätt, Swedbank Franchise/Svensk Fastighetsförmedling (T 3629-14, 16 December
2014).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
38
(81) The concentration of Just Eat/La Nevera Roja (2016) on the Spanish market for
the management of food orders at home via online platforms was cleared subject
to conditions (on these, see below at para (261)). The Spanish NCA considered
that this horizontal merger raised competition concerns because the acquirer and
the target were close competitors and constituted, pre-merger, the biggest and
second biggest players on the market for the management of food orders via online
platforms. Post-merger, they would have a combined market share of about 70-
80%, possibly even higher. In addition, several companies had recently exited that
market. The NCA emphasised the importance of network effects in these markets,
and high barriers to entry consisting of investments to be made in publicity and
marketing. Nevertheless, the NCA also noted that, overall, online food delivery
platforms only accounted for 10% of the local food delivery markets in Spain,
meaning that the market power of these platforms over restaurants was overall
limited.
109
(82) In Just Eat Spain/Canary Delivery Company (2019), the Spanish NCA noted that
the remedies imposed in Just Eat/La Nevera Roja had favoured market entry for
digital food order platforms and thus led to a more competitive Spanish market,
meaning that the concentration under investigation, which concerned the same
relevant market, could take place without conditions.
110
(83) When MIH Food Delivery Holdings wanted to carry out a hostile takeover of Just
Eat in 2019, however, the Spanish NCA only cleared this subject to conditions
(on these, see below at para (263)) as MIH would go from having an indirect
presence in Spain through its minority stake in Glovo to occupying an important
market share with Just Eat. This could lead to an incentive for MIH to prevent
Glovo’s expansion, Glovo at the time being Spain’s second largest food delivery
platform.
111
In February 2022, the Spanish NCA unconditionally cleared Delivery
Hero’s acquisition of Glovo.
112
(84) In Romania, the recent Glovoappro/Foodpanda (2021) merger on the national
market for online food delivery platforms and the national market for online
platforms for delivery of multi-category consumer goods raised issues largely
identical to the ones resolved in the Spanish Just Eat/La Nevera Roja case: In that
case, the Romanian NCA was also concerned that, post-merger, the merged entity
would be in a dominant position and could use this position to impose exclusivity
obligations on restaurants. While users generally multi-homed on the online food
delivery platform market, such a strategy of exclusivity would foreclose other
109
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Just Eat/La Nevera Roja (C/0730/16, 31 March
2016).
110
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Just Eat Spain/Canary Delivery Company
(C/1046/19, 10 September 2019).
111
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, MIH Food Delivery Holdings/Just Eat
(C/1072/19, 5 December 2019).
112
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Delivery Hero/Glovo (C/1260/21, 23 February
2022). The same transaction was notified to the Portuguese, Polish and Romanian NCAs. The Portuguese
NCA found that Portuguese merger control was not applicable to the transaction; see Autoridade da
Concorrência, Delivery Hero/Glovo (Ccent. 61/2021, 25 January 2022).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
39
food delivery platforms. The acquisition was cleared subject to conditions (see
below, para (262)).
113
(85) In Schibsted/Milanuncios (2014), the Spanish NCA had to assess the horizontal
unilateral effects arising from the acquisition of Milanuncios by Schibsted.
Schibsted was a multinational media group, while Milanuncios was an online
platform specialised in classified advertisements. The NCA was concerned that
this acquisition could strengthen Schibsted’s market power vis-à-vis professional
advertisers, who would be faced with price increases for classified advertisements.
It cleared the acquisition subject to conditions (on these, see below at para
(258)).
114
(86) In eBay/Adevinta (2021), the Austrian NCA required commitments for this
transaction involving online classifieds based on its concern that eBay’s online
marketplace was a close competitor of the Austrian marketplace willhaben.at,
especially in respect of C2C
115
transactions. This became apparent through market
surveys and was also confirmed by internal documents of the parties. The market
was already concentrated, and in the eyes of the authority the risk of non-
coordinated effects was considerable. Commitments were necessary to clear this
acquisition (on these, see below at para (253)).
116
(87) When investigating the same merger, the UK NCA also raised concerns based on
horizontal unilateral effects, finding that eBay Marketplace was the largest
platform on the market, over twice the size of Facebook Marketplace, its next
biggest competitor. Gumtree, which belonged to eBay, was third or fourth
(depending on the metric), while Adevinta’s Shpock was relatively small but had
recently increased its competitive constraint on eBay Marketplace. The parties’
platforms were close competitors. Under eBay’s ownership, Gumtree had not
competed as aggressively as it could have. The NCA reasoned that part of eBay’s
motivation to sell Gumtree to Adevinta consisted in eBay continuing to exercise
some influence on that platform. The concentration was cleared subject to
conditions (on these, see below at para (252)).
117
(88) In Dante International/PC Garage (2016), the Romanian NCA investigated the
acquisition by Dante International, a company that provides an online platform
and also acts as a retailer thereon, of PC Garage, an online consumer goods
retailer. It concluded that the acquisition would further strengthen Dante’s market
position, and would therefore significantly impede effective competition in certain
products. It was only cleared subject to conditions (on these, see below at para
(250)).
118
(89) In NS Groep/Pon Netherlands (2020), the Dutch NCA investigated a joint venture
between NS, the largest provider of public transport by train in the Netherlands,
113
România Consiliul Concurenței, Glovoappro/Foodpanda (86/22.11.2021, 22 November 2021).
114
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Schibsted/Milanuncios (C/0573/14, 20
November 2014).
115
Consumer-to-consumer.
116
Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde, eBay/Adevinta (BWB/Z-5141, Z-5142, Z-5420 and Z-5421, 18 June 2021).
117
Competition & Markets Authority, Adevinta/eBay Classifieds Group (ME/6897/20, 16 February 2021).
118
România Consiliul Concurenței, Dante International/PC Garage (84/24.11.2016, 24 November 2016).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
40
and Pon, which produced and imported means of transport. The parties intended
to set up a full-function joint venture in the field of shared mobility through one
central mobile application and specific mobility hubs. The NCA considered that
the joint venture at issue did not raise concerns on horizontal unilateral effects, as
the (retail) market for the integrated provision of transport and mobility services
via an app was developing strongly, and the joint venture would experience
competitive pressure from both local providers of transport modalities and from
providers of integrated mobility services.
119
Commitments were required based
on vertical effects (on these, see below at para (257)).
(90) In Pug/StubHub (2020), the UK NCA focused on horizontal effects between two
close competitors in online exchange platforms for buying and selling tickets to
live events. Together, they would make up between 90-100% of the relevant
market post-merger, with an increment in the range of 30-40% due to the merger.
While Pug’s viagogo had had high market shares for a number of consecutive
years, StubHub had shown strong growth in previous years. There was no
meaningful competitor on the market for secondary ticketing platform services in
the UK, the platforms operated in similar ways and invested heavily in
advertising. viagogo was found to bid ‘on a sizeable proportion of StubHub’s
keywords’ on AdWords, indicating close competition among them. Resellers
regarded the parties as substitutes, and regularly multi-homed. The concentration
was cleared subject to conditions in phase 2 (on these, see below at para (251)).
120
(91) The national case law also allows insights into circumstances when horizontal
unilateral effects were not thought to arise despite the (also) horizontal nature of
the concentration. In a transaction involving two luxury online retailers,
Financière Richmond/Net-A-Porter (2015), the UK NCA noted that the increment
due to the acquisition would be small, and the two parties had different foci and
business models with differentiated offerings and a wide range of alternatives
no horizontal unilateral effects were therefore thought to arise.
121
A number of
cases relating to IT services did not, in the eyes of the Portuguese and Italian
NCAs, raise any competition concerns due to the small size of both acquirer and
target.
122
Three cases relating to online shopping services did not, according to the
Slovenian NCA, raise any competition concerns because of the low market shares
of the parties or the lack of a Slovenian presence of the acquirer.
123
Two
Hungarian cases, eMAG/Extreme Digital and Netrisk.hu/Biztosítás.hu (both
119
Autoriteit Consument & Markt, NS Groep/Pon Netherlands (ACM/20/038614, 20 May 2020).
120
Competition & Markets Authority, Pug/StubHub (ME/6868/19-II, 2 February 2021).
121
Competition & Markets Authority, Financière Richmond/Net-A-Porter (ME/6538-15, 2 September
2015).
122
Autoridade da Concorrência, KKR/Cabolink (Ccent. 41/2018, 8 November 2018); Autoritá Garante della
Concorrenza e del Mercato, OEP 14 Coöperatief/Techedge (28331, 4 August 2020); Autoridade da
Concorrência, Claranet Portugal/Bizdirect (Ccent. 27/2021, 25 June 2021); Autoridade da Concorrência,
Claranet Portugal/OutScope Solutions (Ccent. 38/2021, 24 August 2021).
123
Javna agencija Republike Slovenije za varstvo konkurence, ECE/ELTUS PLUS (3061-41/2018, 25 April
2019); Javna agencija Republike Slovenije za varstvo konkurence, Shoppster/IDEO PLUS (3061-9/2020-
14, 24 April 2020); Javna agencija Republike Slovenije za varstvo konkurence, Allegro.eu/MIMOVRSTE
(3061-25/2021-6, 24 January 2022)
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
41
2019), demonstrated that where online and offline markets can be considered part
of the same relevant market, NCAs may raise less competitive concerns because
of the constraining effect of one distribution channel on the other.
124
(92) Where acquirer and target were not close competitors before the concentration, or
where important competitors remained present post-merger, this would assuage
an NCA’s concerns.
125
Market transparency for consumers eg induced by online
comparison sites as well as multi-homing were seen as important factors to
counter-balance possible anti-competitive effects.
126
Competitive constraints
from outside the relevant market were not discarded, e.g., from restaurant-owned
delivery systems for online food ordering or from traditional point of sale
providers for online payment services.
127
(93) Where a market was understood to be dynamic, this would assuage competition
concerns.
128
The same applies to low barriers to entry and expansion, or the
readiness of customers to switch to alternative suppliers.
129
Whether or not an
online platform bound customers through exclusivity clauses was also considered
an important competitive factor.
130
(94) In technology markets, product differentiation could be such that a seemingly
horizontal overlap would not, ultimately, raise any competition concerns.
131
Also,
buyer power could act as a countervailing factor.
132
(95) In already concentrated online markets, NCAs would sometimes welcome a
merger because it could mean that the market would not tip. Multi-homing by
124
Gazdasági Versenyhivatal, eMAG/Extreme Digital (VJ/14/2019, 17 October 2019); Gazdasági
Versenyhivatal, Netrisk.hu/Biztosítás.hu (VJ/12/2019, 12 December 2019). This is also reminiscent of the
French Fnac/Darty merger, see Autorité de la concurrence, Fnac/Darty (16-DCC-111, 27 July 2016).
125
Eg, see Competition & Markets Authority, Betfair Group/Paddy Power (ME/6572/15, 17 December
2015); Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Paddy Power/Betfair (M/15/059, 15 January
2016); Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Ladbrokes/Gala Coral (M/16/007, 10 March
2016); Competition & Markets Authority, ZPG/Websky (ME/6690/17, 29 June 2017); Competition &
Markets Authority, Blackbaud/Giving (ME/6700/17, 8 September 2017); Autorité de la concurrence, Axel
Springer/Concept Multimédia (18-DCC-18, 1 February 2018); Competition & Markets Authority,
Moneysupermarket.com/Decision Technologies (ME/6749/18, 7 August 2018); Competition & Markets
Authority, eBay/Motors.co.uk (ME/6774/18, 12 February 2019); Competition & Markets Authority,
Salesforce.com/Tableau Software (ME/6841/19, 22 November 2019).
126
Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Stars Group/Sky Betting & Gaming (M/18/038, 18
June 2018); Competition & Markets Authority, Google/Looker (ME/6839/19, 13 February 2020);
Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Flutter Entertainment/Stars Group (M/20/001, 12
May 2020).
127
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Just Eat/La Nevera Roja (C/0730/16, 31 March
2016); Competition & Markets Authority, PayPal/iZettle (ME/6766/18-II, 12 June 2019).
128
Malta Competition and Consumer Affairs Authority, GVC Holdings/Ladbrokes Coral Group (COMP-
MCCAA/4/18, 21 March 2018); Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia,
Daimler/Hailo/MyTaxi/Negocio Hailo (C/0802/16, 24 November 2016).
129
Urząd Ochrony Konkurencji i Konsumentów, 1&1 Internet/Home.pl (DKK-216/2015, 22 December
2015).
130
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Just Eat/La Nevera Roja (C/0730/16, 31 March
2016); Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Daimler/Hailo/MyTaxi/Negocio Hailo
(C/0802/16, 24 November 2016).
131
Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Applied Materials/Kokusai Electric Corporation
(M/19/027, 11 October 2019).
132
Competition & Markets Authority, SK hynix/Intel (ME/6913/20, 28 June 2021).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
42
users or customers was equally seen as a remedy against market tipping.
133
NCAs
also took into account the peculiarities of specific online platforms, e.g., the fact
that network effects for online dating portals tended to be less pronounced because
users usually multi-homed and were not if the portal was successful locked in
for a long time,
134
or the fact that new competition was on the horizon in a
concentrated market.
135
(96) The presence of Big Tech companies such as Amazon, Apple, Facebook (now:
Meta), Google (now: Alphabet) or Microsoft was repeatedly held to constitute an
important factor when concluding that a digital acquisition by a non-Big Tech
company did not raise competition concerns.
136
(97) The possibility that a (smaller) national online market could be constrained by a
(larger) pan-European online market was taken into account in individual cases.
137
However, no horizontal unilateral effects were thought to arise despite a
horizontal overlap in the digital service concerned when two completely different
geographical markets (in casu: UK US) were concerned.
138
c. Discussion
(98) The 51 national cases in which loss of an actual competitor was considered as a
possible theory of harm show how this theory of harm can be and has been adapted
to digital and technology markets. In particular, the various factors that have been
considered by NCAs on a case-by-case basis allow a glimpse into how flexible
this theory of harm is. Multi-homing or dual vendor strategies are regularly
assessed, and the nature of competition in digital markets is considered in some
detail when the possibility of market tipping and the importance of network effects
is assessed.
(99) The four prohibitions and one withdrawal based on the loss of an actual competitor
occurred in diverse market settings, ranging from real estate platforms to online
ticketing, augmentative assistive communication and technology solutions for
airlines. This shows that this type of competition concern, which was the most
prevalent theory of harm applied in case of a prohibition, can arise in multiple
digital market settings. CTS Eventim/Four Artists (2017)
139
demonstrated how
several acquisitions in a row can lead to a situation where one further acquisition
133
Eg, see Bundeskartellamt, Axel Springer/Immowelt (B6-39/15, 20 April 2015).
134
Bundeskartellamt, OCPE II Master (Parship)/EliteMedianet (B6-57/15, 22 October 2015).
135
Competition & Markets Authority, Just Eat/Hungryhouse (ME/6659-16-II, 16 November 2017).
136
Eg, see Autorité de la concurrence, Axel Springer/Concept Multimédia (18-DCC-18, 1 February 2018);
Autorité de la concurrence, TF1/Aufeminin (18-DCC-63, 23 April 2018); Autoridade da Concorrência,
Sonae/CTT - Correios de Portugal JV (Ccent. 27/2018, 19 July 2018); Bundeskartellamt, PayPal/Honey
Science (B6-86/19, 17 December 2019); Autoriteit Consument & Markt, DPG/Sanoma (ACM/19/038207,
10 April 2020); Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Booster/Liftoff Mobile (M/21/002, 15
February 2021); Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Turnitin/Ouriginal Group
(C/1220/21, 19 October 2021).
137
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Turnitin/Ouriginal Group (C/1220/21, 19
October 2021).
138
Competition & Markets Authority, Auction Technology Group/Live Auctioneers (ME/6942/21, 29
September 2021).
139
Bundeskartellamt, CTS Eventim/FKP Scorpio (B6-53/16, 3 January 2017).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
43
can be seen as a red flag, while Tobii/Smartbox (2019)
140
provided a good
indication of when competition from non-specialised products may not be a
competitive constraint on a specialised product.
(100) Of the 9 conditional clearances that involved an analysis of the loss of an actual
competitor, 3 concerned food delivery platforms. A further 3 conditional
clearances related to classified advertising. Other cases that were cleared subject
to commitments related to online retailing, ticketing platforms, and a shared
mobility platform. Overall, this highlights areas in which competition concerns
appear to arise regularly, and that can be addressed through appropriate remedies.
(101) In the Austrian and UK Adevinta/eBay cases, it could be seen how competition
concerns can specifically relate to national players active on national online
markets, requiring different remedies in different settings. The competitive
constraints may need to be assessed differently depending on the national platform
landscape. This was also reflected in the respective commitments accepted in
those two cases.
(102) The research carried out for this Report has brought to light that it would be
beneficial to set out more clearly those factors that come into play when assessing
horizontal theories of harm in digital market environments in order to allow for a
more structured analysis. This, in particular, applies to multi-homing, multi-
sidedness, the presence of Big Tech in a market, the impact of product
differentiation, market transparency through online comparison sites, and the
assessment of closeness of competition in the face of data advantages that span
multiple markets. Also, the importance of product differentiation needs to be re-
evaluated in the face of ever-changing functionalities of digital platforms
something that might be assessed differently in technology markets.
(103) It would also be useful to establish under which circumstances market tipping
could be achieved or prevented by a digital merger.
141
(104) When comparing the national cases to a number of mergers cleared by the
European Commission, it becomes apparent that the factors on which those cases
rely upon are near-identical: As was the case in a number of national cases, the
European Commission in Avago/Broadcom (2015) relied on the combined market
share of the merged entity, the small increment that the transaction would lead to,
and a sufficient number of remaining suppliers to conclude that no horizontal
unilateral effects would arise.
142
Similarly, in Microsoft/GitHub (2018) the
Commission reasoned that the small horizontal overlap between the parties, the
fact that they were not close competitors and the number of remaining competitors
in software development and operations tools meant that horizontal unilateral
effects were unlikely to arise post-merger.
143
In Broadcom/Symantec Enterprise
Security Business (2019), the low combined market shares of the merged entity as
140
Competition & Markets Authority, Tobii/Smartbox (ME/6780/18-II, 15 August 2019).
141
Isabelle de Silva, ‘Assessing online platform mergers: Taking up the new challenges faced by the French
Competition Authority in the digital economy’ (N° 2-2018) Concurrences 39, paras 31 ff.
142
European Commission Decision of 23 November 2015, M.7686 Avago/Broadcom, paras 68 ff.
143
European Commission Decision of 19 October 2018, M.8994 Microsoft/GitHub, paras 81 ff.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
44
well as the competitive constraints from remaining competitors on the market and
the fact that acquirer and target were not close competitors also led the
Commission to conclude that no unilateral effects would arise.
144
(105) In the Facebook/WhatsApp (2014) merger, the European Commission found that
the merging parties were not close competitors based on differences in the
offerings of their consumer communication services.
145
With the benefit of
hindsight, it could be argued that this dynamic market setting may now be seen in
a somewhat different light, with the Federal Trade Commission indeed
retrospectively challenging this acquisition which it did not oppose under a
claim of monopolization,
146
an instrument that is not available in the EU.
(106) In digital merger cases, the creation and strengthening of a dominant position need
to be closely related to the market characteristics. As the European Commission
already pointed out in Microsoft/Skype (2011), market shares may not be good
indicators of market power in highly dynamic markets.
147
(107) The presence of Big Tech in certain markets was regularly seen as a countervailing
factor by NCAs. Interestingly, the European Commission also regarded the strong
presence of Google and Facebook in online advertising to act as a competitive
constraint on another Big Tech company namely Apple in Apple/Shazam
(2018).
148
In this regard, NCAs need to ensure that where Big Tech platforms are
not yet active on a given market, their entry in the foreseeable future is credible,
as otherwise their presence would not represent a competitive constraint on the
merged entity.
149
(108) Google’s and Facebook’s overbearing presence in online advertising was
repeatedly held by NCAs to constitute a factor that favours the clearance of a
digital merger in which Google was not a party.
(109) In the national cases that were assessed, none could be observed that assessed the
data advantage gained through the merger in as much depth as the European
Commission’s Google/Fitbit case of 2020.
150
This is further discussed below (para
(240)). It is possible, however, that national merger control is not yet to a large
extent confronted with cases where data advantages can be identified, especially
because the major Big Tech mergers generally come before the European
Commission, either directly or through a referral (Articles 4 and 22 EUMR).
144
European Commission Decision of 30 October 2019, M.9538 Broadcom/Symantec Enterprise Security
Business.
145
European Commission Decision of 3 October 2014, COMP/M.7217 Facebook/WhatsApp, paras 101
ff, 118 (referring to the market’s dynamism).
146
Federal Trade Commission v Facebook, US District Court for the District of Columbia, Case 1:20-cv-
3590 (11 January 2022).
147
European Commission Decision of 7 October 2011, COMP/M.6281 Microsoft/Skype, para 70-72, 78;
upheld in Case T-79/12 Cisco Systems and Messagenet v Commission, ECLI:EU:T:2013:635.
148
European Commission Decision of 6 September 2018, M.8788 Apple/Shazam.
149
de Silva (n 141) para 73.
150
European Commission Decision of 17 December 2020, M.9660 Google/Fitbit.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
45
ii. Coordinated effects
a. Specificities of the theory of harm
(110) A horizontal merger may change the market structure in a way that it becomes
‘possible, economically rational, and hence preferable’, for companies to reach a
common understanding aimed at increasing prices, limiting production or dividing
the market.
151
In order for such coordination to be sustainable, an authority will
assess three factors that need to be fulfilled cumulatively: the ability to monitor
competitors’ behaviour on the market (i.e., a certain transparency), the possibility
of a credible deterrent mechanism, and no possibility for third parties (customers
or competitors) to jeopardise the coordinated behaviour.
152
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers
(111) Only 4 of the 69 cases analysed in-depth concerned horizontal coordinated effects,
all of which were unconditionally cleared. In the majority of cases, these concerns
were discussed in relation with the loss of an actual competitor.
153
(112) In three German cases, horizontal coordinated effects were directly addressed. In
Axel Springer/Immowelt (2015), the Axel Springer group planned to acquire
Immowelt on the market for online real estate platforms. The German NCA
considered coordinated effects but concluded that the risk of collusion in a two-
sided market such as the one at issue (online real estate platforms) was lower than
in traditional markets, especially as the two remaining players one of which was
the merged entity had considerable structural differences.
154
Similarly, in
ProSiebenSat.1/Verivox (2015) the German NCA concluded that in a merger
involving comparison platforms for final consumer contracts, the merger would
reduce the likelihood of collusion between the merged entity and its main
competitor by leading to further asymmetries among them.
155
In
Parship/EliteMedianet (2015), the German NCA regarded the continued presence
of a varied field of competitors as a countervailing factor to possible coordinated
effects on the national market for online dating platforms.
156
c. Discussion
(113) The considerations found in national cases show that the characteristics of certain
multi-sided digital platform markets were thought to mitigate the risk of
horizontal coordinated effects, especially where asymmetries between the
remaining competitors were created through a merger.
151
European Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines 2004, para 39 (direct quote); Competition &
Markets Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 6.1.
152
European Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines 2004, para 41.
153
Eg, see Autorité de la concurrence, Axel Springer/Concept Multimédia (18-DCC-18, 1 February 2018).
154
Bundeskartellamt, Axel Springer/Immowelt (B6-39/15, 20 April 2015).
155
Bundeskartellamt, ProSiebenSat.1/Verivox (B8-76/15, 24 July 2015).
156
Bundeskartellamt, OCPE II Master (Parship)/EliteMedianet (B6-57/15, 22 October 2015).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
46
iii. Loss of a potential competitor non-coordinated or coordinated
effects
a. Specificities of the theory of harm
(114) The loss of potential or future competition is a further theory of harm in horizontal
mergers. While one merging party will already be active on a relevant market, the
other might only contemplate entry. In the eyes of the European Commission, this
theory of harm will only apply where the potential competitor already poses an
important competitive constraint or there is a significant likelihood for it to
become an important competitor.
157
Also, there will be no competition concerns
if other potential competitors could, post-merger, maintain the competitive
pressure.
158
(115) The UK’s Competition & Markets Authority highlights that either party may be
the potential competitor.
159
It also underscores that loss of dynamic competition
can be particularly problematic in digital platform markets, ‘where the costs and
time required to build up a significant user base and achieve network efficiencies
might involve years of losses’.
160
(116) The Competition & Markets Authority suggests assessing two questions when the
loss of potential competition is at issue, namely:
‘whether either merger firm would have entered or expanded absent the
merger, and
whether the loss of future competition brought about by the merger would
give rise to a[ substantial lessening of competition], taking into account other
constraints and potential entrants.’
161
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers
(117) In 6 of 69 cases analysed in-depth, the loss of a potential competitor was
addressed. Of these cases, 5 came from the UK alone. One such case led to
conditional clearance in phase 2, while another led to a prohibition; a further one
was conditionally cleared in phase 1.
(118) In Meta/Giphy, global technology company Meta (formerly Facebook), with
strong market positions in both social media and display advertising, acquired
Giphy, the world’s leading provider of free GIFs and GIF stickers. Markets
affected included the market for searchable GIF libraries, social media and display
advertising. Both the Austrian
162
and the UK
163
NCAs were concerned that the
acquisition at issue could stifle potential competition between Meta and Giphy for
advertising clients, as Giphy had rolled out a promising advertising service before
157
European Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines 2004, para 60.
158
European Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines 2004, paras 58-60.
159
Competition & Markets Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 5.1. Indeed, this is the
type of scenario it assessed in Competition & Markets Authority, Amazon/Roofoods (ME/6836/19-II, 4
August 2020), a case which preceded the current guidance.
160
Competition & Markets Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 5.4.
161
Competition & Markets Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 5.7.
162
Kartellgericht, 22 July 2021, 28 Kt 6/21y Meta/Giphy.
163
Competition & Markets Authority, Meta/Giphy (ME/6891/20-II, 6 December 2021).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
47
the acquisition that allowed it to monetise its services and that could have
competed with Meta’s display advertising services. In light of Meta’s significant
market power, both in the supply of social media and display advertising services,
the UK NCA considered that the acquisition of this potential competitor was
significant because Giphy not only had the potential to compete with Meta but
had also had plans to move into the UK market. Network effects in those markets
and high entry barriers namely related to interoperability and access to data
164
were equally considered. The UK NCA concluded that based on the acquisition
of a potential competitor, the acquisition would substantially lessen competition.
It required a full divestiture of Giphy (see also below, paras (285) f).
165
The case
was on appeal before the Competition Appeal Tribunal, which in June 2022
dismissed Meta’s substantive claims and only upheld part of its appeal relating to
the UK NCA’s failure to consult with the parties.
166
In order to remedy this
situation, the Competition Appeal Tribunal invite[d] the parties to consider what
consequential orders should be made
167
and it remains unclear how this issue will
be resolved. One possibility is for the UK NCA to consider its procedural
shortcomings and readopt its decisions after remedying them.
168
(119) Following an application from the Austrian NCA, the Austrian Cartel Court took
a different view and conditionally cleared Meta’s acquisition of Giphy subject to
access commitments (see para (255)). This conditional clearance was confirmed
by Austria’s Supreme Cartel Court in June 2022.
169
(120) The Meta/Giphy cases illustrate that while one NCA may view a remedy as
sufficient to address a particular competition concern, another NCA may reach a
different conclusion on the same matter. While these parallel cases were pursued
by one NCA from inside the EU and another from outside the EU, it is to be hoped
that no such inconsistencies would arise within the EU.
170
(121) In Adevinta/eBay Classifieds Group (2021), the UK NCA was concerned that the
concentration would hinder actual or potential competition between online
classified advertising platforms. The concentration was cleared subject to
conditions that included the divestiture of two services (on these, see below para
(252)).
171
164
In this respect, the UK NCA relied on its previous Market Study; Competition & Markets Authority,
Meta/Giphy (ME/6891/20-II, 6 December 2021) paras 28 f, 2.23 ff, 5.7 ff; Competition & Markets
Authority, ‘Online Platforms and Digital Advertising Market Study’ (July 2020).
165
Competition & Markets Authority, Meta/Giphy (ME/6891/20-II, 6 December 2021).
166
Meta/Giphy, [2022] CAT 26, 14 June 2022.
167
Meta/Giphy, [2022] CAT 26, 14 June 2022, para 177.
168
Victoria Ibitoye, ‘Meta scores procedural win in appeal of UK Giphy selloff order, but impact remains
to be seenMLex (14 June 2022)
<https://content.mlex.com/#/content/1385154?referrer=portfolio_openrelatedcontent>.
169
Kartellgericht, 22 July 2021, 28 Kt 6/21y Meta/Giphy; Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde, ‘Meta
(Facebook)/Giphy merger: AFCA appealing against conditional clearance’ (4 March 2022)
<https://www.bwb.gv.at/en/news/news-2022/detail/meta-facebook-giphy-merger-afca-appealing-against-
conditional-clearance>; Kartellobergericht, 23 June 2022, 16 Ok 3/22k and 16 Ok 4/22g Meta/Giphy.
170
Indeed, the parallel cases in Meta/Kustomer (EU and DE 2022) did not give rise to such an inconsistency.
171
Competition & Markets Authority, Adevinta/eBay Classifieds Group (ME/6897/20, 16 February 2021).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
48
(122) In Amazon/Roofoods (2020), the main theory of harm assessed by the UK NCA
concerned the loss of a potential competitor. After Amazon abandoned its market
presence in online restaurant platforms in the UK, it set out to acquire a 16%
shareholding in Deliveroo, a restaurant delivery platform. The NCA assessed
whether it would be likely absent the transaction that Amazon would re-enter
that market, given its strong and continued interest in the online restaurant
platforms market. It also assessed whether such entry would lead to greater
competition. The fact that Amazon would only acquire a 16% stake in Deliveroo,
rather than a larger one, was decisive in this case. This stake, together with the
rights associated with that stake and Amazon’s special status as strategic investor,
was considered to provide Amazon with the ability to exercise material influence
over Deliveroo’s commercial policy. Two scenarios were assessed by the NCA:
Concerning unilateral effects on the entry decision, the authority concluded that it
was not sufficiently likely that Amazon’s 16% stake in Deliveroo would keep it
from re-entering the market in the face of strong financial incentives to do so. The
NCA also assessed what unilateral effects could arise should Amazon re-enter the
market. While Amazon could adopt a strategy to compete less aggressively to
internalise Deliveroo’s profits, the 16% stake in Deliveroo would not provide a
strong enough incentive for this theory of harm to be credible or to influence
market outcomes. Amazon could also encourage Deliveroo to compete less
aggressively against it. However, the authority considered that there was strong
competition between Deliveroo, Uber Eats and Just Eat, limiting Deliveroo’s
scope to compete less strongly.
172
(123) In that same case, the UK NCA also considered possible horizontal unilateral
effects in the supply of online convenience grocery (OCG) shopping. The NCA
considered the offerings by Amazon and Deliveroo in OCG to be quite
differentiated. A number of competitors existed on that market, including online
restaurant delivery providers (e.g., Just Eat, Uber Eats), traditional grocers and
convenience stores (e.g., Waitrose, Sainsbury’s, Co-op), as well as grocery
delivery specialists (e.g., Ocado). Further expansion was to be expected, also
against the background of Covid-19. As a first theory of harm, the NCA assessed
(i) Amazon’s ability to discourage Deliveroo from competing against Amazon in
OCG. It then asked (ii) whether Amazon could protect its investment by avoiding
direct competition with Deliveroo in OCG. In both cases, it concluded that while
Amazon would have material influence on Deliveroo, its 16% stake would not
allow it to set Deliveroo’s policies single-handedly, and outside competition
would constrain it in doing so. Finally, the NCA assessed (iii) whether Amazon
could rely on Deliveroo for its presence in OCG rather than developing its own
service. Here, it was also considered that Amazon might regard the transaction as
a first step towards full acquisition of the target. Viewed within the broader
context of the OCG market, the NCA concluded that other competitors were well-
172
Competition & Markets Authority, Amazon/Roofoods (ME/6836/19-II, 4 August 2020).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
49
placed to compete in the OCG market and no substantiated competition concerns
would arise.
173
The transaction was unconditionally cleared.
(124) In PayPal/iZettle (2019), the UK NCA considered whether iZettle, a financial
technology company providing payment services to small businesses, would have
developed a more comprehensive offer competing with PayPal’s service, leading
to a situation in which potential competition was being eliminated through a
merger. It concluded, however, that absent the merger iZettle would have focused
on its core business rather than on developing such a comprehensive service.
174
The transaction was unconditionally cleared.
(125) In Uber International/GPC Computer Software (2021), Uber, a provider of ride-
hailing services, wanted to acquire GPC Computer Software (Autocab), a
company that (i) develops and supplies booking and dispatch technology (BDT)
enabling taxi companies to connect drivers to end customers, and that (ii) operates
the iGo network that connects demand for taxi trips with supply for taxi trips. The
UK NCA assessed whether the acquisition could lead to a loss of potential
competition. For this, it analysed whether GPC’s services would have developed
to compete with Uber’s services. It concluded that GPC was unlikely to develop
a stand-alone consumer-facing app that would directly compete with Uber’s app.
It was also unlikely that GPC’s iGo network would grow to become a significant
competitor to Uber.
175
The transaction was unconditionally cleared.
c. Discussion
(126) In the context of digital markets, the loss of potential competition may well
represent a theory of harm that competition authorities need to consider more
frequently. Where a digital platform buys a potential competitor in order to
prevent any competition from arising, this will necessarily affect innovation,
choice and the quality of services. As the national cases have shown, each case
needs to be assessed based on its specific facts in order to allow for a proper
appraisal of potential competition and the merger’s impact thereon.
(127) Concerns related to potential competition would be the area where one would
expect theories of harm related to so-called ‘killer acquisitions’ to be found, where
an acquirer uses M&A in order to kill off potential competitors. However, in
digital and technology markets, acquirers do not usually buy start-ups to actually
discontinue their innovation, but rather to incorporate their digital services and
capabilities into their own digital ecosystem. As such, killer acquisitions in
pharmaceuticals
176
cannot be likened to M&A in digital markets. Also, in the
national cases that were analysed, very few cases addressed this type of concern.
(128) In two cases in which the UK NCA assessed whether, absent the merger, the target
would have developed its digital services in a way so as to more fully compete
173
Competition & Markets Authority, Amazon/Roofoods (ME/6836/19-II, 4 August 2020).
174
Competition & Markets Authority, PayPal/iZettle (ME/6766/18-II, 12 June 2019).
175
Competition & Markets Authority, Uber International/GPC Computer Software (ME/6903/20, 29
March 2021).
176
On these, see Cunningham, Ederer and Ma (n 5).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
50
with the acquirer,
177
the NCA found that this was not a likely scenario because the
target would have more likely focused on its core business. This type of analysis
may come up more frequently in digital markets where a smaller company
requires its resources to keep its core business running, while bigger players often
have a broader portfolio that they can enrich by buying smaller (potential)
competitors.
(129) The Amazon/Roofoods case is particularly instructive as it highlighted how a
digital ecosystem’s acquisition of a digital platform could lead to competition
concerns in various related markets based on the capabilities of the acquirer.
While the low shareholding that Amazon set out to acquire led to the conclusion
that no competition concerns would arise, a higher stake may well have led to a
different outcome. This again confirms that a case-by-case analysis of factors
present in each individual case is necessary in order to appraise the consequences
of a particular merger for competition.
(130) The Commission emphasised the criteria it applies to the acquisition of a potential
competitor in Apple/Beats (2014), where it found that the acquisition of music
streaming service Beats by Apple would not eliminate a potential competitor that
was set to be a significant competitive constraint on Apple’s iTunes service.
178
iv. Other horizontal theories of harm
a. Specificities of the theory of harm
(131) Increasing the merged entity’s buyer power in an upstream market may constitute
an additional theory of harm in a horizontal context.
179
Furthermore, the
acquisition of commercially sensitive information in a horizontal context may also
raise competition concerns and can be analysed together with.
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers
(132) In only 5 of 69 cases, NCAs addressed horizontal theories of harm not covered by
the categories above. One such case was prohibited only based on such a theory
of harm, while another was cleared subject to conditions. 3 further cases were
unconditionally cleared.
(133) In the Meta/Giphy case (2022) that was conditionally cleared in Austria, the
Austrian NCA was concerned that by granting Meta access to sensitive
commercial information about competing online services based on other apps’
integrated interface with the Giphy library, anti-competitive effects could arise.
180
(134) In Meta/Kustomer (2021), Meta intended to acquire Kustomer, the provider of a
software as a service (SaaS) customer relationship management (CRM) software
that can be used for business to consumer (B2C) communications. Markets
177
Competition & Markets Authority, PayPal/iZettle (ME/6766/18-II, 12 June 2019); Competition &
Markets Authority, Uber International/GPC Computer Software (ME/6903/20, 29 March 2021).
178
European Commission Decision of 25 July 2014, COMP/M.7290 Apple/Beats, paras 35-40.
179
European Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines 2004, para 61.
180
Kartellgericht, 22 July 2021, 28 Kt 6/21y Meta/Giphy; Kartellobergericht, 23 June 2022, 16 Ok 3/22k
and 16 Ok 4/22g Meta/Giphy; Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde (n 169).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
51
affected included not only the market for the supply of B2C communication via
messaging channels but also the market for service and support related to CRM
software and the market for online display advertising. The UK NCA investigated
whether the acquisition could further strengthen Meta’s data advantage in online
display advertising, leading to higher barriers to entry and expansion and reduced
competition. While the authority emphasised Meta’s competitive advantage due
to its access to data, and while it also acknowledged that the merger would
increase that advantage, it underlined that additional data gains through Kustomer
would be small, due to its size and also taking into account its growth potential,
and wouldn’t raise competition concerns. The NCA also pointed to the possibility
for competitors to access similar data as Meta would gain through the acquisition.
The transaction was unconditionally cleared.
181
The European Commission only
cleared this transaction subject to conditions.
182
(135) In TF1/Aufeminin (2018), TF1, a major player in free and pay-TV, wanted to
acquire Aufeminin, a digital company amongst others involved in running
websites, online advertising and online retailing. The French NCA assessed
competitors’ concerns that post-merger, TF1 could use the data obtained through
Aufeminin to improve its monetisation of online advertising spaces. However, the
merged entity would have a very low coverage rate of the female population it
aimed at (between 5 and 7%), compared to coverage rates of 79% for Google and
68% for Facebook. Therefore, the NCA did not expect horizontal effects to arise
and the transaction was unconditionally cleared.
183
(136) In Parship/EliteMedianet (2015), the German NCA had considered that two
merging online dating portals were not close enough competitors for other non-
coordinated horizontal effects to arise.
184
(137) An entirely different concern was at stake in Magyar RTL Televízió/Central
Digitális Média (2017), where Magyar RTL Televízió (RTL) intended to acquire
30% of the shares of Central Digitális Média (CDM), providing RTL the right of
control over CDM. RTL was a member of the Bertelsmann group, which operates
a number of TV channels, provides broadcasting services and advertising time,
and operates several websites. CDM published online press products and
advertising space therein. The Hungarian NCA prohibited an acquisition based on
the media authority’s refusal to approve the concentration for reasons of media
pluralism (see also para (280)).
185
While the Metropolitan Court of Budapest as
the first instance court upheld the authority’s decision,
186
the Hungarian Supreme
Court annulled it and ordered the authority to conduct a new competition
181
Competition & Markets Authority, Meta/Kustomer (ME/6920/20, 27 September 2021).
182
European Commission Decision of 27 January 2022, M.10262 Meta/Kustomer.
183
Autorité de la concurrence, TF1/Aufeminin (18-DCC-63, 23 April 2018).
184
Bundeskartellamt, OCPE II Master (Parship)/EliteMedianet (B6-57/15, 22 October 2015).
185
Gazdasági Versenyhivatal, Magyar RTL Televízió/Central Digitális Média (Vj/87/2016, 24 January
2017).
186
Fővárosi Törvényszék, Magyar RTL Televízió/Central Digitális Média (21.K.700.023/2018/12, 8 June
2018).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
52
proceeding.
187
As the vendor subsequently abandoned the transaction, the
Hungarian NCA terminated these proceedings.
188
While these types of concerns
lie outside the scope of this Report, they are bound to arise more frequently as
digital media gains a stronger foothold.
c. Discussion
(138) In terms of other horizontal theories of harm, it can clearly be seen that the
strengthening of a data advantage is a common theme among a number of national
mergers from different jurisdictions. This is also confirmed when looking at other
vertical non-coordinated effects that equally focus on the data advantage that a
merger may strengthen (see below, paras (196), (237) ff). To become more
operational, data-related theories of harm would do well with a more in-depth
analysis and an elaboration of possible benchmarks for assessing when the
strengthening of a data advantage becomes such as to warrant intervention in a
merger case. The ubiquitous, non-rivalrous nature of data needs to be contrasted
with realistic opportunities for different players to access such data.
(139) At the national level, commitments based on data-related concerns have been
required, but not when the latter were raised as a possible horizontal concern but
rather when they were assessed under a vertical theory of harm or a conglomerate
theory of harm.
(140) By contrast, the European Commission has previously assessed the data
advantage an acquisition can give rise to under a horizontal theory of harm in
Google/Fitbit (2021), which will be further discussed below (para (240)). More
recently, this was also analysed in the 2022 conditional clearance of
Meta/Kustomer.
189
2. Vertical theories of harm
(141) Vertical effects arise in concentrations that involve companies that are active at
different levels of the supply chain, eg between a manufacturer and a retailer or
between the supplier of a raw material and a manufacturer.
190
A number of
theories of harm related to vertical mergers can be distinguished that are briefly
set out below, followed by an analysis of how these particular theories of harm
were applied in the digital and technology merger cases that were identified on a
national level. Where appropriate, parallels to European Commission cases are
drawn in the discussion that follows.
(142) In general, the approach to vertical and conglomerate mergers has been more
lenient as they do not lead to the loss of direct competition.
191
However, based on
the specific market characteristics in digital and technology sectors, this insight
187
Kúria, Magyar RTL Televízió/Central Digitális Média (Kf.IV.38.095/2018/10, 9 December 2019).
188
RTL continues to pursue this case before the Constitutional Court of Hungary.
189
European Commission Decision of 27 January 2022, M.10262 Meta/Kustomer.
190
European Commission, Guidelines on the assessment of non-horizontal mergers under the Council
Regulation on the control of concentrations between undertakings (Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines
2008) [2008] OJ C265/6, para 4.
191
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, para 11 f.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
53
now has to be questioned, and this conclusion is starting to be reflected in several
of the national cases discussed below.
i. Non-coordinated effects: Input foreclosure
a. Specificities of the theory of harm
(143) Input foreclosure occurs where the merged entity either refuses to supply its
downstream competitors with an input or does so on less favourable terms.
192
This
can in turn raise rivals’ costs, ultimately leading to higher prices for consumers.
To assess whether this type of competitive harm would arise, an authority will
assess the (a) ability and (b) incentive of the merged entity to engage in such
behaviour, as well as (c) the effects of such behaviour on competition
downstream.
193
(144) Concerning the ability to engage in input foreclosure, an authority will usually
assess whether the input concerned is important for the downstream product, e.g.,
because it is a critical component, a significant source of product differentiation
or because switching suppliers is costly. Concerns may arise when the vertically
integrated firm has significant market power in the upstream market.
194
Concerning the incentive to engage in input foreclosure, an authority will typically
assess whether this strategy would be profitable and whether the entity has
engaged in such strategies in the past.
195
While the impact of a foreclosure strategy
on competition is assessed as a final element with a particular emphasis on price
effects,
196
digital and technology markets may require different parameters
compared to more traditional markets. For instance, parameters may include the
access to data that is relevant for competition, the strengthening of a digital
ecosystem, and more.
(145) Input foreclosure will only be seen as problematic where it concerns an important
input for the downstream market, and where the merged entity has a significant
degree of market power upstream.
197
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers
(146) A total of 27 of 69 cases that were analysed in-depth assessed the possibility of
vertical input foreclosure following the merger, making this the most prevalent
vertical theory of harm addressed in the national cases under scrutiny. Of these,
12 cases also addressed a further vertical theory of harm, 20 cases also addressed
a horizontal theory of harm, and 5 also addressed a conglomerate theory of harm.
192
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, para 31; Competition & Markets
Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 7.9.
193
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, para 32; Competition & Markets
Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 7.10.
194
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, paras 33-35; Competition & Markets
Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 7.14.
195
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, paras 40-46; Competition & Markets
Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 7.19.
196
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, para 47.
197
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, paras 34-35.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
54
3 cases addressed all three types of harm. No case exclusively addressed vertical
input foreclosure.
(147) Of all cases that (also) concerned vertical input foreclosure, 2 concentrations were
prohibited, but always in combination with a horizontal theory of harm. 2 cases
led to remedies in phase 1 and a further 3 in phase 2. 18 concentrations were
unconditionally cleared in phase 1 and a further one in phase 2.
(148) The Swedish concentration of Swedbank Franchise/Svensk Fastighetsförmedling
(2014) was blocked because of concerns about vertical input foreclosure, among
others. After the acquisition, Swedbank Franchise would directly and indirectly
strengthen its influence over Hemnet, to the extent that it could change its business
model. Hemnet was the biggest Swedish portal for real estate advertisements. Not
only did Hemnet have high market shares, but it was also an unavoidable trading
partner. Barriers to entry for potential competitors were high, as Hemnet was
owned by real estate agents themselves and they would thus have no incentive to
support a new platform. Hemnet would have the ability and incentive to engage
in input foreclosure vis-à-vis competing real estate agents, e.g., by extracting
monopoly profits or by engaging in price differentiation. The Swedish NCA
concluded that this would significantly impede effective competition, the
Stockholm District Court concurred and a divestiture was ordered (see also para
(278)).
198
(149) Tobii/Smartbox (2019) was blocked by the UK NCA, among others due to vertical
input foreclosure effects. Concerning a possible input foreclosure of Smartbox’s
Grid software, the authority found that the merged entity would likely have both
the ability and incentive to rely on its strong market position in augmentative
assistive communication (AAC) software in order to foreclose downstream
competitors, e.g., by making their access to its popular software more expensive
or of lower quality. Due to consumer demand, downstream competitors were
unable to switch away from Smartbox’s software. The merger increased the
incentive to engage in such a foreclosure strategy. Another theory of harm relating
to input foreclosure of Tobii’s eye gaze cameras was dismissed because such a
strategy might lead to switching to alternative eye gaze cameras, which were
available on the market.
199
On the prohibition, see also paras (281) f.
(150) Vertical input foreclosure was one of the theories of harm that led the UK NCA
to prohibit the Meta/Giphy merger (2021) in phase 2. The UK NCA assessed
whether Meta could foreclose competitors in the market of social media services
by preventing their access to Giphy’s GIFs, a format that users of social media
platforms heavily relied on. Apart from Giphy, the only other comparable service
was Google’s Tenor. Post-merger, Meta would have the ability to engage in input
foreclosure. Based on the benefits awaiting Meta, it would also have the incentive
to do so because users wanting to use Giphy’s GIF library may very well switch
198
Stockholms tingsrätt, Swedbank Franchise/Svensk Fastighetsförmedling (T 3629-14, 16 December
2014).
199
Competition & Markets Authority, Tobii/Smartbox (ME/6780/18-II, 15 August 2019).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
55
to one of the Meta platforms. The NCA emphasised how network effects would
further amplify this effect and how the overall strategy would further strengthen
Meta’s market power in the supply of social media services and have a negative
impact on competition. The NCA also highlighted the dynamic nature of the
multi-sided markets at issue, which led to a lessening of competition on one
market (such as the supply of social media services) exacerbating anti-competitive
effects on another (such as the supply of display advertising). While Meta offered
commitments to the NCA, these were not regarded as sufficient and Meta was
therefore ordered to fully divest Giphy (see also below, paras (285) f).
200
The
Competition Appeal Tribunal almost entirely dismissed Meta’s appeal, and the
UK NCA together with the parties must now determine how to proceed based on
the lack of consultation that the Competition Appeal Tribunal has found.
201
(151) In the Austrian Meta/Giphy (2022) case, the NCA noted that the acquisition may
restrict non-discriminatory access to Giphy for other online services. On the
conditions for clearance imposed by the Cartel Court, see para (255) below. The
Cartel Court’s conditional clearance was confirmed by the Supreme Cartel Court
in June 2022.
202
(152) In CTS Eventim/Barracuda Holding (2019), CTS Eventim, a German provider of
ticketing and live entertainment with a strong market presence in Austria through
oeticket, wanted to acquire 71% of shares and sole control of Barracuda Holding,
an Austrian provider of concerts. The Austrian NCA was concerned that, post-
merger, the merged entity could engage in input foreclosure by making it harder
for ticketing providers to access organisers of live events. The concentration was
cleared subject to conditions (on these, see below at para (265)).
203
(153) The Dutch NCA considered input foreclosure in Sanoma/Iddink (2019). In that
case, Sanoma, a publisher of (digital) learning materials, wanted to acquire Iddink,
a distributor of (digital) learning materials and electronic learning environments
in secondary education. The NCA was concerned that the acquisition could
foreclose competitors of Iddink’s electronic learning environments by providing
preferential treatment or better compatibility with Sanoma products on the market
for issuing educational materials. As a result, competitors would become less
effective, barriers to entry would be raised and opportunities for innovation would
be harmed. In view of the digital nature of the market and the need for further
digitization in the educational resource chain, this would have a negative impact
on price, quality and innovation. The concentration was cleared subject to
conditions in phase 2 (on these, see below at para (256)).
204
(154) In NS Groep/Pon Netherlands (2020), the Dutch NCA assessed a range of vertical
relationships in a joint venture between the Netherlands’ main train service
200
Competition & Markets Authority, Meta/Giphy (ME/6891/20-II, 6 December 2021).
201
Meta/Giphy, [2022] CAT 26, 14 June 2022.
202
Kartellgericht, 22 July 2021, 28 Kt 6/21y Meta/Giphy; Kartellobergericht, 23 June 2022, 16 Ok 3/22k
and 16 Ok 4/22g Meta/Giphy.
203
Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde, CTS Eventim/Barracuda Holding (BWB/Z-4651, 3 December 2019).
204
Autoriteit Consument & Markt, Sanoma/Iddink (ACM/19/035555, 28 August 2019).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
56
provider (NS) and a producer of means of transport (Pon). The NCA believed that,
due to the joint venture, NS would have both the ability and the incentive to
engage in a partial input foreclosure strategy regarding its train services and the
integrated provision of transport and mobility services via an app. This could lead
to (i) the foreclosure of current providers of integrated mobility services via an
app, and (ii) raise barriers to entry into the national market for the integrated
provision of transport and mobility services via an app. Based on this, the
authority believed that the joint venture could result in a significant restriction of
competition, and only cleared it subject to conditions (on these, see below at para
(257)).
205
(155) In the case of Sully System/CENEJE (2018), the Slovenian NCA assessed whether
Sully System’s acquisition of Ceneje, a company active in the market of online
advertising through search engines and online price comparison, could lead to
input foreclosure in online price comparison or online non-food retail of consumer
goods.
Sully System was active in the latter market. As the merged entity would
have a market share of more than 30% in at least one relevant market, the NCA
assessed more closely whether the merged entity could discriminate between
offers of online retailers and use non-objective search and ranking algorithms of
online retail offers which would be preferential to the merged entity. The remedies
addressed these concerns (on these, see below at para (267)).
206
(156) In several cases, NCAs concluded that vertical input foreclosure was not a credible
theory of harm based on the low market shares post-merger and/or the competitive
constraint expected from competitors that would remain active on either the
upstream or the downstream markets.
207
A dual vendor strategy employed by
buyers was seen as a countervailing factor in technology markets,
208
similar to
multi-homing in digital markets. Where switching costs were not high, this was
also seen as an important strategy to counter vertical input foreclosure.
209
(157) In ProSiebenSat.1/Verivox (2015), the German NCA assessed a merger between
a media company (ProSiebenSat.1) and a comparison platform for consumer
contracts (Verivox). It assessed whether vertical input foreclosure may arise based
on the media company’s ability and incentive to grant Verivox better advertising
space at more favourable conditions than to competing comparison platforms,
thereby restricting effective competition. Verivox was the market leader, Check24
its main competitor, and both together held 95% of the market. ProSiebenSat.1’s
ability and incentive to engage in such input foreclosure would be restricted as it
would lose out on advertising revenue from Verivox’s competitors. Also, TV
205
Autoriteit Consument & Markt, NS Groep/Pon Netherlands (ACM/20/038614, 20 May 2020).
206
Javna agencija Republike Slovenije za varstvo konkurence, Sully System/CENEJE (3061-27/2017-71,
12 April 2018).
207
Autorité de la concurrence, Rakuten/Alpha Direct Services (13-DCC-08, 16 January 2013); Competition
and Consumer Protection Commission, EQT Fund Management/SUSE (M/18/066, 18 September 2018);
Bundeskartellamt, PayPal/Honey Science (B6-86/19, 17 December 2019).
208
Bundeskartellamt, Cisco Systems/Acacia Communications (B7-205/19, 6 February 2020).
209
Competition & Markets Authority, Uber International/GPC Computer Software (ME/6903/20, 29
March 2021).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
57
commercials at ProSiebenSat.1 were not the only advertising channels available
to Verivox’s competitors. In addition, sellers usually used several price
comparison platforms in parallel (multi-homing). The NCA therefore concluded
that this would not result in an appreciable restriction, also not through market
tipping. The transaction was unconditionally cleared.
210
(158) In four concentrations in the online gaming and betting sectors, the Irish NCA
assessed the possibility of vertical input foreclosure. In two cases, the provision
of live betting exchange data to online betting service providers was at issue, and
the NCA asked whether, post-merger, competing fixed-odds betting service
providers could be foreclosed by restricting their access to the merged entity’s live
betting exchange data. The Irish NCA found that this was unlikely, as the data did
not constitute an essential input for these providers; there was an array of
alternative sources for this data.
211
The UK NCA reached the same conclusion
when analysing one of these concentrations.
212
(159) In two further cases, the Irish NCA considered whether the concentration could
lead to the foreclosure of competing betting and gaming providers from access to
the merged entity’s odds comparison website. It concluded that the odds
comparison website would be unlikely to refuse to display competing offers, as
displaying multiple offerings is required for these types of sites. In addition, there
were several competing odds comparison services active on the market.
213
Concerning online affiliate marketing services, the Irish NCA concluded that
input foreclosure was unlikely to arise as there were many international online
market affiliates specialising in the gambling sector, a high number of competing
online fixed-odds betting providers and online gaming providers, and low market
involvement of the merged entity.
214
(160) In Sonae/CTT (2018), Sonae and CTT - Correios de Portugal (Post Portugal)
notified the creation of a joint venture dedicated to the operation of an e-commerce
platform for the provision of intermediation services between traders and
consumers. The Portuguese NCA
215
assessed whether the joint venture might
210
Bundeskartellamt, ProSiebenSat.1/Verivox (B8-76/15, 24 July 2015).
211
Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Paddy Power/Betfair (M/15/059, 15 January 2016);
Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Ladbrokes/Gala Coral (M/16/007, 10 March 2016).
Similarly, see also the conclusion on horse racing and football data provision in Competition and Consumer
Protection Commission, Flutter Entertainment/Stars Group (M/20/001, 12 May 2020).
212
Competition & Markets Authority, Betfair Group/Paddy Power (ME/6572/15, 17 December 2015). The
UK NCA had also investigated the Ladbrokes/Gala Coral merger and only cleared it subject to conditions
in phase 2. The competition concerns in that case, however, related to local betting offices rather than any
digital concerns. See Competition & Markets Authority, Ladbrokes/Gala Coral (ME/6556-15-II, 26 July
2016).
213
Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Stars Group/Sky Betting & Gaming (M/18/038, 18
June 2018); Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Flutter Entertainment/Stars Group
(M/20/001, 12 May 2020).
214
Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Stars Group/Sky Betting & Gaming (M/18/038, 18
June 2018); Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Flutter Entertainment/Stars Group
(M/20/001, 12 May 2020).
215
For the Portuguese experience, see also Tânia Luísa Faria, ‘Portugal’ in Daniel ndrescu (ed), EU
Competition Law and the Digital Economy: Protecting Free and Fair Competition in an Age of
Technological (R)Evolution (XXIX FIDE Congress 2020) 431, 433.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
58
engage in input foreclosure of other marketplaces. It concluded that Sonae, which
had a relatively high market share in certain retail markets (sporting goods,
consumer electronics), would not be able to terminate or deteriorate supply
conditions to customers that operated on the same market as the joint venture. It
would also not be able to stop reselling products to competing marketplaces.
Multiple competitors remained on the market that would constrain such a strategy
of input foreclosure. The joint venture was unconditionally cleared.
216
(161) In Turnitin/Ouriginal Group (2021), Turnitin, an international provider of a wide
range of software solutions for the educational sector, wanted to acquire sole
control over the Swedish Ouriginal Group, which is only active on the market for
plagiarism detection software. This transaction did not, in the eyes of the Spanish
NCA, raise vertical input foreclosure effects because of the low market shares of
the target and was unconditionally cleared.
217
In the UK, the UK NCA believed
that the same concentration would lead to horizontal unilateral effects, but applied
its de minimis exception due to the small nature of the case.
218
(162) The UK NCA assessed the possibility of vertical input foreclosure in a number of
cases. In ZPG/Websky (2017), ZPG, which owns a customer relationship
management (CRM) software for real estate agents as well as the online property
portal Zoopla, acquired Websky, which runs the CRM property software Expert
Agent. The UK NCA assessed whether the merged entity could engage in input
foreclosure of property portals in the vertical relationship between online property
portals such as Zoopla (downstream) and CRM property software (upstream). In
particular, it analysed whether the merged entity could degrade the quality of the
upload feed to property portals that are competing with Zoopla. However, the
NCA concluded that the merged entity would not have the ability to adopt a
foreclosure strategy vis-à-vis rival property portals due to the high number of
competitors operating on the market.
219
(163) In Moneysupermarket.com/Decision Technologies (2018),
Moneysupermarket.com agreed to acquire Decision Technologies. Both parties
supply digital comparison tool services for mobile and home communications
switching. Decision Technologies also operates upstream, providing white label
and application programming interface (API) services to providers of digital
comparison tools. The UK NCA found that the merged entity would have the
ability to foreclose digital comparison tool providers from the supply of white
label and API services, which were considered an important input. Decision
Technologies was the market leader and no entry was on the horizon. The NCA
then assessed a number of factors that would curtail the merged entity’s incentive
216
Autoridade da Concorrência, Sonae/CTT - Correios de Portugal JV (Ccent. 27/2018, 19 July 2018).
217
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Turnitin/Ouriginal Group (C/1220/21, 19
October 2021).
218
Competition & Markets Authority, Turnitin/Ouriginal (ME/6931/21, 26 July 2021).
219
Competition & Markets Authority, ZPG/Websky (ME/6690/17, 29 June 2017).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
59
to foreclose, and found that this strategy would not be profitable. The
concentration was unconditionally cleared.
220
(164) The Google/Looker (2020) concentration also involved the possibility of vertical
input foreclosure. Google, a global technology company, acquired Looker, a
provider of business intelligence (BI) tools, i.e. software that supports corporate
decision-making by analysing, visualising and interpreting business data. The UK
NCA assessed whether the merged entity could engage in a partial foreclosure
strategy based on Google’s substantial market power in web analytics and online
advertising. As Google generates a wealth of data, the authority assessed whether
Google could restrict competing BI tool providers from access to Google-
generated data. It found that Google would indeed have the ability to engage in
such an input foreclosure strategy: it is important to many businesses to be able to
analyse Google-generated data, Google has market power in web analytics and
online advertising and can offer a combined product possibly further enhancing
its market power, and it could implement various price- and non-price-based
foreclosure mechanisms to restrict access to Google-generated data. The NCA did
not consider that Google had an incentive to engage in such a strategy, however.
Its internal documents did not reveal any plans to carry out such a strategy.
Switching by customers may to some extent hamper the profitability of such a
strategy. Targeting individual competing BI tools with such a strategy would also
be costly. The concentration was unconditionally cleared.
221
(165) In Meta/Kustomer (2021), the UK NCA also assessed vertical input foreclosure.
In particular, it analysed whether Meta could foreclose other providers of
customer relationship management (CRM) software by restricting or degrading
their access to Meta’s messaging channels. This is because CRM providers require
Meta APIs to integrate them into their software. While Meta would have the
ability to engage in such foreclosure, the authority did not find evidence that it
had a sufficient incentive for this strategy. B2C
222
messaging was growing, and
such a foreclosure strategy would cut Meta off from revenue-generating CRM
providers, as not all customers would switch to relatively small Kustomer. The
CMA found it unlikely that such a foreclosure strategy would result in gains
exceeding the losses. The CMA also considered that a foreclosure strategy which
would target close competitors of Kustomer would not have been possible. The
transaction was unconditionally cleared.
223
c. Discussion
(166) Vertical input foreclosure is a frequently encountered theory of harm in digital
and technology mergers on a national level. While regularly dismissed based on
remaining competitive constraints or a lack of market power on any relevant
220
Competition & Markets Authority, Moneysupermarket.com/Decision Technologies (ME/6749/18, 7
August 2018).
221
Competition & Markets Authority, Google/Looker (ME/6839/19, 13 February 2020).
222
Business-to-consumer.
223
For the European Commission’s contrary findings on this issue, which led to a conditional clearance of
the same merger, see European Commission Decision of 27 January 2022, M.10262 Meta/Kustomer.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
60
market, this theory of harm has led to remedies in a number of national mergers,
although usually not on a stand-alone basis.
224
(167) Particularly in Ireland, but also in the UK, the growing importance of online
betting and gaming has also come within the purview of the NCAs, and digital
aspects are increasingly considered an important factor to consider in mergers in
that sector. At the same time, it was seen that this sector currently appears to be
competitive enough to allow for further concentration. This shows how sectors
that were previously regarded as non-digital can (partially) morph into digital
sectors, at which point know-how regarding how to analyse digital cases becomes
essential.
(168) Against the background of the national cases analysed for this Report, it seems
that it could be useful if the particularities of vertical input foreclosure in digital
and technology markets were spelled out more clearly in soft law guidance,
especially as regards the ability of the other market side to switch or multi-home
and the questions of vertical integration and of credible competition. The incentive
to engage in input foreclosure also needs to be seen in the context of a digital
ecosystem, which can lead to multiple incentives in various markets coming
together.
225
(169) In the vast majority of cases analysed, not all three cumulative criteria for finding
a credible strategy of input foreclosure were fulfilled, leading to a dismissal of
this type of theory of harm. This was also seen in a number of Commission
decisions in which vertical input foreclosure was dismissed.
226
(170) In the European Meta/Kustomer (2022) case, the European Commission carried
out a similar analysis to that of the UK NCA but was concerned that Meta could
engage in input foreclosure of Kustomer’s competitors by denying or degrading
access to APIs for Meta’s various messenger functionalities. It only cleared the
acquisition subject to two commitments: Meta guaranteed non-discriminatory
access to its publicly available APIs for its messaging channels to competing
customer service CRM software providers and new entrants i.e., companies
competing with Kustomer , and would also make available to them
improvements in Meta’s messenger functionalities that Kustomer’s customers use
today.
227
In Germany and the UK, this acquisition was unconditionally cleared.
228
The Commission had issued its conditional clearance while the German NCA’s
224
But see, on the European level, European Commission Decision of 27 January 2022, M.10262
Meta/Kustomer.
225
On this, see European Commission Decision of 27 January 2022, M.10262 Meta/Kustomer.
226
Eg, European Commission Decision of 17 December 2020, M.9660 Google/Fitbit, paras 570-610,
611-648, 649-679, 680-709; European Commission Decision of 6 December 2016, M.8124
Microsoft/LinkedIn, paras 246-277, 370-381. It is also noteworthy how in Microsoft/LinkedIn, vertical and
conglomerate foreclosure effects were assessed in close proximity, highlighting how these two cannot be
easily separated in digital market environments.
227
European Commission, ‘Mergers: Commission clears acquisition of Kustomer by Meta (formerly
Facebook), subject to conditions’ IP/22/652 (27 January 2022); European Commission Decision of 27
January 2022, M.10262 Meta/Kustomer.
228
Competition & Markets Authority, Meta/Kustomer (ME/6920/20, 27 September 2021);
Bundeskartellamt, Meta/Kustomer (B6-21/22, 11 February 2022).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
61
review was still ongoing, and the German NCA took the Commission’s findings
and the commitments accepted by the Commission into account when
unconditionally clearing the transaction.
229
ii. Non-coordinated effects: Customer foreclosure
a. Specificities of the theory of harm
(171) A second type of foreclosure a vertical merger may give rise to is customer
foreclosure, whereby the merged entity forecloses access to customers for its
upstream competitors, thereby cutting off or hindering their access to the
market.
230
It can do so by sourcing all its requirements from its own upstream
operation, by reducing its purchases from an upstream competitor or by buying
from upstream competitors on less favourable terms.
231
This increases rivals’
costs, possibly leading to higher prices for consumers or reduced innovation.
(172) To assess whether this type of competitive harm would arise, an authority will
assess the (a) ability and (b) incentive of the merged entity to engage in such
behaviour, as well as (c) the effects of such behaviour on competition
downstream.
232
Concerning the ability to engage in customer foreclosure, an
authority may particularly want to consider the size of the customer and the
importance of scale upstream.
233
(173) Such foreclosure would also deter entry on the upstream market and put
competitors on the downstream market at a competitive disadvantage.
234
(174) Competition concerns related to customer foreclosure would only arise where the
merged entity is an important customer with a significant degree of market power
in the downstream market.
235
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers
(175) A total of 11 of the 69 cases analysed in-depth contained an assessment of
customer foreclosure. Only in one case namely CTS Eventim/Four Artists
236
was this the only vertical theory of harm assessed (in addition to a horizontal
theory of harm). In 6 cases, no horizontal theories of harm were assessed in
addition to vertical (or vertical and conglomerate) theories of harm.
(176) Of the cases that assessed vertical customer foreclosure, 2 led to a prohibition and
3 to conditional clearance (2 in phase 1, 1 in phase 2). The remaining
concentrations were unconditionally cleared.
229
Bundeskartellamt, ‘Bundeskartellamt clears acquisition of Kustomer by Meta (formerly Facebook)’
Press Release (11 February 2022)
<https://www.bundeskartellamt.de/SharedDocs/Meldung/EN/Pressemitteilungen/2022/11_02_2022_Meta
_Kustomer.html>.
230
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, para 58; Competition & Markets
Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 7.23.
231
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, para 60.
232
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, para 59.
233
Competition & Markets Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 7.26.
234
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, paras 64, 72.
235
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, para 58.
236
Bundeskartellamt, CTS Eventim/Four Artists (B6-35/17, 23 November 2017).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
62
(177) In Tobii/Smartbox (2019), a case involving augmentative assistive
communication (AAC) solutions, the UK NCA found that the merged entity
would likely have both the ability and incentive to limit the compatibility of eye
gaze cameras produced by the acquirer’s competitors with the target’s popular
software. This strategy would be profitable as AAC solution providers were not
very likely to switch to an alternative software in order to use an alternative eye
gaze camera. This foreclosure strategy would lead to lower innovation in eye gaze
cameras and higher prices. The acquisition was prohibited (see also paras (281)
f).
237
(178) In CTS Eventim/Four Artists (2017),
238
the German NCA prohibited an
acquisition based on the finding that it would (also) have further strengthened
customer foreclosure: While an acquisition by CTS Eventim, a company active in
live entertainment, earlier that same year had been unconditionally cleared in
phase 2,
239
the NCA believed that this further acquisition would contribute to CTS
Eventim’s strategy of customer foreclosure to the detriment of competition. CTS
Eventim’s competitors already had restricted access to customers, both because
of CTS Eventim’s vertical integration and because of CTS Eventim’s exclusivity
clauses with event organisers. On the prohibition, see also para (279).
(179) In a further case involving CTS Eventim, CTS Eventim/Barracuda Holding
(2019), the Austrian NCA was concerned that, post-merger, the merged entity
could engage in customer foreclosure by providing its ticketing services at above
market prices to companies that do not belong to the CTS Eventim group.
240
This
concentration was cleared subject to conditions (on these, see below at para
(265)).
(180) In NS Groep/Pon Netherlands (2020), the Dutch NCA concluded that it was not
plausible that NS would have the ability and incentive to implement a customer
foreclosure strategy vis-à-vis providers of bicycle-sharing and providers of car-
sharing. The joint venture was cleared subject to conditions based on concerns
related to vertical input foreclosure (on the remedies, see below at para (257)).
241
(181) The French NCA considered possible customer foreclosure in Rakuten/Alpha
Direct Services (2013). In that case, Rakuten, which is active in e-commerce
through its electronic marketplace PriceMinister and several price comparison
websites, wanted to acquire exclusive control over Alpha Direct Services, a
company specialising in inbound logistics services for e-commerce and catalogue-
based distance selling. The NCA concluded that customer foreclosure was
unlikely to arise based on the many different sellers that the target provided its
services to, the number of important competitors in e-marketplaces, and the lack
237
Competition & Markets Authority, Tobii/Smartbox (ME/6780/18-II, 15 August 2019).
238
Bundeskartellamt, CTS Eventim/Four Artists (B6-35/17, 23 November 2017).
239
Bundeskartellamt, CTS Eventim/FKP Scorpio (B6-53/16, 3 January 2017).
240
Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde, CTS Eventim/Barracuda Holding (BWB/Z-4651, 3 December 2019).
241
Autoriteit Consument & Markt, NS Groep/Pon Netherlands (ACM/20/038614, 20 May 2020).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
63
of exclusivity contracts by the acquirer’s marketplace. The transaction was
unconditionally cleared.
242
(182) Two Irish cases considered both vertical input and vertical customer foreclosure.
In Stars Group/Sky Betting & Gaming (2018), the Irish NCA considered whether
the merged entity could foreclose competing odds comparison services from
accessing customers, or whether it could foreclose competing online affiliate
marketing services from accessing customers. It concluded that based on the
multiple players active on the market, neither would materialise. The transaction
was unconditionally cleared.
243
(183) The case of Sonae/CTT (2018) also related to possible customer foreclosure by
the joint venture creating an e-commerce platform. There, the Portuguese NCA
found it unlikely that the owners of the joint venture would adopt a strategy of
customer foreclosure by preventing one of the partiescompetitors from providing
services to the joint venture or reselling its products on the new marketplace. This
would prevent the success of a marketplace, which requires two market sides to
come on board.
244
(184) Under a possible theory of harm related to vertical customer foreclosure, the UK
NCA assessed in Meta/Kustomer (2021) whether Meta could foreclose other B2C
messaging services by preventing them from integrating their services with
Kustomer. As Kustomer was a small provider specialised in serving small and
medium-sized businesses, and many alternative providers would remain on the
market, this was not seen as a credible theory of harm, either. The transaction was
unconditionally cleared.
245
(185) The presence of a sufficient number of competitors on one of the relevant markets
was regularly seen as mitigating any vertical effects.
246
Low turnover was also
sometimes seen as hindering a company’s ability to foreclose competitors.
247
c. Discussion
(186) Vertical customer foreclosure is a theory of harm that was not seen as a credible
threat to competition in many national cases. The analysis related to customer
foreclosure is often very price-centric. For digital and technology mergers, further
parameters of competition such as privacy, quality, choice and innovation
would need to be focused on more carefully in order to ensure that the multi-
dimensional nature of competition is depicted in the merger analysis.
(187) It is interesting to note how in Sonae/CTT, the two-sided nature of a market was
regarded as an intrinsic countervailing factor that would render a strategy based
242
Autorité de la concurrence, Rakuten/Alpha Direct Services (13-DCC-08, 16 January 2013).
243
Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Stars Group/Sky Betting & Gaming (M/18/038, 18
June 2018).
244
Autoridade da Concorrência, Sonae/CTT - Correios de Portugal JV (Ccent. 27/2018, 19 July 2018).
245
Competition & Markets Authority, Meta/Kustomer (ME/6920/20, 27 September 2021). Note that in the
European Union, this concentration was only conditionally cleared by the European Commission Decision
of 27 January 2022, M.10262 Meta/Kustomer.
246
Eg, see Bundeskartellamt, PayPal/Honey Science (B6-86/19, 17 December 2019).
247
Eg, see Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, EQT Fund Management/SUSE (M/18/066,
18 September 2018).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
64
on customer foreclosure futile. Vertical integration and exclusivity contracts
already concluded on a relevant market, on the other hand, were seen as factors
contributing to a successful customer foreclosure strategy.
(188) In the Austrian and German cases involving CTS Eventim, it was seen how very
similar concerns arose in those cases based on the market power CTS Eventim
held in ticketing services, although these concerns were resolved specifically with
a view to the national markets concerned.
iii. Other non-coordinated effects
a. Specificities of the theory of harm
(189) In terms of other non-coordinated effects arising from unilateral behaviour of the
merged entity, a vertical merger can lead the merged entity to obtain access to
commercially sensitive information that may allow it to compete less aggressively
or to put competitors at a competitive disadvantage.
248
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers
(190) Only 4 of the 69 cases analysed in-depth discussed other vertical unilateral effects,
but 3 of these cases led to commitments.
(191) In Rockaway Capital/Heureka (2016), private equity company Rockaway Capital
intended to acquire control of Heureka.cz, a Czech comparison shopping website,
and other online businesses. The Czech NCA was concerned that post-merger
comparison shopping site Heureka.cz could ask Rockaway’s online shops to
collect excessive amounts of data about their users, data that could then be used
in the interest of Rockaway Capital’s businesses.
249
This concern was explicitly
addressed in the commitments offered by Rockaway (on these, see para (266)
below).
(192) In Sanoma/Iddink (2019), the Dutch NCA considered it plausible that the merged
entity would have access to commercially sensitive information from competitors
after the proposed concentration, giving it an advantage over its competitors and
possibly impeding competition in the market for the issuance of teaching materials
in secondary education. The acquisition was cleared subject to conditions (on
these, see para (256) below).
250
(193) In the Slovenian case of Sully System/CENEJE (2018), the NCA also raised the
concern that the acquisition could provide the acquirer with access to
commercially sensitive information regarding competitors’ activities in the
downstream market, and cleared it subject to conditions (on these, see para (267)
below).
251
248
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, para 78; Competition & Markets
Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 7.3.
249
Úřad pro ochranu hospodářské soutěže, Rockaway Capital/Heureka (ÚOHS-S0013/2016/KS-
21123/2016/840/DVá, 16 May 2016).
250
Autoriteit Consument & Markt, Sanoma/Iddink (ACM/19/035555, 28 August 2019).
251
Javna agencija Republike Slovenije za varstvo konkurence, Sully System/CENEJE (3061-27/2017-71,
12 April 2018).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
65
(194) In Uber International/GPC Computer Software (2021), the UK NCA assessed
whether the acquisition would give Uber access to commercially sensitive
information about competitors that would allow it to compete more aggressively.
However, the NCA considered that more intense competition would, in fact, be
beneficial and in any case, competing taxi companies could switch to other
booking and dispatch technology providers in case the merged entity engaged in
such conduct. The transaction was unconditionally cleared.
252
(195) A further case that involved other vertical unilateral effects was the UK
esure/Gocompare.com case (2015),
253
where the UK NCA raised the issue that
the acquirer might gain access to commercially sensitive information through the
target’s price comparison website, allowing it to either increase its margins or gain
a competitive advantage, eg by enabling it to back-estimate competitors’ pricing
algorithms or increase prices.
254
In this particular case, the authority concluded
that this was not likely to occur and the transaction was unconditionally cleared.
255
c. Discussion
(196) Access to commercially sensitive information, and to user data in particular, has
only been identified as a competition concern in a limited number of cases but
has led to dedicated remedies. In digital markets that centre around user data, it
would not be surprising to see this type of theory of harm resurface more
frequently. This is further discussed below (see paras (237) ff).
(197) In Apple/Shazam (2018), the European Commission found that the acquisition
would give Apple access to commercially sensitive information about competitors
of its Apple Music service, and in particular music streaming service Spotify.
However, it regarded it as ‘unclear whether the merged entity would be able to
put competing providers of digital music streaming apps at a competitive
disadvantage’ and underlined that the processing of personal data remained
subject to the General Data Protection Regulation.
256
It was also not certain that
Apple would have the incentive to use such data to disadvantage competitors.
257
(198) It is notable that such a reference to data protection rules is absent in the national
merger cases analysed in-depth.
258
252
Competition & Markets Authority, Uber International/GPC Computer Software (ME/6903/20, 29
March 2021).
253
This case was not selected for in-depth analysis.
254
Competition & Markets Authority, esure Group/Gocompare.com (ME/6495-14, 23 February 2015).
255
Competition & Markets Authority, esure Group/Gocompare.com (ME/6495-14, 23 February 2015),
para 82.
256
Regulation (EU) 2016/679 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 27 April 2016 on the
protection of natural persons with regard to the processing of personal data and on the free movement of
such data, and repealing Directive 95/46/EC (General Data Protection Regulation, GDPR) [2016] OJ
L119/1.
257
European Commission Decision of 6 September 2018, M.8788 Apple/Shazam, paras 196 ff (direct
quote at para 221).
258
But see, in a case on a possible abuse of a dominant position based on an infringement of data protection
rules when collecting users’ data, Bundeskartellamt, Facebook (B6-22/16, 6 February 2019); questions on
this case have now been referred to the Court of Justice by the Oberlandesgericht Düsseldorf; Case C-
252/21, Meta Platforms/Bundeskartellamt [2021] OJ C320/16 (pending).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
66
iv. Coordinated effects
a. Specificities of the theory of harm
(199) Just like a horizontal merger, a vertical merger may also alter the market structure
so as to allow companies to reach a common understanding aimed at increasing
prices, limiting production or dividing the market.
259
In order to find whether such
coordination is sustainable, an authority will assess the same three factors as set
out for horizontal coordinated effects: the ability to monitor competitors’
behaviour on the market (i.e., a certain transparency), the possibility of a credible
deterrent mechanism, and no possibility for third parties (customers or
competitors) to jeopardise the coordinated behaviour.
260
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers
(200) Not one out of the 69 cases analysed in-depth discussed such a theory of harm.
(201) Recently, the agreement between Google and Apple to ensure that Google Search
remains the default search engine on Apple devices running on the iOS operating
system has been cast in the antitrust spotlight.
261
The prospect of such an
agreement between the merged entity and other technology companies could be
considered as a possible coordinated effect in a conglomerate or also vertical
merger.
3. Conglomerate theories of harm
(202) Conglomerate effects may arise in concentrations that involve companies that are
not connected either horizontally or vertically. Competition concerns are
especially thought to arise where the companies involved operate in closely
related markets, eg where products are complementary.
262
(203) A number of theories of harm related to conglomerate mergers can be
distinguished that are briefly set out below, followed by an analysis of how these
particular theories of harm were applied in the digital and technology merger cases
that were identified on a national level. Where appropriate, parallels to European
Commission cases are drawn in the discussion that follows.
i. Non-coordinated effects: Foreclosure
a. Specificities of the theory of harm
(204) Competition concerns can arise in a conglomerate merger when a merged entity
utilises its market power on one market as leverage to gain market power in
another market, eg by linking the sale of its products.
263
Possibilities include
259
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, paras 79 ff.
260
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, paras 79 ff.
261
See Daisuke Wakabayashi and Jack Nicas, ‘Apple, Google and a Deal That Controls the Internet’ New
York Times (25 October 2020). This deal is being challenged in US v Google, US District Court for the
District of Columbia, Case 1:20-cv-03010 (complaint brought on 20 October 2020, amended on 15 January
2021).
262
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, para 5.
263
See Competition & Markets Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 7.8(c).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
67
(technical or contractual) tying and (mixed or pure) bundling, including certain
rebate schemes.
(205) To assess whether this type of competitive harm would arise, an authority will
assess the (a) ability and (b) incentive of the merged entity to engage in such
behaviour, as well as (c) the effects of such behaviour on competition
downstream.
264
(206) Concerning the ability to foreclose through linking products, the characteristics of
a product and how it is purchased are relevant.
265
The Commission has
emphasised that foreclosure concerns only arise where the merged entity has
considerable market power but not necessarily beyond the threshold of
dominance in one of the affected markets.
266
Economies of scale and network
effects can make conglomerate foreclosure effects more pronounced.
267
Further
factors to consider include the feasibility of a combined offering and the loss of
sales by rivals.
268
A conglomerate’s foreclosure practices may negatively affect
potential entry.
269
Overall, the Commission believes that such foreclosure will
only be anti-competitive if it affects a ‘sufficiently large fraction of market
output’.
270
(207) The UK’s Competition & Markets Authority has emphasised that foreclosure
strategies related to conglomerate mergers may be particularly concerning in
digital markets.
271
For instance, a foreclosure strategy may raise competition
concerns where a product is integrated within a digital ecosystem, thereby
effectively reinforcing the platform’s digital ecosystem.
272
While competition law
does not primarily focus on the welfare of competitors, this type of ecosystem
integration can effectively ensure that (potential) competitors cannot expand and
the merged entity’s market power is strengthened.
273
A particular difficulty lies in
the fact that ‘these anticompetitive effects may not emerge in full until after the
market has reached maturity’, leading to considerable uncertainty in the
analysis.
274
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers
(208) A total of 15 of the 69 cases analysed in-depth assessed conglomerate theories of
harm related to possible foreclosure effects. 7 of these also concerned horizontal
effects, 3 of these also concerned horizontal and vertical effects, and a further 3
264
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, para 94; Competition & Markets
Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 7.32.
265
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, para 98.
266
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, para 99.
267
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, para 101.
268
Competition & Markets Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 7.33.
269
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, para 112.
270
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, para 113; see also Competition &
Markets Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, paras 7.35 ff.
271
Competition & Markets Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 7.37.
272
Competition & Markets Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 7.30.
273
Competition & Markets Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 7.31.
274
Competition & Markets Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines 2021, para 7.37.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
68
also concerned vertical but no horizontal effects. 2 cases exclusively related to
conglomerate effects, namely the UK case of Advanced Micro Devices/Xilinx
(2021)
275
and the Greek case of Delivery Hero (2022).
276
Only 3 concentrations
were cleared subject to conditions, one in phase 1 and two in phase 2. The
remaining 12 concentrations were unconditionally cleared, 10 in phase 1 and 2 in
phase 2.
(209) In Rockaway Capital/Heureka (2016), the Czech NCA was concerned that, post-
merger, comparison shopping site Heureka.cz would give preferential treatment
to online businesses already controlled by the acquirer, Rockaway Capital,
thereby foreclosing competitors. Heureka.cz had a market share between 45-55%.
The concentration was cleared subject to conditions that addressed this concern
(see below, para (266)).
277
(210) In Delivery Hero (2022), Delivery Hero operated e-food, the leading online food
delivery platform in Greece. It wanted to acquire a range of companies, namely
Alfa Distributions, which is active in the wholesale supply of consumer goods to
supermarkets; Inkat, which is active in the wholesale supply of groceries and
operates a retail grocery store chain; Delivery.gr, which provides online
intermediation services for restaurants, supermarkets, convenience stores and
other local stores; and E-table, which provides online intermediation services for
reservations in restaurants. The NCA only assessed conglomerate theories of harm
and found that by combining the acquirer’s online food ordering platform (e-food)
with the targets’ online intermediation services, conglomerate effects would arise.
Both E-table and Delivery Hero had significant market power in their respective
Greek markets. Post-merger, conglomerate foreclosure effects through bundling
were likely to arise, as the merged entity would have the ability and incentive to
bundle their services for business users. A further concern voiced by the authority
related to the combination of data sets from both services that would allow for
targeted advertisements with which no competitors could effectively compete.
The concentration was cleared subject to conditions (see below, para (264)).
278
(211) Concerning a possible foreclosure strategy through bundling between the
acquirer’s digital learning materials and the target’s distribution of such learning
materials and the provision of electronic learning environments, the Dutch NCA
in Sanoma/Iddink (2019) found that the parties could not profitably implement
such a strategy based on the limited income resulting from it. The case was cleared
subject to conditions based on other theories of harm (see para (256)).
279
In the
later case of DPG/Sanoma (2020), DPG intended to acquire Sanoma. DPG was
active in the field of news media, including the publishing of newspapers and
275
Competition & Markets Authority, Advanced Micro Devices/Xilinx (ME/6915/20, 29 June 2021).
276
Επιτροπή Ανταγωνισμού, Delivery Hero/Alfa Distributions/Inkat/Delivery.gr/E-table (775/2022, 18
April 2022).
277
Úřad pro ochranu hospodářské soutěže, Rockaway Capital/Heureka (ÚOHS-S0013/2016/KS-
21123/2016/840/DVá, 16 May 2016).
278
Επιτροπή Ανταγωνισμού, Delivery Hero/Alfa Distributions/Inkat/Delivery.gr/E-table (775/2022, 18
April 2022).
279
Autoriteit Consument & Markt, Sanoma/Iddink (ACM/19/035555, 28 August 2019).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
69
door-to-door papers, radio and online services, including in the field of online job
advertisements, price comparison and car and technology websites and also on the
Dutch radio market. The target was active in the field of publishing a large number
of magazines, offering online news and online services, including comparison
websites. The Dutch NCA found that while acquirer DPG, a media company,
might be able to bundle its activities on various markets with its online advertising
services, DPG would not have market power in any advertising market that it
could transfer to adjacent advertising markets. Post-merger, DPG would also have
the ability to use its position in unpaid general online news to refer visitors to its
own e-commerce activities, but again this would be unlikely to foreclose
competitors. Sufficient alternative channels would remain available for recruiting
visitors for providers of job and car advertisements. In the area of price
comparison services, it was unlikely that a possible strategy in which hyperlinks
are placed from unpaid general online news to price comparison services would
lead to foreclosure. The transaction was unconditionally cleared.
280
(212) In Crédit Mutuel Arkéa, Primonial Management, Blackfin, Latour
Capital/Primonial Holding (2015), Crédit Mutuel Arkéa, Primonial Management,
Blackfin and Latour Capital wanted to acquire joint control of Primonial Holding.
Amongst many others, this transaction concerned the market for price comparison
websites regarding insurance and loans in which the Blackfin fund is involved,
and the authority analysed possible conglomerate effects relating to this market.
The French NCA did not believe any conglomerate foreclosure effects would arise
related to the comparison website for loans and insurance operated by one of the
parties due to that website’s low market shares (0-5% for comparing loans; 10-
20% for comparing insurance) and the negligible market shares of the parties in
banking and insurance (0-5%).
281
(213) In Blackbaud/Giving (2017), the UK NCA considered whether the acquisition by
an online fundraising platform (OFP) of another could raise conglomerate
foreclosure effects, as the acquirer also provided payment services and customer
relationship management (CRM) software. As CRM software and OFPs were not
complements, and customers did not usually buy these two products from a single
source, nor at the same time, it would be difficult for the merged entity to engage
in a foreclosure strategy. Concerning a possible bundling of the merged entity’s
CRM and OFP offerings, the NCA found that Blackbaud had already
unsuccessfully tried such a strategy. In addition, a discounted bundle could be pro-
competitive as long as CRM competitors were not forced out of the market.
Finally, the NCA also considered the possibility that the merged entity could
foreclose CRM or OFP competitors by reducing the quality of data integration
either between competing OFPs and Blackbaud’s CRM software or between
competing CRM software and the merged entity’s OFPs. Here, the NCA
280
Autoriteit Consument & Markt, DPG/Sanoma (ACM/19/038207, 10 April 2020).
281
Autorité de la concurrence, Crédit Mutuel Arkéa, Primonial Management, Blackfin, Latour
Capital/Primonial Holding (15-DCC-105, 12 August 2015).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
70
underlined that improving data integration between Blackbaud’s CRM and its
future OFPs would be pro-competitive. However, customers did not choose CRM
software based on how well it integrated with only one tool, leading the NCA to
conclude that the merged entity would not have the ability to engage in such a
foreclosure strategy. Ultimately, the acquisition was unconditionally cleared.
282
(214) In Axel Springer/Concept Multimédia (2018), a transaction that affected the
market for online real estate classified ads, the market for classified ads in print
media and the national market for online advertising markets, the French NCA
assessed whether there was a risk of conglomerate effects due to the target’s
presence on the market for real estate classified ads in print media as well as
online. The NCA considered that while the target’s Logic-Immo had a
considerable share of the market for real estate classified ads in print media, that
market was in decline and it therefore did not possess the type of market power to
allow it to leverage it on a connected market. There was therefore no risk of
foreclosure on the market for online real estate classified ads. The NCA also
assessed whether foreclosure was likely on the market for real estate classified ads
in print media, as Logic-Immo already offered an online/offline bundle and Axel
Springer’s internal documents showed that such an offer was also considered by
it. The NCA concluded that the merged entity would have the ability to propose
such bundles or bundled rebates. Based on three different scenarios (a discount on
print ads; a discount on online ads; tying or a price increase), however, it
concluded that the incentive to implement such discounts for bundles or to enforce
ties would be limited due to the negative effects on the merged entity. It also
concluded that, in any case, the effect of such a bundle on competition on the
market would be feeble.
283
(215) In TF1/Aufeminin (2018), the French NCA assessed possible conglomerate effects
between TF1’s market presence in selling television advertising space and
markets on which the target was present, notably the sale of online advertising
space and marketing and commercial communication services. While TF1
certainly had the ability to adopt a bundling strategy in the sale of online and
television advertising space, bundling TV advertising with online or radio
advertising was a common strategy in this sector that TF1’s competitors also
engaged in. TF1’s incentive to carry out this strategy was assessed through several
factors. The NCA emphasised that TF1 could benefit from the complementarity
of its bundle, the merging of data sets and cost synergies, and concluded that the
implementation of such bundles appeared to be one of the objectives of the
acquisition. TF1 would use its position on the market for television advertising
space as leverage to strengthen its position on the market for online advertising
space. On the latter market, however, the new entity would have a market share
below 10%. Based on the strong position of TF1’s competitors and low barriers
to entry, and especially considering the competitive pressure emanating from Big
282
Competition & Markets Authority, Blackbaud/Giving (ME/6700/17, 8 September 2017).
283
Autorité de la concurrence, Axel Springer/Concept Multimédia (18-DCC-18, 1 February 2018).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
71
Tech (with Google’s market share in online advertising at 50-60%, Facebook at
10-20% and the new entity at only 0-5%), the NCA concluded that conglomerate
effects could be discarded.
284
(216) The UK NCA assessed two conglomerate theories of harm in
Salesforce.com/Tableau Software (2019). In that case, Salesforce had acquired
Tableau Software. Both parties supply business intelligence (BI) software, and in
particular modern BI software making use of artificial intelligence and business
analytics. Salesforce also offers a customer relationship management (CRM)
platform that integrates with third-party products. First of all, the UK NCA
assessed whether the merged entity could foreclose competing BI software
providers through technical restrictions or bundling/tying of CRM products with
BI products. While the merged entity could have the ability to pursue such a
foreclosure strategy, there was no incentive to do so. Second, the NCA considered
whether the merged entity could foreclose competing CRM software providers
through technical restrictions or bundling/tying of BI products with CRM
products. The NCA emphasised that a BI tool was more valuable when it
connected to multiple data sources, and in any case the costs would outweigh the
benefits for the merged entity. The merger was unconditionally cleared.
285
(217) Advanced Micro Devices/Xilinx (2021) was the second case that exclusively
focused on conglomerate effects. Given that the merged entity would have a
strong market position in field programmable gate arrays (FPGAs) for datacentre
applications, the UK NCA assessed whether the merged entity could bundle or tie
the sale of FPGAs with the sale of its central processing units (CPUs) for
datacentre services. It found, however, that the merged entity would not have the
ability or incentive to foreclose datacentre CPU suppliers, as datacentre CPUs are
mostly not bought together with datacentre FPGAs. Given the merged entity’s
strong market position in FPGAs for embedded applications, the NCA also
assessed whether the merged entity could foreclose competitors supplying CPUs
for embedded applications through linking sales. Again, it concluded that
embedded CPUs and FPGAs were not usually used together, meaning no anti-
competitive outcome was to be expected. The acquisition was unconditionally
cleared.
286
(218) Meta/Kustomer (2021) also concerned conglomerate foreclosure effects. In
particular, the UK NCA considered whether Meta (formerly Facebook) could
cross-subsidise a free(mium) version of Kustomer’s customer relationship
management (CRM) with profits from online display advertising, thereby
foreclosing competing CRM providers. The UK NCA considered that such a
strategy would fit within Meta’s overall business strategy of monetising ‘free’
services, and that Meta would have both the ability and inventive to do so.
However, the NCA concluded that this would not have a negative impact on
284
Autorité de la concurrence, TF1/Aufeminin (18-DCC-63, 23 April 2018).
285
Competition & Markets Authority, Salesforce.com/Tableau Software (ME/6841/19, 22 November
2019).
286
Competition & Markets Authority, Advanced Micro Devices/Xilinx (ME/6915/20, 29 June 2021).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
72
competition. While some competitors may be hard-hit by such a strategy, CRM
providers competed on more than just price and there would remain sufficient
competition on that market even if such a strategy were to be adopted. The
transaction was unconditionally cleared.
287
(219) Finally, in Auction Technology Group/Live Auctioneers (2021), Auction
Technology Group (ATG) agreed to acquire Live Auctioneers. Both operate
online auction marketplaces for arts and antiques, a market which the authority
noted was national in scope because of the complexity of international
transactions in these goods. The UK NCA assessed conglomerate effects that may
arise if the merged entity could leverage the target’s strong market position in
online auction marketplaces for arts and antiques in the US in order to increase
the number of auction houses that used the acquirer’s services in the UK, eg by
engaging in a bundling strategy regarding the target’s US bidder base. Based on
shares of supply, however, the NCA concluded that the target did not have market
power in the US, while the acquirer was already an important market player in the
UK and would gain little from such a strategy. Therefore, the merged entity would
only have a limited ability to engage in such a leveraging strategy. The transaction
was unconditionally cleared.
288
c. Discussion
(220) In digital markets, conglomerate foreclosure can involve measures to reduce
interoperability with competing products, using commercially sensitive
information or data sets from one market as leverage in another, and many other
types of strategies. For each type of strategy, it carefully needs to be assessed what
impact this could have not only on the relevant markets at issue, but also on other
relevant markets in which a digital platform is active. This is what makes
conglomerate effects particularly challenging in digital market environments but
it is also a type of analysis that NCAs should not shy away from.
289
(221) The possibility that the merged entity would give preferential treatment to one of
its services found within the same conglomerate, to the detriment of competitors,
was already seen as a concern in the Czech Rockaway Capital/Heureka case, and
is a concern that also surfaced in the European Google Shopping case,
290
where
the abuse of dominance at issue related to such behaviour. In the Czech merger
case, the remedies aimed to prevent such behaviour.
(222) An issue that perhaps has not yet been sufficiently discussed in national merger
assessments is the fact that data capabilities relating to both personal data and
non-personal data are central to success in many digital markets and can
287
Competition & Markets Authority, Meta/Kustomer (ME/6920/20, 27 September 2021).
288
Competition & Markets Authority, Auction Technology Group/Live Auctioneers (ME/6942/21, 29
September 2021).
289
As aptly put by Witt (n 13), asking who was afraid of conglomerate mergers.
290
European Commission Decision of 27 June 2017, AT.39740 Google Search (Shopping); upheld on
appeal in Case T-612/17, Google and Alphabet/Commission (Google Shopping), ECLI :EU:T:2021:763,
currently on appeal as Case C-48/22 P, Google and Alphabet/Commission (Google Shopping) [2022] OJ
C191/10 (pending).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
73
therefore also represent a significant competitive advantage to digital platforms in
distant markets. Here, the decisional practice is still developing. The recent Greek
case involving a food delivery platform points towards possibilities in this regard.
Going forward, national cases will need to take into account to what extent data
capabilities in one market can also be used to an incumbent’s advantage in related
or entirely different markets. Because of its implications for different markets, this
can be looked at under a horizontal
291
or under a conglomerate theory of harm.
While a competitive data advantage can transform into benefits for consumers, it
could also lead to the foreclosure of competitors.
ii. Coordinated effects
a. Specificities of the theory of harm
(223) Just like horizontal and vertical mergers, a conglomerate merger may alter the
market structure so as to allow companies to reach a common understanding
aimed at increasing prices, limiting production or dividing the market.
292
The
framework of analysis is the same as outlined above for coordinated effects in
horizontal and vertical mergers.
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers
(224) None of the 69 cases analysed in-depth addressed this theory of harm.
(225) As mentioned above (para (201)), the prospect of an agreement such as the one
concluded between Google and Apple to maintain Google Search’s status as
default search engine on Apple devices
293
could, in the framework of a merger
review, be considered as a possible coordinated effect in a conglomerate or also
vertical merger.
iii. Other effects
a. Specificities of the theory of harm
(226) This category includes any other anti-competitive effects that a conglomerate
merger may give rise to and that are not caught by the previous categories. In
particular, the strengthening of a digital ecosystem could find its place here.
b. NCAs applying the theory of harm in digital and technology mergers
(227) Only one of the 69 cases analysed in-depth addressed this theory of harm. This
was the unconditional clearance of Meta/Kustomer (2022) by the German
NCA.
294
In that case, the NCA emphasised that this acquisition by Meta also
needed to be assessed against the background of Meta’s social media ecosystem.
In particular, it investigated whether the acquisition could enable Meta to
safeguard, further develop or strengthen its own digital ecosystem. This could
291
See European Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines 2004, para 36.
292
European Commission, Non-horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008, paras 119 ff.
293
See Wakabayashi and Nicas (n 261). This deal is being challenged in US v Google, US District Court
for the District of Columbia, Case 1:20-cv-03010 (complaint brought on 20 October 2020, amended on 15
January 2021).
294
Bundeskartellamt, Meta/Kustomer (B6-21/22, 11 February 2022).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
74
then manifest itself on particular relevant markets, such as in social media
advertising. In this respect, the NCA particularly considered the data advantage
that the acquisition of Kustomer would provide Meta with. It also analysed to
what extent the acquisition could help Meta to further develop its offerings. The
NCA concluded that, overall, anti-competitive effects on markets in which Meta
already had significant market power were entirely possible. However, it refrained
from opening phase 2 proceedings as it was not possible to establish, to the
required standard of probability, that the services and capabilities associated with
Kustomer were of sufficient importance to lead to a strengthening of Meta’s
ecosystem as sketched by the NCA.
c. Discussion
(228) Theories of harm relating to the strengthening of a digital ecosystem are starting
to make their way into national decisional practice, even if no legal consequences
have been derived from them so far. This issue is discussed in more detail below
(section V.4.i.). Suffice to say that at the European level, the European
Commission’s recent review of the same merger similarly led to an assessment of
the combination of different types of vertical foreclosure strategies.
295
4. Theories of harm largely absent in the decisional practice
(229) The national case law relating to digital and technology mergers was analysed
based on the most common categorisation of theories of harm available today. It
is clear, however, that by sticking to these traditional categories, NCAs also
necessarily stay within well-trodden paths of merger analysis. In certain
circumstances, this may mean that competition concerns may be overlooked or
underestimated when they arise in dynamic market environments and against the
background of changing competition dynamics that would require an adjustment
of the traditional analytical framework. For this reason, the following points out
three considerations that may be useful when assessing the analytical framework
of merger control against the background of the digitalisation of markets.
i. Building and reinforcing a digital ecosystem
(230) With over 800 unchallenged acquisitions over the past decade, Big Tech
companies have acquired a substantial number of start-ups without any antitrust
295
European Commission Decision of 27 January 2022, M.10262 Meta/Kustomer.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
75
intervention.
296
This has helped the creation of a small number of vast digital
ecosystems
297
and may in itself raise new competition concerns.
(231) In fact, competition concerns in today’s digital markets may arise not so much
because of well-defined competition issues in specific relevant markets, and
perhaps not even because of every single small merger that is completed. Instead,
competition concerns related to digital platforms arise from the combined effects
of these mergers in multi-sided markets with strong network effects, with a great
many markets concerned. Of the over 800 acquisitions that were completed by
Big Tech in recent years,
298
only one known instance of a prohibition by
competition authorities comes to mind the recent prohibition of the Meta/Giphy
merger in the UK, which was challenged in court but upheld on substance.
299
This
can mean one of three things: (i) either these mergers were not reviewed because
of a lack of jurisdiction, or (ii) they are completely benign in their impact on
competition, or (iii) they cannot be well depicted under currently applicable
theories of harm. For instance, in digital acquisitions it is regularly the case that
the acquirer has significant market power, while the target has no noteworthy
market power at all and that there is therefore hardly any increment in market
shares.
300
However, at least at the level of the European Union, recent decisional
practice has shown how the significant impediment of effective competition test
under Article 2 para 3 EUMR is starting to accommodate new market realities in
complex digital markets that involve digital ecosystems.
301
(232) Regularly, acquisitions by digital platforms will lead to a situation where the
target’s business is both in a vertical and a conglomerate relationship with the
acquirer’s business. For instance, in Apple/Shazam (2018), the European
Commission underlined that music recognition apps such as Shazam and digital
music distribution apps (such as Apple Music or Spotify) were complementary or
at least closely related products, that links from the music recognition app were
296
Federal Trade Commission, ‘Non-HSR Reported Acquisitions by Select Technology Platforms, 2010-
2019: An FTC Study’ (September 2021) <https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/reports/non-hsr-
reported-acquisitions-select-technology-platforms-2010-2019-ftc-
study/p201201technologyplatformstudy2021.pdf>; American Economic Liberties Project, ‘Big Tech
Mergers’ <https://www.economicliberties.us/big-tech-merger-tracker/>; Chris Alcantara, Kevin Schaul,
Gerrit De Vynck and Reed Albergotti, ‘How Big Tech got so big: Hundreds of acquisitions’ Washington
Post (21 April 2021) <https://www.washingtonpost.com/technology/interactive/2021/amazon-apple-
facebook-google-acquisitions/>; European Commission, Evaluation of procedural and jurisdictional
aspects of EU merger control, SWD(2021) 66 final, para 111.
297
Eg, see Konstantinos Stylianou, ‘Exclusion in Digital Markets’ (2018) 24 Michigan Telecommunications
& Technology Law Review 181, 207; Georgios Petropoulos, ‘Competition Economics of Digital
Ecosystems’ (2020) DAF/COMP/WD(2020)91; Marc Bourreau, ‘Some Economics of Digital Ecosystems
(2020) DAF/COMP/WD(2020)89.
298
On these, see the references in n 296 above.
299
Competition & Markets Authority, Meta/Giphy (ME/6891/20-II, 6 December 2021); Meta/Giphy,
[2022] CAT 26, 14 June 2022.
300
This was the case for a number of Irish cases in the online betting and gaming sectors, as well as in
Office of Fair Trading, Google/BeatThatQuote (ME/4912/11, 1 July 2011).
301
Eg, see European Commission Decision of 17 December 2020, M.9660 Google/Fitbit; European
Commission Decision of 27 January 2022, M.10262 Meta/Kustomer. On the challenges of market
definition in digital ecosystems, see Robertson (n 72).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
76
also an important tool for customer acquisition, and that data from music
recognition apps could be used to improve digital music streaming apps. From
this, it assessed both vertical and conglomerate foreclosure strategies. It
concluded, however, that while the merged entity would have both the ability and
incentive to engage in such strategies, they would not in themselves negatively
impact competition.
302
While this might be true for individual foreclosure
strategies, what is missing from this and other cases is a more comprehensive
understanding of the combination of post-merger strategies that serve to further
reinforce digital ecosystems and could thereby, ultimately, negatively impact
competition.
303
The same applies to business strategies that transcend individual
relevant markets that are frequently the unit of analysis for merger control. This,
of course, is closely linked to the spreading of digital ecosystems and the data
advantages that are encountered in digital markets. While the effects of an
individual merger, viewed in isolation, might not yet give rise to the types of anti-
competitive effects that the merger rules are explicitly targeting, it might be the
very combination of those effects that ultimately add up to a ‘significant
impediment of effective competition’ or a ‘substantial lessening of competition’.
(233) It would seem that current enforcement guidelines do not yet envisage an
assessment that takes the strengthening of a digital ecosystem into account,
presumably because they were published at a time when such strategies were not
yet commonplace. This is not to say, however, that the EU Merger Regulation or
national merger rules necessarily stand in the way of such an assessment. Indeed,
the European Commission’s recent Meta/Kustomer review assessed the
combination of different types of vertical foreclosure strategies.
304
Such theories
of harm need to be developed with diligence, and this certainly is work in
progress: In the recent unconditional clearance of Meta/Kustomer in Germany
(2022), for instance, the Bundeskartellamt stated that while it believed the
strengthening of Meta’s digital ecosystem through the acquisition was quite
likely, it could not prove this to the required legal standard and therefore did not
initiate phase 2 proceedings.
305
(234) Joint ventures and minority stakes can also be avenues through which digital
platforms enlarge their digital ecosystems. For instance, in the GE/Microsoft joint
venture (2012), a health intelligence platform was created that would add to
Microsoft’s increasing ecosystem.
306
In the Sanofi/Google/DMI joint venture
(2016), a new company providing services for the management and treatment of
diabetes was created.
307
And in Amazon/Roofoods (2020), a minority stake in a
food delivery platform paved Amazon’s way back into the online restaurant
302
European Commission Decision of 6 September 2018, M.8788 Apple/Shazam, paras 260 ff.
303
Fletcher (n 71) paras 24 f (containing further references).
304
European Commission Decision of 27 January 2022, M.10262 Meta/Kustomer.
305
Bundeskartellamt, Meta/Kustomer (B7-119/21, 11 February 2022).
306
European Commission Decision of 10 February 2012, COMP/M.6474 GE/Microsoft/JV. This was
cleared unconditionally and subject to a simplified procedure.
307
European Commission Decision of 23 February 2016, M.7813 Sanofi/Google/DMI JV.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
77
ordering market in the UK.
308
These should therefore be more closely observed as
well.
(235) In the European Commission’s Google/Fitbit case (2020), the sheer number of
relevant markets affected by this acquisition aptly indicated the ecosystem nature
of this merger.
309
Most national cases, however, will not look like this because
based on the EUMR’s turnover thresholds – NCAs tend to deal with much smaller
transactions than the European Commission. An exception are Big Tech
acquisitions of small start-ups that do not (yet) generate significant turnover and
that could end up before NCAs. These cases, however, may be referred to the
European Commission under Article 22 EUMR, or the notifying parties may ask
for the Commission to deal with the merger under Article 4 para 5 EUMR.
(236) The creation and strengthening of digital ecosystems are objectives that several
digital platforms pursue, and should therefore not be overlooked in the merger
assessment. The ways in which this can be done are manifold and merit more in-
depth analysis and research.
ii. Data advantages
(237) In digital mergers, the acquisition of personal and non-personal data and data sets
is regularly seen as a possible competition concern as it could foreclose
competitors. At the same time, increased data capabilities can also lead to a
considerable improvement in digital services to the benefit of consumers.
(238) So far, data advantages obtained through an acquisition have been assessed as a
novel horizontal unilateral theory of harm, as another type of horizontal harm, or
as a vertical or conglomerate concern. While some cases dealt with the merged
entity’s access to commercially sensitive information about competitors,
310
others
concerned data sets about users that could be monetised by a merged entity.
311
(239) While the non-rivalrous nature of data is often emphasised in the case law,
312
it
should also be borne in mind that different digital platforms have varying abilities
to actually access data that is relevant for competition.
(240) In Google/Fitbit (2020), the European Commission assessed the data advantage
stemming from the concentration in considerable detail. In that case, the
Commission assessed various theories of harm relating to a large number of
different relevant markets, highlighting how this transaction is embedded in a vast
308
Competition & Markets Authority, Amazon/Roofoods (ME/6836/19-II, 4 August 2020).
309
European Commission Decision of 17 December 2020, M.9660 Google/Fitbit, para 384 (for an
overview of affected markets).
310
Javna agencija Republike Slovenije za varstvo konkurence, Sully System/CENEJE (3061-27/2017-71,
12 April 2018); Autoriteit Consument & Markt, Sanoma/Iddink (ACM/19/035555, 28 August 2019);
Competition & Markets Authority, Uber International/GPC Computer Software (ME/6903/20, 29 March
2021).
311
Úřad pro ochranu hospodářské soutěže, Rockaway Capital/Heureka (ÚOHS-S0013/2016/KS-
21123/2016/840/DVá, 16 May 2016); Autorité de la concurrence, TF1/Aufeminin (18-DCC-63, 23 April
2018).
312
Eg, see Competition & Markets Authority, Meta/Kustomer (ME/6920/20, 27 September 2021).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
78
digital ecosystem of interconnected products and services.
313
The Commission
noted that this transaction did not relate to horizontally affected markets in a
traditional sense. Instead, it analysed data-related effects arising from Fitbit as
a source of data on health and personal activities as horizontal effects, because
data was recognised to constitute a valuable asset.
314
These effects were thought
to arise in the exploitation of said data for advertising and digital healthcare.
315
If
the merger enabled the combination of datasets, this could, in the eyes of the
Commission, lead to a situation resembling the one set out in its Horizontal
Merger Guidelines,
316
namely the gaining of such control over an asset that
competitors’ entry or expansion becomes more difficult.
317
The data accumulation
through the acquisition of Fitbit would strengthen Google’s dominant position in
online search advertising,
318
and this was addressed by the Ads Commitment,
which foresees that Google will not use certain health data in or for Google Ads
and will operate data silos.
319
(241) Access to commercially sensitive information about competitors was at issue in
cases involving horizontal, vertical as well as conglomerate effects, eg in national
cases such as esure/Gocompare.com (UK 2015),
320
Sully System/CENEJE (SI
2018),
321
MIH Food Delivery Holdings/Just Eat (ES 2019),
322
Sanoma/Iddink
(NL 2019),
323
Meta/Giphy (AT 2021),
324
and Uber International/GPC Computer
Software (UK 2021).
325
This was also the case in the European Commission’s
cases of Broadcom/Brocade (2017)
326
and Apple/Shazam (2018).
327
(242) In other national cases, access to user data that would become available through
an acquisition was at the centre of the analysis, eg in Rockaway Capital/Heureka
(CZ 2016),
328
TF1/Aufeminin (FR 2018),
329
and Meta/Kustomer (UK 2021).
330
313
European Commission Decision of 17 December 2020, M.9660 Google/Fitbit, para 384 (for an
overview of affected markets).
314
European Commission Decision of 17 December 2020, M.9660 Google/Fitbit, paras 385, 399.
315
European Commission Decision of 17 December 2020, M.9660 Google/Fitbit, para 400.
316
European Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines 2004, para 36.
317
European Commission Decision of 17 December 2020, M.9660 Google/Fitbit, para 401.
318
European Commission Decision of 17 December 2020, M.9660 Google/Fitbit, para 468.
319
European Commission Decision of 17 December 2020, M.9660 Google/Fitbit, Commitments of 4
November 2020, p 1.
320
Competition & Markets Authority, esure Group/Gocompare.com (ME/6495-14, 23 February 2015).
321
Javna agencija Republike Slovenije za varstvo konkurence, Sully System/CENEJE (3061-27/2017-71,
12 April 2018).
322
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, MIH Food Delivery Holdings/Just Eat
(C/1072/19, 5 December 2019).
323
Autoriteit Consument & Markt, Sanoma/Iddink (ACM/19/035555, 28 August 2019).
324
Kartellgericht, 22 July 2021, 28 Kt 6/21y Meta/Giphy; Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde (n 169);
Kartellobergericht, 23 June 2022, 16 Ok 3/22k and 16 Ok 4/22g Meta/Giphy.
325
Competition & Markets Authority, Uber International/GPC Computer Software (ME/6903/20, 29
March 2021).
326
European Commission Decision of 12 May 2017, M.8314 Broadcom/Brocade, paras 235 ff.
327
European Commission Decision of 6 September 2018, M.8788 Apple/Shazam, paras 196 ff.
328
Úřad pro ochranu hospodářské soutěže, Rockaway Capital/Heureka (ÚOHS-S0013/2016/KS-
21123/2016/840/DVá, 16 May 2016).
329
Autorité de la concurrence, TF1/Aufeminin (18-DCC-63, 23 April 2018).
330
Competition & Markets Authority, Meta/Kustomer (ME/6920/20, 27 September 2021).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
79
This was also considered in the European case of Google/Fitbit (2020).
331
Further
national cases, such as Blackbaud/Giving (UK 2017)
332
and Google/Looker (UK
2020),
333
concerned data integration among digital services. Delivery Hero (EL
2022) related to increased capabilities to run targeted advertising.
334
Several
national cases related to online betting and gaming concerned access to live
betting exchange data or horse racing and football data.
335
(243) Overall, therefore, multiple aspects of access and use of data as well as of data
integration and data protection have come into play in digital merger cases in
recent years. What matters now is to consolidate the various approaches in order
to develop a coherent approach to assessing data aspects in merger control. Here,
policy choices will need to be made as to the extent to which questions of data
protection can and need to filter into the competition assessment.
iii. Concentration and abuse of dominance
(244) In substantive terms, the theories of harm relied upon in merger control are, of
course, closely related to the types of abuse of dominance that one encounters in
digital markets. For instance, the UK NCAs concern in Google/BeatThatQuote
(2011)
336
related to the manipulation of search results to demote rivals and to
improve own services’ ranking reminiscent of the self-preferencing that the
European Commission identified as anti-competitive in the abuse of dominance
case of Google Shopping (2017).
337
Similar concerns arose in the Rockaway
Capital/Heureka merger (CZ 2016).
338
(245) In the German CTS Eventim/Four Artists case, the German NCA highlighted that
it regarded CTS Eventim’s exclusivity contracts with event organisers as
contributing to an abusive customer foreclosure vis-à-vis competing ticketing
platforms. It believed that the same analysis had to apply when assessing this
concentration.
339
331
European Commission Decision of 17 December 2020, M.9660 Google/Fitbit.
332
Competition & Markets Authority, Blackbaud/Giving (ME/6700/17, 8 September 2017).
333
Competition & Markets Authority, Google/Looker (ME/6839/19, 13 February 2020).
334
Επιτροπή Ανταγωνισμού, Delivery Hero/Alfa Distributions/Inkat/Delivery.gr/E-table (775/2022, 18
April 2022).
335
Competition & Markets Authority, Betfair Group/Paddy Power (ME/6572/15, 17 December 2015);
Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Paddy Power/Betfair (M/15/059, 15 January 2016);
Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Ladbrokes/Gala Coral (M/16/007, 10 March 2016);
Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Flutter Entertainment/Stars Group (M/20/001, 12
May 2020).
336
Office of Fair Trading, Google/BeatThatQuote (ME/4912/11, 1 July 2011) para 68.
337
European Commission Decision of 27 June 2017, AT.39740 Google Search (Shopping); upheld on
appeal in Case T-612/17, Google and Alphabet/Commission (Google Shopping), ECLI :EU:T:2021:763,
currently on appeal as Case C-48/22 P, Google and Alphabet/Commission (Google Shopping) [2022] OJ
C191/10 (pending).
338
Úřad pro ochranu hospodářské soutěže, Rockaway Capital/Heureka (ÚOHS-S0013/2016/KS-
21123/2016/840/DVá, 16 May 2016).
339
Bundeskartellamt, CTS Eventim/Four Artists (B6-35/17, 23 November 2017).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
80
(246) While a great many number of food delivery mergers were considered by several
NCAs (e.g., ES 2016, 2019 and 2022; ES 2019; RO 2021; EL 2022),
340
the
European Commission recently started investigations in that sector.
341
While the
Commission’s investigations appear to focus on a possible agreement to share
markets, it will also be interesting to see to what extent competition concerns
voiced in the merger decisions are encountered in the antitrust probes.
(247) While the UK decided not to challenge Meta’s acquisition of Instagram in 2012,
342
and both the European Commission and the United States Federal Trade
Commission decided not to challenge Meta’s acquisition of WhatsApp in 2014,
343
the Federal Trade Commission is currently trying to break up these merged
entities ex post based on a claim of monopolisation.
344
The question whether a
similar approach would also be feasible under EU law is currently being
considered in a preliminary ruling before the Court of Justice of the European
Union.
345
In Towercast v Autorité de la concurrence, the French Cour d’appel de
Paris asked the Court to specify whether Article 21 EUMR precludes an NCA
from assessing whether a concentration that has neither a Union dimension nor
comes within the national jurisdictional thresholds, and that has not been referred
to the European Commission based on Article 22 EUMR, may constitute an abuse
of a dominant position under Article 102 TFEU. The preliminary ruling could
open up new avenues in this regard.
(248) These small glimpses into national merger control show that a more cohesive
approach to abuses of dominance on the one hand and theories of harm under
merger control on the other hand can be a useful tool to better grasp competition
concerns in digital mergers. Here, ongoing legislative developments e.g., new
§ 19a ARC
346
or the Digital Markets Act
347
can provide a new impetus for
updating theories of harm so that they better reflect economic realities.
5. Remedies
(249) Two types of remedies are generally distinguished, structural remedies and
behavioural remedies. Within these categories, however, a great many different
340
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Just Eat/La Nevera Roja (C/0730/16, 31 March
2016); Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Just Eat Spain/Canary Delivery Company
(C/1046/19, 10 September 2019); Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, MIH Food
Delivery Holdings/Just Eat (C/1072/19, 5 December 2019); Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la
Competencia, Delivery Hero/Glovo (C/1260/21, 23 February 2022); România Consiliul Concurenței,
Glovoappro/Foodpanda (86/22.11.2021, 22 November 2021); Επιτροπή Ανταγωνισμού, Delivery
Hero/Alfa Distributions/Inkat/Delivery.gr/E-table (775/2022, 18 April 2022).
341
European Commission, ‘Antitrust: Commission confirms unannounced inspections in the online food
delivery sector’ IP/22/4345 (6 July 2022).
342
Office of Fair Trading, Facebook/Instagram (ME/5525/12, 14 August 2012).
343
European Commission Decision of 3 October 2014, COMP/M.7217 Facebook/WhatsApp;
344
Federal Trade Commission v Facebook, US District Court for the District of Columbia, Case 1:20-cv-
3590 (11 January 2022).
345
Case C-449/21, Towercast v Autorité de la concurrence [2021] OJ C452/9 (pending).
346
Act against Restraints of Competition, German Federal Law Gazette I 2013/1750, 3245 as amended.
347
Regulation (EU) 2022/1925 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 14 September 2022 on
contestable and fair markets in the digital sector and amending Directives (EU) 2019/1937 and (EU)
2020/1828 (Digital Markets Act, DMA) [2022] OJ L265/1.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
81
remedies can be envisaged that may address the competition concerns raised in a
specific merger.
348
The following sets out the various remedies that were approved
in all digital and technology cases involving remedies that were analysed for this
Report.
i. Structural remedies
(250) A small number of national cases included structural remedies. To address the
Romanian NCA’s concerns related to horizontal unilateral effects in Dante
International/PC Garage (2016) (see above, para (85)), Dante committed to (i)
divest four online stores active in the non-food retail market (namely, pcfun.ro,
shopit.ro, garagemall.ro and electrofun.ro) as an ongoing concern, and (ii) not to
be involved in the divested activities for at least 10 years.
349
(251) To address its concerns related to horizontal unilateral effects in Pug/StubHub
(2021) (see above, para (90)), the UK NCA required a partial divestiture of
StubHub, namely of the StubHub International business (i.e., StubHub outside of
North America). This was regarded as the only effective remedy for this
completed transaction.
350
(252) To address the UK NCA’s concerns related to horizontal unilateral effects in
Adevinta/eBay Classifieds Group (2021) (see above, paras (87), (121)), the parties
proposed the following commitments: (i) divestiture of Gumtree UK (incl
Motor.co.uk) on a debt-free basis, (ii) divestiture of Shpock to RussMedia Equity
Partners on a debt-free basis, (iii) provision of transitional services in relation to
Shpock and Gumtree UK. The NCA accepted these commitments.
351
(253) Involving the same transaction, eBay/Adevinta (2021), Adevinta and eBay also
agreed to commitments with the Austrian NCA to address the latter’s concerns
related to horizontal unilateral effects (see above, para (86)). Adevinta and eBay
proposed and the Austrian NCA accepted the following commitments: (i) in order
to eliminate incentives for anti-competitive behaviour, eBay reduces its economic
stake in Adevinta to 33% or less within 18 months; (ii) in order to prevent eBay’s
ability to engage in anti-competitive behaviour, both parties take measures to
prevent the exchange of information and to reduce the economic influence of eBay
on willhaben.at. In particular, eBay commits to restrict the voting rights of eBay-
appointed board members on issues related to willhaben.at and Adevinta commits
not to exercise its right to appoint a managing director as well as several board
members at willhaben.at. The commitments are binding as long as eBay appoints
a director to Adevinta’s board and eBay’s financial or voting interest in Adevinta
is 25% or higher; but for a maximum of ten years.
352
348
European Commission, Commission notice on remedies acceptable under Council Regulation (EC) No
139/2004 and under Commission Regulation (EC) No 802/2004 [2008] OJ C267/1, paras 22-70.
349
România Consiliul Concurenței, Dante International/PC Garage (84/24.11.2016, 24 November 2016).
350
Competition & Markets Authority, Pug/StubHub (ME/6868/19-II, 2 February 2021).
351
Competition & Markets Authority, Adevinta/eBay Classifieds Group (ME/6897/20, 16 February 2021).
352
Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde, eBay/Adevinta (BWB/Z-5141, Z-5142, Z-5420 and Z-5421, 18 June 2021).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
82
ii. Behavioural remedies: access and interoperability
(254) Several national cases included various types of access remedies. To address the
Austrian NCA’s concerns related to customer foreclosure in CTS
Eventim/Barracuda Holding (2019) (see above, para (179)), CTS Eventim
committed that its Austrian ticketing service oeticket would, for a duration of five
years, (i) provide customers that wanted to use its ticketing services with non-
discriminatory access to its full range of services, including advertising contracts,
and (ii) not to engage in self-preferencing in relation to the content and the way
that events are promoted on oeticket.com.
353
(255) To address vertical foreclosure concerns raised in Meta/Giphy (2022) (see above,
para (151)), the Austrian Cartel Court imposed the following conditions for
clearance of the merger: Meta has to (i) provide non-discriminatory access to
Giphy’s GIF library for competing social media providers (for a duration of five
years) and (ii) grant alternative GIF libraries, under certain conditions, access to
Giphy’s GIF library via programming interfaces (APIs) to allow the establishment
of an additional GIF provider other than Giphy (Meta) and Tenor (Google) (for a
duration of seven years).
354
The conditional clearance was confirmed by Austria’s
Supreme Cartel Court.
355
(256) To address the Dutch NCA’s concerns related to vertical input foreclosure in
Sanoma/Iddink (2019) (see above, para (153)), Sanoma agreed to (i) grant
publishers access to the Magister API under fair, reasonable and non-
discriminatory (FRAND) conditions, including the necessary information to
enable the same link with Magister for all publishers; (ii) provide information
about Magister to publishers who request this under FRAND conditions, if they
provide similar information to Sanoma; and (iii) conclude a service agreement
with publishers for the disclosure and use of digital learning resources of
publishers via Magister, which includes the option for publishers to have it
established by means of their own audit that the publisher in question gains access
to the Magister API in a FRAND manner and a dispute settlement procedure is to
be arranged.
356
(257) To address the Dutch NCA’s concerns related to vertical input foreclosure in NS
Groep/Pon Netherlands (2020) (see above, para (154)), the parties to the joint
venture agreed to grant (potential) competitors of the joint venture, access to the
application programming interfaces (APIs) of the train and OV-fiets services on
equal (commercial) conditions as these are made available to the joint venture.
357
(258) In two national cases, it was considered whether exclusive licenses could
constitute an effective remedy to address competition concerns related to
horizontal unilateral effects, thus granting (limited) access through a license. In
one case it was considered an appropriate remedy, while another time it was not
353
Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde, CTS Eventim/Barracuda Holding (BWB/Z-4651, 3 December 2019).
354
Kartellgericht, 22 July 2021, 28 Kt 6/21y Facebook/Giphy.
355
Kartellobergericht, 23 June 2022, 16 Ok 3/22k and 16 Ok 4/22g Meta/Giphy.
356
Autoriteit Consument & Markt, Sanoma/Iddink (ACM/19/035555, 28 August 2019).
357
Autoriteit Consument & Markt, NS Groep/Pon Netherlands (ACM/20/038614, 20 May 2020).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
83
regarded as sufficient. To address the Spanish NCA’s concerns related to
horizontal unilateral effects in Schibsted/Milanuncios (2014) (see above, para
(99)), Schibsted committed to maintain the free option of direct publication of
advertisements on the milanuncios.com portal. Furthermore, Schibsted committed
to allow a third party (licensee) to exploit on an exclusive basis professional
advertisements displayed on the platform related to the motor segment of
milanuncios.com. The merged entity committed to let the licensee automatically
export advertisements by professional advertisers to the motor section of the
portal, and to access the contact details of professional advertisers. The licensee
would also exclusively receive the income from classified ads published by
professional advertisers in the motor segment. Among others, the licensee would
be allowed to redirect user traffic from clicks on classified ads to its own platform.
The exclusive license would be valid for two years.
358
(259) To address the Swedish NCA’s concerns related to horizontal unilateral effects in
Blocket/Hemnet (2016) (see above, para (76)), Blocket proposed to grant an
exclusive license to a smaller website (Bovision) for a certain period of time,
whereby Blocket would automatically refer users that were accessing its website
for properties sold through realtors to Bovision. This would, in the acquirer’s
view, remove the horizontal overlap between Blocket and Hemnet. As Bovision
was only a very small player however, the NCA did not consider this an effective
remedy. In relation to real estate agencies, the remedies proposed by Blocket
involved limitations of sellers’ commitments to future advertising on Hemnet, a
time-limited price cap for advertisements, and further commitments. As the
market test was overall negative, and the NCA did not believe this to be an
effective remedy, the authority moved to block the concentration. Faced with this
possibility, the parties withdrew their notification.
359
iii. Further types of behavioural remedies
(260) A range of different behavioural remedies apart from access remedies were
included in national cases. There have been a number of mergers related to food
delivery services, covering Spain, Romania and Greece. Competition concerns
related to these concentrations were resolved through very similar commitments
that aimed at preventing exclusivity obligations for business partners.
(261) To address the Spanish NCA’s concerns related to horizontal unilateral effects in
Just Eat/La Nevera Roja (2016) (see above, para (81)), Just Eat proposed and the
Spanish NCA accepted the following commitments: (1) not to impose exclusivity
on restaurants (currently or in the future) affiliated with it; (2) no tying of
commissions paid by affiliated restaurants (current or in the future) to an
exclusivity obligation; (3) no penalisation of affiliated restaurants (current or in
the future) for joining third platforms. The public documents did not state the
duration of these commitments. Just Eat further promised to communicate these
358
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Schibsted/Milanuncios (C/0573/14, 20
November 2014).
359
Konkurrensverket, Blocket/Hemnet (84/2016, 2016).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
84
commitments to its affiliates within two weeks of them being accepted by the
NCA. The NCA considered that these commitments would severely limit Just
Eat’s ability to engage in exclusivity strategies, thus allowing restaurants to
continue multi-homing. Bearing in mind the expansive nature of the relevant
market and different competitive strategies employed by different platforms, the
NCA considered that the commitments would allow the market to remain
competitive.
360
(262) To address the Romanian NCA’s concerns related to horizontal unilateral effects
in Glovoappro/Foodpanda (2021) (see above, para (84)), Glovo offered and the
Romanian NCA accepted the following commitments related to exclusivity
clauses with restaurants: Glovo would (1) not impose an exclusivity obligation on
restaurants in current or future intermediation agreements with restaurants, (2) not
contractually base the level of commissions paid by restaurants on exclusivity, (3)
not penalize restaurants for joining another online food ordering platform, and (4)
not renew the target’s exclusivity obligations vis-à-vis restaurants.
(263) To address the Spanish NCA’s concerns related to horizontal unilateral effects in
MIH Food Delivery Holdings/Just Eat (2019) (see above, para (83)), MIH
proposed the following commitments: (1) MIH would not obtain access to
commercially sensitive information of either Delivery Hero or Glovo; (2) MIH
would not influence Glovo’s strategy in markets where it competed (or may
compete) with Just Eat in Spain; (3) Delivery Hero (and Glovo) would not be able
to access commercially sensitive information of Just Eat. These commitments
would be binding for three years.
361
(264) In the recent case of Delivery Hero/Alfa Distributions/Inkat/Delivery.gr/E-table
(2022), the Greek NCA only cleared these acquisitions by the food-delivery
platform Delivery Hero subject to conditions, namely that Delivery Hero would
not bundle food-ordering services with restaurant-reservation services when
offering these to business users. This non-bundling commitment was also not
allowed to be circumvented by offering rebates or lower fees. Furthermore,
Delivery Hero committed that it would not use data collected from its food-
delivery platform for personalised advertising for its restaurant-booking services
(or vice versa) unless users consented to this in accordance with applicable data
protection rules.
362
The commitments were entered into for a duration of two
years, but depending on market developments the Greek NCA can prolong them
by an additional year.
363
360
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Just Eat/La Nevera Roja (C/0730/16, 31 March
2016).
361
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, MIH Food Delivery Holdings/Just Eat
(C/1072/19, 5 December 2019).
362
Επιτροπή Ανταγωνισμού, Delivery Hero/Alfa Distributions/Inkat/Delivery.gr/E-table (775/2022, 18
April 2022).
363
‘Delivery Hero wins conditional approval for Greek acquisitions’ MLex (2 May 2022)
<https://content.mlex.com/#/content/1374846?referrer=email_dailycontentset&dailyId=137821cefd9e45f
bb3e5c211a46cffb5>.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
85
(265) In a further case, non-exclusivity was equally seen as a remedy to resolve concerns
related to vertical input foreclosure. In the Austrian case of CTS
Eventim/Barracuda Holding (2019) (see above, para (151)), CTS Eventim
committed that its Austrian ticketing service oeticket would, for a duration of five
years, (i) not require exclusivity from brick-and-mortar resellers, (ii) not require
exclusivity from customers of its JetTicket brand, and (iii) not impose exclusivity
beyond two years with white label ticketing platforms in Austria.
364
(266) To address the Czech NCA’s concerns related to vertical effects in Rockaway
Capital/Heureka (2016) (see above, para (191)), Rockaway Capital proposed to
limit the possibility to gather excessive data related to a specific, score-based
service that shows the reliability of the online store from the customers
perspective. In particular, Heureka.cz would not oblige sellers to provide other
data than the users’ email addresses, and it was not allowed to favour sellers that
provided more data or disadvantage those who did not.
365
(267) To address the Slovenian NCA’s concerns related to vertical input foreclosure and
other vertical effects in Sully System/CENEJE (2018) (see above, paras (155) and
(193)), the parties offered the following commitments to the authority: (i) Ceneje
would not discriminate, either directly or indirectly, between online retailer ads,
in particular with regard to appearance and display, (ii) Ceneje would maintain
neutral and objective search and ranking algorithms used for online retailers ads,
(iii) Ceneje would maintain neutral and objective recommendations, (iv) Sully
System’s website would include a statement that Ceneje is a member of the
Rockaway Group, (v) Sully System would ensure that Ceneje meets all its
obligations in the proposed commitments, (vi) Sully System would provide
historical price data to the authority every six months for a period of 30 months.
366
(268) To address the Dutch NCA’s concerns related to other non-coordinated vertical
effects, namely the access to commercially sensitive information, in
Sanoma/Iddink (2019) (see above, para (192)), Sanoma agreed to implement
internal measures to ensure that Sanoma does not have access to competitively
sensitive information about other publishers.
367
(269) Only in one case were remedies designed to address conglomerate effects arising
from a merger. To address the Czech NCA’s concerns related to conglomerate
foreclosure in Rockaway Capital/Heureka (2016) (see above, para (209)),
Rockaway Capital proposed to include a clear link between Heureka.cz and other
Rockaway Capital activities on the website, and committed not to discriminate
against independent sellers, especially as regards the prescribed number of
positions of recommended shops and the minimum number of search results.
368
364
Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde, CTS Eventim/Barracuda Holding (BWB/Z-4651, 3 December 2019).
365
Úřad pro ochranu hospodářské soutěže, Rockaway Capital/Heureka (ÚOHS-S0013/2016/KS-
21123/2016/840/DVá, 16 May 2016).
366
Javna agencija Republike Slovenije za varstvo konkurence, Sully System/CENEJE (3061-27/2017-71,
12 April 2018).
367
Autoriteit Consument & Markt, Sanoma/Iddink (ACM/19/035555, 28 August 2019).
368
Úřad pro ochranu hospodářské soutěže, Rockaway Capital/Heureka (ÚOHS-S0013/2016/KS-
21123/2016/840/DVá, 16 May 2016).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
86
iv. Discussion
(270) It is notable that very few national cases resorted to structural remedies in order
to address competition concerns. If this occurred, then it was to address horizontal
unilateral effects. Behavioural remedies have been the prevalent way to resolve
competition concerns in national merger cases in the digital and technology
sectors.
(271) Over the past years, access and interoperability commitments have become a
regularly encountered remedy in digital merger cases. In particular, the access to
APIs on non-discriminatory terms, as was also required in Google/Fitbit
(2020),
369
has become a more frequent type of access remedy that intends to
ensure interoperability so that no foreclosure effects can arise while at the same
time enabling efficiencies from mergers to materialise. Other types of access
remedies included access to services and access to a GIF library. None of the
national cases analysed in-depth led to a finding of vertical input foreclosure that
warranted the granting of a license that would be comparable to the licenses that
resolved the competition concerns in Avago/Broadcom.
370
(272) Behavioural remedies outside of access commitments constituted the most
prevalent types of remedies found in national cases. While an exclusive license
for exploiting professional advertisements was considered an effective remedy to
address a concern related to horizontal unilateral effects (Schibsted/Milanuncios
2014), this type of remedy was proposed but not considered sufficient in a further
case (Blocket/Hemnet 2016). In a range of cases revolving around digital
platforms, non-exclusivity commitments were seen as appropriate remedies to
address possible horizontal unilateral effects. When it comes to addressing
concerns related to vertical effects, these were resolved with behavioural remedies
such as transparency provisions, the commitment not to engage in self-
preferencing, non-discrimination commitments, and a commitment not to access
commercially sensitive information.
(273) It is notable that no national cases included commitments to keep certain acquired
data sets separate as was the case in the European Commission’s Google/Fitbit
decision (2020).
371
(274) While conglomerate concerns appear to be on the rise in digital mergers, no
extensive experience with remedies to address these concerns has been gathered
on a national level. Only one case addressed competition concerns related to
conglomerate effects, and required the merging party to make its link with the
target transparent and not to discriminate against independent sellers. Here, the
question needs to be asked to what extent and under what circumstances
behavioural remedies can be sufficient to address such concerns, particularly
369
European Commission Decision of 17 December 2020, M.9660 Google/Fitbit, Commitments of 4
November 2020, p 3.
370
European Commission Decision of 23 November 2015, M.7686 Avago/Broadcom, paras 119 ff (for
the commitments offered).
371
European Commission Decision of 17 December 2020, M.9660 Google/Fitbit, Commitments of 4
November 2020, p 1.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
87
where an acquirer owns a digital ecosystem in which monitoring behavioural
commitments can be particularly challenging. For this purpose, an independent
expert (i.e., a software engineering company) was appointed in Google/Fitbit
(2020) in order to assist the monitoring trustee with reviewing the implementation
of the commitments.
372
A similar approach was taken in the commitments offered
in the Commission’s Meta/Kustomer case (2022).
373
(275) To allow for a comparison, several examples shall illustrate remedies that the
European Commission has regarded as apt in cases involving conglomerate
effects: In Broadcom/Brocade (2017), the Commission was concerned that the
merged entity could foreclose competitors by degrading the interoperability of the
merged entity’s FC SAN switches with competing components, as well as by
misusing confidential information it may obtain on suppliers of competing
components, in particular regarding Cisco (conglomerate effects). The
Commission accepted the parties’ revised commitments in this respect, which
consisted of an interoperability commitment and a commitment to protect
confidential information.
374
In Qualcomm/NXP Semiconductors (2018), licensing
and interoperability commitments were designed to address the Commission’s
concerns that the merged entity could engage in a number of conglomerate
foreclosure strategies to its own advantage. A number of divestitures of patents
also formed part of the commitments.
375
(276) In Microsoft/LinkedIn (2016), the European Commission raised competition
concerns related to conglomerate foreclosure effects through a pre-installation of
professional social network (PSN) LinkedIn on Microsoft Windows PCs and a
degradation of interoperability with competing PSNs. These concerns were also
addressed through access remedies as well as the possibility for original
equipment manufacturers to uninstall LinkedIn should it be pre-installed. The
access remedies ensured that not only would Microsoft refrain from pre-installing
LinkedIn on its Windows operating system, but it would also maintain the
interoperability of competing PSNs with its Office products, eg through APIs.
376
In Google/Fitbit (2020), certain API commitments were designed to address the
European Commission’s concerns that Google could leverage its dominant
position in licensable smart operating systems to the market for wrist-worn
wearables, eg by degrading the interoperability of Android smartphones with
other wearables than Fitbit through APIs.
377
Similarly, in Meta/Kustomer (2022),
the European Commission accepted a commitment from Meta to make its B2C
372
See, in particular, European Commission Decision of 17 December 2020, M.9660 Google/Fitbit, para
28 of the commitments.
373
European Commission Decision of 27 January 2022, M.10262 Meta/Kustomer, para 17 of the
commitments.
374
European Commission Decision of 12 May 2017, M.8314 Broadcom/Brocade, paras 235 ff.
375
European Commission Decision of 18 January 2018, M.8306 Qualcomm/NXP Semiconductors, paras
491-807, 808-918 and Commitments, p 6-9.
376
European Commission Decision of 6 December 2016, M.8124 Microsoft/LinkedIn, paras 278-352 and
Commitments, p 5-7.
377
European Commission Decision of 17 December 2020, M.9660 Google/Fitbit, paras 716-817 and
Commitments of 4 November 2020, p 4-5.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
88
messaging channel APIs available to third parties that provide customer
relationship management software on a non-discriminatory basis.
378
6. Prohibition decisions
(277) Out of all 97 cases analysed, only 6 led to prohibition decisions.
379
These 6
prohibitions shall briefly be outlined in the following to appreciate which theories
of harm led to these far-reaching merger decisions.
(278) In Swedbank Franchise/Svensk Fastighetsförmedling (2014), a concentration was
blocked because of concerns about horizontal unilateral effects and vertical input
foreclosure. For the purposes of this Report, the latter is of particular interest (see
above, para (148)).
380
This was the first time a Swedish court prohibited a merger.
(279) In CTS Eventim/Four Artists (2017), the German NCA’s concerns related to
horizontal unilateral effects (see above, para (77)) as well as vertical customer
foreclosure (see above, para (178)) led to the prohibition of this acquisition.
381
The parties appealed the prohibition before the Higher Regional Court Düsseldorf,
which confirmed the Bundeskartellamt’s prohibition decision.
382
Upon further
appeal, this was also confirmed by the German Federal Court.
383
(280) In the Hungarian case of Magyar RTL Televízió/Central Digitális Média (2017),
an acquisition was blocked based on media law (see above, para (137)).
384
(281) The completed acquisition in Tobii/Smartbox (2019) was prohibited and the
divestiture of Smartbox ordered due to competition concerns related to horizontal
unilateral effects (see above, para (78)) as well as vertical input (see above, para
(149)) and customer (see above, para (177)) foreclosure.
385
Tobii had proposed
two different sets of remedies to the UK NCA, with a structural element to address
the horizontal competition concerns and a behavioural element to address the
vertical competition concerns. Concerning the structural element, Tobii proposed
to divest Smartbox’s augmentative assistive communication (AAC) hardware
business (partial divestiture) and to keep Smartbox’s AAC software business,
while granting the buyer a perpetual license for Smartbox’s popular software on
FRAND terms as well as allowing it to resell Tobii’s eye gaze cameras. However,
378
European Commission Decision of 27 January 2022, M.10262 Meta/Kustomer, para 1 of the
commitments.
379
Although Meta/Giphy in the UK is labelled as a ‘clearance’ decision of an already completed acquisition,
this amounted to a substantive prohibition by requiring a full divestiture of the target, and is therefore also
counted as such; Competition & Markets Authority, Meta/Giphy (ME/6891/20-II, 6 December 2021).
380
Stockholms tingsrätt, Swedbank Franchise/Svensk Fastighetsförmedling (T 3629-14, 16 December
2014).
381
Bundeskartellamt, CTS Eventim/Four Artists (B6-35/17, 23 November 2017).
382
Oberlandesgericht Düsseldorf, 5 December 2018, Kart 3/18 (V) CTS Eventim/Four Artists.
383
Although the Higher Regional Court had not allowed a further appeal on legal grounds, the Federal
Court decided to accept such an appeal (even after the parties had abandoned the merger);
Bundesgerichtshof, 24 March 2020, KVZ 3/19 CTS Eventim/Four Artists. Subsequently, the Federal
Court confirmed the Bundeskartellamt’s decision that the strengthening of a dominant position can be a
valid reason for prohibiting a merger where competition would be further limited by a concentration;
Bundesgerichtshof, 12 January 2021, KVR 34/20 CTS Eventim/Four Artists.
384
Gazdasági Versenyhivatal, Magyar RTL Televízió/Central Digitális Média (Vj/87/2016, 24 January
2017).
385
Competition & Markets Authority, Tobii/Smartbox (ME/6780/18-II, 15 August 2019).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
89
the NCA concluded that these commitments would not effectively address the
competition concerns it had identified, based on a risk framework including
specification risks, circumvention risks, distortion risks and monitoring and
enforcement risks. Based thereon, the NCA concluded that the proposed remedies
would not fully address these risks and would only have a limited impact in
addressing the competition concerns identified. Full divestiture was regarded as
the only effective remedy available.
(282) While the Competition Appeal Tribunal agreed with Tobii that the Competition
& Markets Authority’s had not provided sufficient evidential basis for its concerns
relating to partial input foreclosure, it upheld the NCA’s divestiture decision on
all but this one ground.
386
Tobii was not granted permission to appeal that
decision.
387
Tobii has since divested Smartbox.
388
(283) In Sabre/Farelogix (2020), the proposed acquisition of Farelogix by Sabre was
also prohibited by the UK NCA based on horizontal unilateral effects (see above,
para (79)).
389
The parties had offered commitments to the authority, including (i)
making Farelogix’s FLX Services available at the same or lower prices to those
at the time, including levels of support, for an agreed-upon period of time, (ii)
offering all current Sabre GDS customers and all current FLX OC customers the
opportunity to extend their existing contract on the same terms for a period of at
least three years, (iii) to continue investing in the development of FLX Services
capabilities at levels no less than current levels, for an agreed-upon period of time,
and (iv) to continue to offer and support FLX Services capabilities to any third
parties and all outlets that wish to use them to connect to Sabre, other GDSs, other
distribution partners, or directly to travel agents on an agnostic basis, for an
agreed-upon period of time. The NCA concluded, however, that the parties’
remedies proposal did not weigh up the loss of competition that would result from
Farelogix no longer being an independent player that competes to meet airlines’
evolving needs. It regarded the prohibition of the merger as the only effective
means of avoiding a significant lessening of competition.
(284) The Competition Appeal Tribunal dismissed Sabre’s appeal of the NCA
decision.
390
As a result of this case, the merger was terminated on 1 May 2020.
391
In the United States, the Department of Justice equally sought to prohibit the
merger that it viewed as ‘a dominant firm’s attempt to eliminate a disruptive
competitor after years of trying to stamp it out’.
392
While this case was cleared by
386
Tobii/Smartbox, [2020] CAT 1, 10 January 2020.
387
Tobii/Smartbox, [2020] CAT 6, 17 February 2020.
388
‘Tobii divests Smartbox’ (6 October 2020) <https://www.tobii.com/group/news-media/press-
releases/2020/10/tobii-divests-smartbox/>.
389
Competition & Markets Authority, Sabre/Farelogix (ME/6806/19-II, 9 April 2020).
390
Sabre/Farelogix, [2021] CAT 11, 21 May 2021.
391
‘Sabre and Farelogix $360m merger deal cancelled’ (1 May 2020) <https://www.phocuswire.com/sabre-
farelogix-merger-terminated>.
392
Sabre/Farelogix, Complaint in Case 1:19-cv-01548-UNA (20 August 2019).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
90
a US District Court in a rather controversial judgment,
393
the case was
subsequently vacated because the parties abandoned their merger.
394
(285) Most recently, the UK NCA cleared Meta’s completed acquisition of Giphy
subject to conditions in December 2021 with the condition being a full
divestiture of Giphy, thus effectively amounting to an ex post prohibition.
395
The
NCA voiced concerns related to horizontal effects (loss of a potential competitor;
see above, para (118)) as well as to vertical input foreclosure (see above, para
(150)). In order to address the authority’s concerns, Meta had offered a number of
commitments: (i) an open access remedy relating to APIs, (ii) a commingling
remedy that would allow Giphy search results to be interspersed with results from
another GIF provider, and (iii) a white label licensing remedy to sell a white label
copy of Giphy’s content library and a license to use Giphy’s search algorithm for
five years. The authority was not satisfied with these proposed behavioural
commitments as the competition concerns that arose in this dynamic market
would not be alleviated by time-limited behavioural changes. It also highlighted
a risk of Meta circumventing the commitments, and difficulties in monitoring and
enforcing.
(286) This case was on appeal before the Competition Appeal Tribunal on six grounds,
of which the Tribunal dismissed five and only upheld one in relation to a failure
on the part of the UK NCA to properly consult with the parties.
396
(287) Overall, the picture on prohibitions of digital mergers is rather straightforward:
apart from the special Hungarian case based on media law, all prohibitions related
to the loss of an actual competitor (plus, in one case, vertical customer foreclosure)
or the loss of a potential competitor plus vertical input foreclosure. This shows
that horizontal theories of harm continue to be regarded as the most credible threat
to competitive markets, also in digital environments, despite recent research that
has shown that conglomerate (and vertical) effects resulting from digital mergers
merit closer scrutiny.
397
393
US v Sabre/Farelogix, 452 F. Supp. 3d 97 (D. Del. 2020). That court applied two-sided market theory
in a way that does not correspond to market realities (see p 136), holding that two-sided platforms cannot
compete with one-sided market offerings based on Ohio v American Express, 138 S. Ct. 2274, 2285 (2018).
394
As the Department of Justice explained when asking the US Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit to
vacate the District Court judgment, it also did so because that judgment’s pronouncements regarding
competition among one- and two-sided businesses would have too much of a bearing on future antitrust
cases; US Department of Justice’s Motion to Vacate, Case No. 20-1767 (12 May 2020). The District Court’s
judgment was vacated on 20 July 2020.
395
Competition & Markets Authority, Meta/Giphy (ME/6891/20-II, 6 December 2021).
396
Meta/Giphy, [2022] CAT 26, 14 June 2022.
397
Witt (n 13).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
91
VI. Conclusions
(288) In Europe, national merger cases in digital and technology markets have
proliferated in recent years. This has enabled the comparative analysis of the
decisional practice carried out in this Report. This comparison allows us, for the
first time, a glimpse into the theories of harm that NCAs have applied in these
merger cases as well as a better understanding of the types of remedies that NCAs
regarded as effective to address the competitive concerns they found to arise.
(289) While this conclusion is not the place to repeat the main findings deduced from
this comparison for this, the reader is referred to the executive summary and the
introduction it is safe to say that the NCA analysis still very much runs along
the traditional lines of horizontal vertical conglomerate effects. Within these
traditional categories, however, NCAs are increasingly accommodating the
specific characteristics of competition in digital and technology markets: data and
data capabilities as an important asset, multi-homing of users as a factor to
consider, the presence of Big Tech conglomerates as a competitive force that
smaller players need to reckon with, ecosystem competition, and many more.
Types of anti-competitive behaviour that appear to be encountered more
frequently in these digital and technology markets are also increasingly being
considered when remedies are negotiated.
(290) Going forward, it will be useful to keep two things in mind: First of all, digital
markets are often highly dynamic, meaning that merger analysis may need to go
beyond the traditional framework in order to do better justice to the complexities
of digital markets. While the merger laws are often flexible enough to
accommodate markets that are constantly evolving, they also need to be applied
with this flexibility in mind. Here, it will be decisive how courts review NCA
decisions in digital and technology markets. Merger remedies also need to adapt
to this dynamism. As was seen, access and interoperability remedies have already
become an often-used remedy in these types of cases, and this may increase as we
move into the future.
(291) Secondly, as national merger control is increasingly gaining experience in
assessing mergers in digital markets with a focus on keeping these markets
competitive, cooperation among NCAs and between the European Commission
and NCAs will remain essential. For Europe, it continues to be the case that
numerous mergers in the digital sphere are analysed at a national level, as they
can only reach the European Commission based on a referral from NCAs or a
request from the parties as long as European turnover thresholds are not reached.
Here, European consistency will continue to depend on close cooperation between
and among NCAs and the European Commission. This is what is required in order
for merger control in Europe to reach its full potential.
(292) In some parts of this world, legislative proposals have already been tabled to better
adapt merger control to digital markets. While a Report comparing national
merger cases is not the place to discuss any such proposals in detail, it is worth
noting that no such proposals have been adopted yet. In the UK, a bespoke merger
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
92
regime for digital mergers was proposed that should not only include a transaction
value threshold but also bring about a change in the probability standard that
applies to mergers of companies with a strategic market status.
398
Currently, it
appears that these legislative proposals will not be adopted as originally
planned.
399
(293) A legislative act that was recently published is the Digital Markets Act (DMA) at
the European Union level.
400
In the DMA, a certain concern with mergers by Big
Tech has become palpable. First of all, designated gatekeepers will need to keep
the European Commission informed of their acquisitions, thus allowing the
Commission to monitor their M&A behaviour and giving it insights into
acquisition strategies by gatekeepers.
401
The DMA also goes further and foresees
that once a designated gatekeeper has systematically infringed the DMA, the
Commission may not only increase the fine to 20% (instead of 10%) of the
previous year’s turnover,
402
but it may also impose, based on a market
investigation into that systematic non-compliance, a remedy that can include ‘the
prohibition, during a limited period, for the gatekeeper to enter into a [merger]
regarding the core platform services or the other services provided in the digital
sector or enabling the collection of data that are affected by the systematic non-
compliance’.
403
While this new power will have to be tried and tested, it indicates
that the buying spree on which many Big Tech companies have gone over the past
decade has raised concerns as to the contestability of these markets.
(294) In the area of soft law, the Korean Fair Trade Commission (KFTC) just launched
a study into platform merger review, inquiring into the types of harms that such
merger reviews should focus on.
404
(295) Apart from the legislative and soft law proposals that are currently underway in
different parts of the world, a lot can be done with the merger laws we currently
have in Europe. For the future, it could be useful to frame theories of harm more
in line with the complex and interrelated market realities that we find in the digital
environment, and thereby obtain a clearer view of the three issues that have, so
far, only been assessed in a smaller number of national cases: digital ecosystems,
data advantages and the interaction of mergers with abuse of dominance. A review
of the national decisional practice on digital and technology mergers against the
398
Secretary of State for Digital, Culture, Media & Sport and Secretary of State for Business, Energy and
Industrial Strategy (n 65).
399
Ibitoye (n 65).
400
Regulation (EU) 2022/1925 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 14 September 2022 on
contestable and fair markets in the digital sector and amending Directives (EU) 2019/1937 and (EU)
2020/1828 (Digital Markets Act, DMA) [2022] OJ L265/1.
401
Article 14 DMA. More precisely, that Article speaks of concentrations ‘where the merging entities or
the target of concentration provide core platform services or any other services in the digital sector or enable
the collection of data’.
402
Article 30 para 2 DMA.
403
Article 18 para 2 DMA.
404
Wooyoung Lee, ‘South Korea launches new study to come up with platform merger review guidelines’
MLex (15 March 2022)
<https://content.mlex.com/#/content/1365494?referrer=email_dailycontentset&dailyId=f986fa0ee8864bd
ba7c0d88f4b4892fc>.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
93
background of the European decisional practice, such as the one carried out in this
Report, may be a good starting point for further developing merger control in
Europe and beyond in order to enable it to fully capture the anti-competitive
effects that certain digital mergers are capable of producing.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
94
References
‘Cisco-Acacia merger receives antitrust approval in US, still needs OK in Germany and
China’ MLex (27 September 2019)
<https://content.mlex.com/#/content/1131563?referrer=portfolio_openrelatedcontent
>.
‘Dante International, PC Garage merger gets conditional Romanian approval’ MLex (29
November 2016)
<https://content.mlex.com/#/content/846719?referrer=search_linkclick>.
‘Delivery Hero wins conditional approval for Greek acquisitions’ MLex (2 May 2022)
<https://content.mlex.com/#/content/1374846?referrer=email_dailycontentset&dailyI
d=137821cefd9e45fbb3e5c211a46cffb5>.
‘Prosus Statement: Lapse of the Offer for Just Eat plc By Prosus N.V. Through Its
Wholly-owned Indirect Subsidiary MIH Food Delivery Holdings B.V.’
Businesswire.com (10 January 2020)
https://www.businesswire.com/news/home/20200110005400/en/Prosus-Statement-
Lapse-of-the-Offer-for-Just-Eat-plc-By-Prosus-N.V.-Through-Its-Wholly-owned-
Indirect-Subsidiary-MIH-Food-Delivery-Holdings-B.V.
‘Sabre and Farelogix $360m merger deal cancelled’ (1 May 2020)
<https://www.phocuswire.com/sabre-farelogix-merger-terminated>.
‘Tobii divests Smartbox’ (6 October 2020) <https://www.tobii.com/group/news-
media/press-releases/2020/10/tobii-divests-smartbox/>.
Alcantara, Chris, Kevin Schaul, Gerrit De Vynck and Reed Albergotti, ‘How Big Tech
got so big: Hundreds of acquisitions’ Washington Post (21 April 2021)
<https://www.washingtonpost.com/technology/interactive/2021/amazon-apple-
facebook-google-acquisitions/>.
American Economic Liberties Project, ‘Big Tech Mergers’
<https://www.economicliberties.us/big-tech-merger-tracker/>.
Autoriteit Consument & Markt, ‘After follow-up investigation, ACM still conditionally
clears acquisition of Iddink Group by Sanoma Learning’ (27 August 2021)
<https://www.acm.nl/en/publications/after-follow-investigation-acm-still-
conditionally-clears-acquisition-iddink-group-sanoma-learning>.
Bourreau, Marc, ‘Some Economics of Digital Ecosystems’ (2020)
DAF/COMP/WD(2020)89.
Bourreau, Marc, and Alexandre de Streel, ‘Digital Conglomerates and EU Competition
Policy’ (CERRE Report, March 2019).
Bundeskartellamt, ‘Bundeskartellamt clears merger between eBay Classifieds Group and
Adevinta (24 November 2020)
<https://www.bundeskartellamt.de/SharedDocs/Publikation/EN/Pressemitteilungen/2
020/24_11_2020_ebay_Adevinta.pdf?__blob=publicationFile&v=5>.
Bundeskartellamt, ‘Bundeskartellamt clears acquisition of Kustomer by Meta (formerly
Facebook)’ Press Release (11 February 2022)
<https://www.bundeskartellamt.de/SharedDocs/Meldung/EN/Pressemitteilungen/202
2/11_02_2022_Meta_Kustomer.html>.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
95
Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde, ‘Meta (Facebook)/Giphy merger: AFCA appealing against
conditional clearance’ (4 March 2022) <https://www.bwb.gv.at/en/news/news-
2022/detail/meta-facebook-giphy-merger-afca-appealing-against-conditional-
clearance>.
Competition & Markets Authority, Online Platforms and Digital Advertising Market
Study (July 2020).
Competition & Markets Authority, ‘Merger investigation into the Completed acquisition
by PUG LLC (viagogo) of the StubHub business of eBay Inc.’ (8 September 2021)
<https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/media/61379adfe90e07044435c8d0/Viagog
o_StubHub_Case_closure_summary.pdf>.
Crémer, Jacques, Heike Schweitzer and Yves-Alexandre de Montjoye, Competition
Policy in the Digital Era (2019).
Cunningham, Colleen, Florian Ederer and Song Ma, ‘Killer Acquisitions’ (2021) 129
Journal of Political Economy 649.
de Silva, Isabelle, ‘Assessing online platform mergers: Taking up the new challenges
faced by the French Competition Authority in the digital economy’ (N° 2-2018)
Concurrences 39.
Dinu, Raluca, ‘Romania’ in Daniel Mândrescu (ed), EU Competition Law and the Digital
Economy: Protecting Free and Fair Competition in an Age of Technological
(R)Evolution (XXIX FIDE Congress 2020) 451.
Eisenmann, Thomas, Geoffrey Parker and Marshall Van Alstyne, ‘Platform
Envelopment’ (2011) 32 Strategic Management Journal 1270.
European Commission, Evaluation of procedural and jurisdictional aspects of EU merger
control, SWD(2021) 66 final.
European Commission, ‘Mergers: Commission approves acquisition of Nuance by
Microsoft’ IP/21/7067 (21 December 2021).
European Commission, ‘Mergers: Commission clears acquisition of Kustomer by Meta
(formerly Facebook), subject to conditions’ IP/22/652 (27 January 2022).
European Commission, ‘Antitrust: Commission confirms unannounced inspections in the
online food delivery sector’ IP/22/4345 (6 July 2022).
Faria, Tânia Luísa, ‘Portugal’ in Daniel Mândrescu (ed), EU Competition Law and the
Digital Economy: Protecting Free and Fair Competition in an Age of Technological
(R)Evolution (XXIX FIDE Congress 2020) 431.
Federal Trade Commission, ‘Non-HSR Reported Acquisitions by Select Technology
Platforms, 2010-2019: An FTC Study’ (September 2021)
<https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/reports/non-hsr-reported-acquisitions-
select-technology-platforms-2010-2019-ftc-
study/p201201technologyplatformstudy2021.pdf>.
Fletcher, Amelia, ‘Digital Competition Policy: Are Ecosystems Different?’ (2020)
DAF/COMP/WD(2020)96.
Forsberg, Peter, Xandra Carlsson and Sebastian Wiik, ‘Sweden, Overview of merger
control activity during the last 12 months’ in Nigel Parr and Catherine Hammon (eds),
Merger Control (5th edn, 2016) 191.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
96
Furman, Jason, et al., Unlocking Digital Competition Report of the Digital Competition
Expert Panel (2019)
<https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attach
ment_data/file/785547/unlocking_digital_competition_furman_review_web.pdf>.
García García, José Marino, and Pablo Ibáñez Colomo, ‘Spain’ in Daniel Mândrescu (ed),
EU Competition Law and the Digital Economy: Protecting Free and Fair Competition
in an Age of Technological (R)Evolution (XXIX FIDE Congress 2020) 499.
Gazdasági Versenyhivatal, ‘The Hungarian Competition Authority authorised the
acquisition of Extreme Digital by eMAG’ (17 October 2019)
<https://www.gvh.hu/en/press_room/press_releases/press_releases_2019/the_hungari
an_competition_authority_authorised_the>.
Gazdasági Versenyhivatal, ‘The GVH authorised the merger of Netrisk and Biztosítás.hu’
(12 December 2019)
<https://www.gvh.hu/en/press_room/press_releases/press_releases_2019/the-gvh-
authorised-the-merger-of-netrisk-and-biztositas.hu>.
Hovenkamp, Herbert, ‘Competitive Harm from Vertical Mergers (2021) 59 The
Industrial Organization Society 139.
Ibitoye, Victoria, ‘UK scraps tougher Big Tech merger-review standard, stays quiet on
law to back digital regulator’ MLex (6 May 2022)
<https://content.mlex.com/#/content/1376156?referrer=email_dailycontentset&dailyI
d=ecdc6c88629a4326bbe6bfbb614c0e59>.
Ibitoye, Victoria, ‘Meta scores procedural win in appeal of UK Giphy selloff order, but
impact remains to be seen’ MLex (14 June 2022)
<https://content.mlex.com/#/content/1385154?referrer=portfolio_openrelatedcontent
>.
Jacobides, Michael G., and Ioannis Lianos, ‘Ecosystems and Competition Law in Theory
and Practice’ (2021) 30 Industrial and Corporate Change 1199.
Kang, Cecilia, and David McCabe, ‘F.T.C. Broadens Review of Tech Giants, Homing In
on Their Deals’ New York Times (11 February 2020).
Kindl, Jiří, and Michal Petr, ‘Czech Republic’ in Daniel Mândrescu (ed), EU Competition
Law and the Digital Economy: Protecting Free and Fair Competition in an Age of
Technological (R)Evolution (XXIX FIDE Congress 2020) 165.
Lear, ‘Ex-post Assessment of Merger Control Decisions in Digital Markets’ (9 May
2019).
Lécuyer, Tristan, ‘Digital Conglomerates and Killer Acquisitions A Discussion of the
Competitive Effects of Start-Up Acquisitions by Digital Platforms’ (N° 1-2020)
Concurrences 42.
Lim, Yong, ‘Tech Wars: Return of the Conglomerate Throwback or Dawn of a New
Series for Competition in the Digital Era?’ (2020) 19 Journal of Korean Law 47, 48.
Lombardi, Pietro, and Samuel Stolton, ‘Microsoft heads for second big EU showdown —
this time over gaming’ Politico (24 January 2022)
<https://www.politico.eu/article/microsoft-activision-eu-showdown-video-game/>.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
97
Lundqvist, Björn, ‘Sweden’ in Daniel Mândrescu (ed), EU Competition Law and the
Digital Economy: Protecting Free and Fair Competition in an Age of Technological
(R)Evolution (XXIX FIDE Congress 2020) 517.
Macintyre, Everette, ‘Statement on Conglomerate Mergers and Antitrust Laws’ (2
December 1966)
<https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/public_statements/683731/19661202_
macintyre_conglomerate_mergers_and_antitrust_laws.pdf>.
Magister, <https://www.magister.nl/>.
Mândrescu, Daniel (ed), EU Competition Law and the Digital Economy: Protecting Free
and Fair Competition in an Age of Technological (R)Evolution (XXIX FIDE Congress
2020).
McCabe, David, and Jim Tankersley, ‘Biden Urges More Scrutiny of Big Business, Such
as Tech Giants’ New York Times (16 September 2021).
Newton, Casey, and Nilay Patel, ‘“Instagram can hurt us”: Mark Zuckerberg Emails
Outline Plan to Neutralize Competitors’ The Verge (29 July 2020)
<https://www.theverge.com/2020/7/29/21345723/facebook-instagram-documents-
emails-mark-zuckerberg-kevin-systrom-hearing>.
Oberster Gerichtshof, ‘Bestätigung der kartellrechtlichen Nicht-Untersagung eines
Zusammenschlusses unter Auflagen’ (24 June 2022)
<https://www.ogh.gv.at/entscheidungen/entscheidungen-ogh/bestaetigung-der-
kartellrechtlichen-nicht-untersagung-eines-zusammenschlusses-von-m-und-g-unter-
auflagenv/>.
Petropoulos, Georgios, ‘Competition Economics of Digital Ecosystems’ (2020)
DAF/COMP/WD(2020)91.
Robertson, Viktoria H.S.E., ‘Antitrust Law and Digital Markets’ in Heinz D. Kurz,
Marlies Schütz, Rita Strohmaier and Stella S. Zilian (eds), The Routledge Handbook
of Smart Technologies: An Economic and Social Perspective (2022) 432.
Robertson, Viktoria H.S.E., ‘Antitrust Market Definition for Digital Ecosystems’ (N°2-
2021) Concurrences 3.
Robertson, Viktoria H.S.E., Competition Law’s Innovation Factor: The Relevant Market
in Dynamic Contexts in the EU and the US (Hart 2020).
Schmalensee, Richard, ‘Entry Deterrence in the Ready-to-Eat Breakfast Cereal Industry’
(1978) 9 Bell Journal of Economics 305.
Secretary of State for Digital, Culture, Media & Sport and Secretary of State for Business,
Energy and Industrial Strategy, A new pro-competition regime for digital markets
(CP 489, July 2021)
<https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attach
ment_data/file/1003913/Digital_Competition_Consultation_v2.pdf>.
Sherman Alex, and Lauren Feiner, ‘Amazon, Microsoft and Alphabet went on a buying
spree in 2021 despite D.C.’s vow to take on Big Tech’ (22 January 2022) CNBC
<https://www.cnbc.com/2022/01/22/amazon-microsoft-alphabet-set-more-deals-in-
2021-than-last-10-years.html>.
Stacey, Kiran, James Fontanella-Khan and Stefania Palma, ‘Big tech companies snap up
smaller rivals at record pace’ Financial Times (19 September 2021).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
98
Stylianou, Konstantinos, ‘Exclusion in Digital Markets’ (2018) 24 Michigan
Telecommunications & Technology Law Review 181.
Subramaniam, Mohan, et al., ‘Competing in Digital Ecosystems’ (2019) 62 Business
Horizons 83.
Sweden, ‘Agency decision-making in merger cases: from a prohibition decision to a
conditional clearance’ (3 November 2016) DAF/COMP/WP3/WD(2016)70.
Sweden, ‘Annual Report on Competition Policy Developments in Sweden’ (9 June 2017)
DAF/COMP/AR(2017)16.
Vestager, Margrethe, ‘Competition in a Big Data World’ (Munich, 17 January 2016).
Vestager, Margrethe, ‘Shaping Competition Policy in the Era of Digitisation’ (Brussels,
17 January 2019).
Wakabayashi, Daisuke, and Jack Nicas, ‘Apple, Google and a Deal That Controls the
Internet New York Times (25 October 2020).
Waters, Richard, and Leo Lewis, ‘Why gaming is the new Big Tech battleground
Financial Times (21 January 2022).
Witt, Anne C., Who’s Afraid of Conglomerate Mergers’ (2022) 67 Antitrust Bulletin
208.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
99
Table of legislation and soft law documents
European Union legislation
Consolidated Version of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union [2016] OJ
C202/47 (TFEU).
Council Regulation (EC) No 1/2003 of 16 December 2002 on the implementation of the
rules on competition laid down in Articles 81 and 82 of the Treaty [2003] OJ L1/1.
Council Regulation (EC) No 139/2004 of 20 January 2004 on the control of
concentrations between undertakings (EUMR) [2004] OJ L24/1.
Regulation (EU) 2016/679 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 27 April
2016 on the protection of natural persons with regard to the processing of personal
data and on the free movement of such data, and repealing Directive 95/46/EC
(General Data Protection Regulation, GDPR) [2016] OJ L119/1.
Regulation (EU) 2022/1925 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 14
September 2022 on contestable and fair markets in the digital sector and amending
Directives (EU) 2019/1937 and (EU) 2020/1828 (Digital Markets Act, DMA) [2022]
OJ L265/1.
National legislation
Act against Restraints of Competition, German Federal Law Gazette I 2013/1750 as
amended.
Cartel Act, Austrian Federal Law Gazette I 61/2005 as amended.
European Union soft law
EU Merger Working Group, ‘Best Practices on Cooperation between EU National
Competition Authorities in Merger Review’ (8 November 2011).
European Commission, Commission notice on remedies acceptable under Council
Regulation (EC) No 139/2004 and under Commission Regulation (EC) No 802/2004
[2008] OJ C267/1.
European Commission, Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers under the
Council Regulation on the control of concentrations between undertakings (Horizontal
Merger Guidelines 2004) [2004] OJ C31/5.
European Commission, Guidelines on the assessment of non-horizontal mergers under
the Council Regulation on the control of concentrations between undertakings (Non-
horizontal Merger Guidelines 2008) [2008] OJ C265/6.
European Commission, Commission Guidance on the application of the referral
mechanism set out in Article 22 of the Merger Regulation to certain categories of cases
[2021] OJ C113/1.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
100
National soft law
Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde and Bundeskartellamt, Leitfaden Transaktionswert-
Schwellen fr die Anmeldepflicht von Zusammenschlussvorhaben 35 Abs. 1a GWB
und § 9 Abs. 4 KartG) (January 2022).
Competition & Markets Authority, Merger Assessment Guidelines (CMA129, 18 March
2021).
US Department of Justice, Merger Guidelines (1968).
US Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines
(19 August 2010).
US Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission, Vertical Merger Guidelines
(30 June 2020).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
101
Table of cases
Australia
Australian Competition & Consumer Commission, Meta/Kustomer (18 November 2021).
Australian Competition and Consumer Commission, Turnitin/Ouriginal Group (25
November 2021).
Austria
Kartellobergericht, 23 June 2022, 16 Ok 3/22k and 16 Ok 4/22g Meta/Giphy.
Kartellgericht, 22 April 2021, 27 Kt 9/21g Tableau/Salesforce.
Kartellgericht, 22 July 2021, 28 Kt 6/21y Facebook/Giphy.
Kartellgericht, 7 February 2022, 28 Kt 8/21t and 28 Kt 9/21i Meta/Giphy.
Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde, Cisco Systems/Acacia Communications (BWB/Z-4545, 3
September 2019).
Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde, CTS Eventim/Barracuda Holding (BWB/Z-4651, 3
December 2019).
Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde, eBay/Adevinta (BWB/Z-5141, Z-5142, Z-5420 and Z-5421,
18 June 2021).
Bulgaria
Комисия за защита на конкуренцията, Net Info/Credit Garant (818/11.10.2016, 11
October 2016).
Комисия за защита на конкуренцията, Ozone Entertainment/Pulsar (906/01.08.2019,
1 August 2019).
Комисия за защита на конкуренцията, Flutter Entertainment/Stars Group
(269/16.04.2020, 16 April 2020).
China
State Administration for Market Regulation, Cisco Systems/Acacia Communications (14
January 2021).
State Administration for Market Regulation, Advanced Micro Devices/Xilinx (27 January
2022).
Cyprus
Επιτροπής Προστασίας Ανταγωνισμού, CVC Capital Partners/Skroutz Internet Services
(23/2020, 12 June 2020).
Επιτροπής Προστασίας Ανταγωνισμού, Tencent/1C Entertainment (58/2021, 1
September 2021).
Czechia
Úřad pro ochranu hospodářské soutěže, Rockaway Capital/Heureka (ÚOHS-
S0013/2016/KS-21123/2016/840/DVá, 16 May 2016).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
102
Úřad pro ochranu hospodářské soutěže, Rockaway Capital/Sully System/Netretail
(ÚOHS-S0223/2016/KS-26867/2016/840/DVá, 27 June 2016).
Estonia
Konkurentsiamet, Tulika Takso and AS Tallink Takso/Taxofon Eesti (5.1-5/16-006,
26 February 2016).
Konkurentsiamet, auto24/Meediamootor OÜ (5-5/2017-031, 30 May 2017).
Konkurentsiamet, AS Eesti Meedia/OÜ Patsiendiportaal (5-5/2017-035, 8 June 2017).
Konkurentsiamet, Media Investments & Holding/AllePal (5-5/2019-070, 20 December
2019).
European Union
Case C-252/21, Meta Platforms/Bundeskartellamt [2021] OJ C320/16 (pending).
Case C-449/21, Towercast v Autorité de la concurrence [2021] OJ C452/9 (pending).
Case C-48/22 P, Google and Alphabet/Commission (Google Shopping) [2022] OJ
C191/10 (pending).
Case T-79/12 Cisco Systems and Messagenet v Commission, ECLI:EU:T:2013:635.
Case T-612/17, Google and Alphabet/Commission (Google Shopping),
ECLI:EU:T:2021:763
European Commission Decision of 11 March 2008, COMP/M.4731
Google/DoubleClick.
European Commission Decision of 18 February 2010, COMP/M.5727
Microsoft/Yahoo! Search Business.
European Commission Decision of 7 October 2011, COMP/M.6281 Microsoft/Skype.
European Commission Decision of 10 February 2012, COMP/M.6474
GE/Microsoft/JV.
European Commission Decision of 13 February 2012, COMP/M.6381
Google/Motorola Mobility.
European Commission Decision of 4 December 2012, COMP/M.7047 Microsoft/Nokia.
European Commission Decision of 25 July 2014, COMP/M.7290 Apple/Beats.
European Commission Decision of 3 October 2014, COMP/M.7217
Facebook/WhatsApp.
European Commission Decision of 3 October 2014, COMP/M.7217
Facebook/WhatsApp.
European Commission Decision of 14 October 2015, M.7688 Intel/Altera.
European Commission Decision of 23 November 2015, M.7686 Avago/Broadcom.
European Commission Decision of 23 February 2016, M.7813 Sanofi/Google/DMI JV.
European Commission Decision of 6 December 2016, M.8124 Microsoft/LinkedIn.
European Commission Decision of 12 May 2017, M.8314 Broadcom/Brocade.
European Commission Decision of 27 June 2017, AT.39740 Google Search (Shopping).
European Commission Decision of 6 September 2018, M.8788 Apple/Shazam.
European Commission Decision of 18 January 2018, M.8306 Qualcomm/NXP
Semiconductors.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
103
European Commission Decision of 12 October 2018, M.9054 Broadcom/CA.
European Commission Decision of 19 October 2018, M.8994 Microsoft/GitHub.
European Commission Decision of 30 October 2019, M.9538 Broadcom/Symantec
Enterprise Security Business.
European Commission Decision of 17 December 2020, M.9660 Google/Fitbit.
European Commission Decision of 5 March 2021, M.10001 Microsoft/ZeniMax.
European Commission Decision of 20 May 2021, M.10059 SK Hynix/Intel’s NAND and
SSD Business.
European Commission Decision of 30 June 2021, COMP/M.10097 Advanced Micro
Devices/Xilinx.
European Commission Decision of 21 December 2021, M.10290 Microsoft/Nuance.
European Commission Decision of 27 January 2022, M.10262 Meta/Kustomer.
European Commission Decision of 15 March 2022, M.10349 Amazon/MGM.
France
Autorité de la concurrence, Rakuten/Alpha Direct Services (13-DCC-08, 16 January
2013).
Autorité de la concurrence, Crédit Mutuel Arkéa/Primonial Management/Blackfin/
Latour Capital/Primonial Holding (15-DCC-105, 12 August 2015).
Autorité de la concurrence, Fnac/Darty (16-DCC-111, 27 July 2016).
Autorité de la concurrence, Axel Springer/Concept Multimédia (18-DCC-18, 1 February
2018).
Autorité de la concurrence, TF1/Aufeminin (18-DCC-63, 23 April 2018).
Germany
Bundesgerichtshof, 12 January 2021, KVR 34/20 CTS Eventim/Four Artists.
Bundesgerichtshof, 24 March 2020, KVZ 3/19 CTS Eventim/Four Artists.
Oberlandesgericht Düsseldorf, 5 December 2018, Kart 3/18 (V) CTS Eventim/Four
Artists.
Bundeskartellamt, Axel Springer/Immowelt (B6-39/15, 20 April 2015).
Bundeskartellamt, ProSiebenSat.1/Verivox (B8-76/15, 24 July 2015).
Bundeskartellamt, OCPE II Master (Parship)/EliteMedianet (B6-57/15, 22 October
2015).
Bundeskartellamt, CTS Eventim/FKP Scorpio (B6-53/16, 3 January 2017).
Bundeskartellamt, CTS Eventim/Four Artists (B6-35/17, 23 November 2017).
Bundeskartellamt, Facebook (B6-22/16, 6 February 2019).
Bundeskartellamt, PayPal/Honey Science (B6-86/19, 17 December 2019).
Bundeskartellamt, Cisco Systems/Acacia Communications (B7-205/19, 6 February
2020).
Bundeskartellamt, Parship and ElitePartner/Lovoo (B6-29/20, 6 July 2020).
Bundeskartellamt, Adevinta/eBay Classifieds Group (B6-41/20, 23 November 2020).
Bundeskartellamt, Meta/Kustomer (B6-37/21, 9 December 2021).
Bundeskartellamt, Meta/Kustomer (B6-21/22, 11 February 2022).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
104
Greece
Επιτροπή Ανταγωνισμού, OPAP/DeepInvestments/Padian/GML Interactive (693/2019,
17 October 2019).
Επιτροπή Ανταγωνισμού, Saiga/Skroutz (714/2020, 24 June 2020).
Επιτροπή Ανταγωνισμού, OPAP/Kaizen Gaming Internaional (725/2021, 1 March
2021).
Επιτροπή Ανταγωνισμού, Delivery Hero/Alfa Distributions/Inkat/Delivery.gr/E-table
(775/2022, 18 April 2022).
Hungary
Kúria, Magyar RTL Televízió/Central Digitális Média (Kf.IV.38.095/2018/10, 9
December 2019).
Fővárosi Törvényszék, Magyar RTL Televízió/Central Digitális Média
(21.K.700.023/2018/12, 8 June 2018).
Gazdasági Versenyhivatal, Magyar RTL Televízió/Central Digitális Média (VJ/87/2016,
24 January 2017).
Gazdasági Versenyhivatal, Renesas Electronics Corporation/Integrated Device
Technology (VJ/35-10/2018, 14 November 2018).
Gazdasági Versenyhivatal, Netrisk.hu/Biztosítás.hu (VJ/12/2019, 12 December 2019).
Gazdasági Versenyhivatal, eMAG/Extreme Digital (VJ/14/2019, 17 October 2019).
Ireland
Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Paddy Power/Betfair (M/15/059, 15
January 2016).
Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Ladbrokes/Gala Coral (M/16/007,
10 March 2016).
Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Stars Group/Sky Betting & Gaming
(M/18/038, 18 June 2018).
Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, EQT Fund Management/SUSE
(M/18/066, 18 September 2018).
Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Applied Materials/Kokusai Electric
Corporation (M/19/027, 11 October 2019).
Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, BoyleSports/GT Retail (M/19/032,
14 February 2020).
Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Flutter Entertainment/Stars Group
(M/20/001, 12 May 2020).
Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Booster/Liftoff Mobile (M/21/002,
15 February 2021).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
105
Italy
Autoritá Garante della Concorrenza e del Mercato, OEP 14 Coöperatief/Techedge
(28331, 4 August 2020).
Malta
Malta Competition and Consumer Affairs Authority, GVC Holdings/Ladbrokes Coral
Group (COMP-MCCAA/4/18, 21 March 2018).
Malta Competition and Consumer Affairs Authority, Flutter Entertainment/Stars Group
(COMP-MCCAA/03/2020, 18 February 2020).
Netherlands
College van Beroep voor het Bedrijfsleven, Sanoma/Iddink (21/467, 21/468 & 21/469,
12 July 2022), ECLI:NL:CBB:2022:411.
Rechtbank Rotterdam, Sanoma/Iddink (ROT 19/5120, 4 March 2020),
ECLI:NL:RBROT:2021:1766.
Autoriteit Consument & Markt, Sanoma/Iddink (ACM/19/035555, 28 August 2019).
Autoriteit Consument & Markt, DPG/Sanoma (ACM/19/038207, 10 April 2020).
Autoriteit Consument & Markt, NS Groep/Pon Netherlands (ACM/20/038614, 20 May
2020).
Poland
Urząd Ochrony Konkurencji i Konsumentów, 1&1 Internet/Home.pl (DKK-216/2015, 22
December 2015).
Portugal
Autoridade da Concorrência, KKR/Cabolink (Ccent. 41/2018, 8 November 2018).
Autoridade da Concorrência, Sonae/CTT - Correios de Portugal JV (Ccent. 27/2018, 19
July 2018).
Autoridade da Concorrência, Siris/Travelport (Ccent. 1/2019, 7 February 2019).
Autoridade da Concorrência, Claranet Portugal/Bizdirect (Ccent. 27/2021, 25 June
2021).
Autoridade da Concorrência, Claranet Portugal/OutScope Solutions (Ccent. 38/2021, 24
August 2021).
Autoridade da Concorrência, Delivery Hero/Glovo (Ccent. 61/2021, 25 January 2022).
Romania
România Consiliul Concurenței, Dante International/PC Garage (84/24.11.2016, 24
November 2016).
România Consiliul Concurenței, Glovoappro/Foodpanda (86/22.11.2021, 22 November
2021).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
106
Singapore
Competition and Consumer Commission of Singapore, Advanced Micro Devices/Xilinx
(400/140/2021/003, 30 August 2021).
Slovenia
Javna agencija Republike Slovenije za varstvo konkurence, Sully System/CENEJE (3061-
27/2017-71, 12 April 2018).
Javna agencija Republike Slovenije za varstvo konkurence, ECE/ELTUS PLUS (3061-
41/2018, 25 April 2019).
Javna agencija Republike Slovenije za varstvo konkurence, Shoppster/IDEO PLUS
(3061-9/2020-14, 24 April 2020).
Javna agencija Republike Slovenije za varstvo konkurence, Allegro.eu/MIMOVRSTE
(3061-25/2021-6, 24 January 2022).
Spain
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Schibsted/Milanuncios
(C/0573/14, 20 November 2014).
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Just Eat/La Nevera Roja
(C/0730/16, 31 March 2016).
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Daimler/Hailo/MyTaxi/Negocio
Hailo (C/0802/16, 24 November 2016).
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Just Eat Spain/Canary Delivery
Company (C/1046/19, 10 September 2019).
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, MIH Food Delivery Holdings/Just
Eat (C/1072/19, 5 December 2019).
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Flutter Entertainment/Stars
Group (C/1094/20, 12 March 2020).
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Turnitin/Ouriginal Group
(C/1220/21, 19 October 2021).
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Delivery Hero/Glovo (C/1260/21,
23 February 2022).
Sweden
Stockholms tingsrätt, Swedbank Franchise/Svensk Fastighetsförmedling (T 3629-14, 16
December 2014).
Konkurrensverket, Blocket/Hemnet (84/2016, 2016).
United Kingdom
Meta/Giphy, [2022] CAT 26, 14 June 2022.
Sabre/Farelogix, [2021] CAT 11, 21 May 2021.
Tobii/Smartbox, [2020] CAT 1, 10 January 2020.
Tobii/Smartbox, [2020] CAT 6, 17 February 2020.
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
107
Office of Fair Trading, Google/BeatThatQuote (ME/4912/11, 1 July 2011).
Office of Fair Trading, Facebook/Instagram (ME/5525/12, 14 August 2012).
Office of Fair Trading, Web Reservations/Hostelbookers.com (ME/6062/13, 2 August
2013).
Competition & Markets Authority, esure Group/Gocompare.com (ME/6495-14, 23
February 2015).
Competition & Markets Authority, Ticketmaster/Seatwave/Timbre (ME/6505-14, 26
March 2015).
Competition & Markets Authority, Financière Richmond/Net-A-Porter (ME/6538-15, 2
September 2015).
Competition & Markets Authority, CliniSys Group/Roper Technologies (ME/6564/15, 11
December 2015).
Competition & Markets Authority, Betfair Group/Paddy Power (ME/6572/15, 17
December 2015).
Competition & Markets Authority, Mapil Bidco/Chain Reaction Cycles/Decade
(ME/6569/16, 30 June 2016).
Competition & Markets Authority, Ladbrokes/Gala Coral (ME/6556-15-II, 26 July
2016).
Competition & Markets Authority, ZPG/Websky (ME/6690/17, 29 June 2017).
Competition & Markets Authority, Blackbaud/Giving (ME/6700/17, 8 September 2017).
Competition & Markets Authority, Just Eat/Hungryhouse (ME/6659-16-II, 16 November
2017).
Competition & Markets Authority, Moneysupermarket.com/Decision Technologies
(ME/6749/18, 7 August 2018).
Competition & Markets Authority, eBay/Motors.co.uk (ME/6774/18, 12 February 2019).
Competition & Markets Authority, PayPal/iZettle (ME/6766/18-II, 12 June 2019).
Competition & Markets Authority, Salesforce.com/Tableau Software (ME/6841/19, 22
November 2019).
Competition & Markets Authority, Tobii/Smartbox (ME/6780/18-II, 15 August 2019).
Competition & Markets Authority, Google/Looker (ME/6839/19, 13 February 2020).
Competition & Markets Authority, Flutter Entertainment/Stars Group (ME/6865/19, 31
March 2020).
Competition & Markets Authority, Sabre/Farelogix (ME/6806/19-II, 9 April 2020).
Competition & Markets Authority, Amazon/Roofoods (ME/6836/19-II, 4 August 2020).
Competition & Markets Authority, Pug/StubHub (ME/6868/19-II, 2 February 2021).
Competition & Markets Authority, Adevinta/eBay Classifieds Group (ME/6897/20, 16
February 2021).
Competition & Markets Authority, Uber International/GPC Computer Software
(ME/6903/20, 29 March 2021).
Competition & Markets Authority, SK hynix/Intel (ME/6913/20, 28 June 2021).
Competition & Markets Authority, Advanced Micro Devices/Xilinx (ME/6915/20, 29
June 2021).
Competition & Markets Authority, Turnitin/Ouriginal (ME/6931/21, 26 July 2021).
Competition & Markets Authority, Meta/Kustomer (ME/6920/20, 27 September 2021).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
108
Competition & Markets Authority, Auction Technology Group/Live Auctioneers
(ME/6942/21, 29 September 2021).
Competition & Markets Authority, Decision to impose a penalty on Facebook, Inc.,
Tabby Acquisition Sub Inc., and Facebook UK Limited under section 94A of the
Enterprise Act 2002 (20 October 2021).
Competition & Markets Authority, Meta/Giphy (ME/6891/20-II, 6 December 2021).
Competition & Markets Authority, Decision to impose a penalty on Meta Platforms, Inc.,
Tabby Acquisition Sub Inc., and Facebook UK Limited under section 94A of the
Enterprise Act 2002 (4 February 2022).
Competition & Markets Authority, Microsoft/Nuance (ME/6940/21, 2 March 2022).
United States
Ohio v American Express, 138 S. Ct. 2274, 2285.
US v Sabre/Farelogix, 452 F. Supp. 3d 97 (D. Del. 2020).
US v Google, US District Court for the District of Columbia, Case 1:20-cv-03010
(complaint brought on 20 October 2020, amended on 15 January 2021).
Federal Trade Commission v Facebook, US District Court for the District of Columbia,
Case 1:20-cv-3590 (11 January 2022).
Federal Trade Commission, Statement Concerning Google/DoubleClick, FTC File No.
071-0170 (11 December 2007).
Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
109
List of figures
1. Quantitative insights: Outcome of 97 national merger cases ..................................... 28
2. Quantitative insights: Distribution by country of 69 selected national merger cases 29
3. Quantitative insights: Combinations of theories of harm in 69 selected national
merger cases ............................................................................................................... 30
4. Quantitative insights: Distribution of horizontal theories of harm in 69 selected
national merger cases ................................................................................................. 31
5. Quantitative insights: Distribution of vertical theories of harm in 69 selected
national merger cases ................................................................................................. 32
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
110
Annex I: 97 national cases on digital and technology mergers, coded by outcome
Outcome
ID
running number of the case summaries
provided in Annex III. Where an ID is
assigned, the national decision was also
coded based on the theories of harm
employed (see Annex II).
UCPH1
Unconditional clearance phase 1
UCPH2
Unconditional clearance phase 2
CCPH1
Conditional clearance phase 1
CCPH2
Conditional clearance phase 2
PROH
Prohibition
WITH
Withdrawal
NONAPP
Non-applicability
ID
Country
Decisional body
Date
Case name
Case number
Outcome
1
AT
Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde
03.12.2019
CTS Eventim/Barracuda Holding
BWB/Z-4651
CCPH1
2
AT
Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde
18.06.2021
eBay/Adevinta
BWB/Z-5141, Z-
5142, Z-5420 and
Z-5421
CCPH1
3
AT
Kartellgericht
07.02.2022
Meta/Giphy
28 Kt 8/21t and 28
Kt 9/21i
CCPH2
BG
Комисия за защита на
конкуренцията
11.10.2016
Net Info/Credit Garant
818/11.10.2016
UCPH1
BG
Комисия за защита на
конкуренцията
01.08.2019
Ozone Entertainment/Pulsar
906/01.08.2019
UCPH1
CY
Επιτροπής Προστασίας
Ανταγωνισμού
12.06.2020
CVC Capital Partners/Skroutz Internet
Services
23/2020
UCPH1
CY
Επιτροπής Προστασίας
Ανταγωνισμού
01.09.2021
Tencent/1C Entertainment
58/2021
UCPH1
4
CZ
Úřad pro ochranu hospodářské
soutěže
16.05.2016
Rockaway Capital/Heureka
ÚOHS-
S0013/2016/KS-
21123/2016/840/DVá
CCPH1
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
111
ID
Country
Decisional body
Date
Case name
Case number
Outcome
CZ
Úřad pro ochranu hospodářské
soutěže
27.06.2016
Rockaway Capital/Sully System/Netretail
ÚOHS-
S0223/2016/KS-
26867/2016/840/DVá
UCPH1
9
DE
Bundeskartellamt
20.04.2015
Axel Springer/Immowelt
B6-39/15
UCPH1
10
DE
Bundeskartellamt
24.07.2015
ProSiebenSat.1/Verivox
B8-76/15
UCPH1
11
DE
Bundeskartellamt
22.10.2015
OCPE II Master/EliteMedianet
B6-57/15
UCPH2
12
DE
Bundeskartellamt
03.01.2017
CTS Eventim/FKP Scorpio
B6-53/16
UCPH2
13
DE
Bundeskartellamt
23.11.2017
CTS Eventim/Four Artists
B6-35/17
PROH
14
DE
Bundeskartellamt
17.12.2019
PayPal/Honey Science
B6-86/19
UCPH1
15
DE
Bundeskartellamt
11.11.2019
Cisco Systems/Acacia Communications
B7-205/19
UCPH1
DE
Bundeskartellamt
06.07.2020
Parship & Elite Partner/Lovoo
B6-29/20
UCPH1
DE
Bundeskartellamt
23.11.2020
Adevinta/eBay Classifieds Group
B6-41/20
UCPH1
16
DE
Bundeskartellamt
11.02.2022
Meta/Kustomer
B6-21/22
UCPH1
EE
Konkurentsiamet
26.02.2016
Tulika Takso and AS Tallink Takso/Taxofon
Eesti OÜ
5.1-5/16-006
UCPH1
EE
Konkurentsiamet
30.05.2017
auto24/Meediamootor OÜ
5-5/2017-031
UCPH1
EE
Konkurentsiamet
08.06.2017
AS Eesti Meedia/OÜ Patsiendiportaal
5-5/2017-035
UCPH1
EE
Konkurentsiamet
20.12.2019
Media Investments & Holding/AllePal
5-5/2019-070
UCPH1
EL
Επιτροπή Ανταγωνισμού
17.10.2019
OPAP/DeepInvestments/Padian/GML
Interactive
693/2019
UCPH1
EL
Επιτροπή Ανταγωνισμού
24.06.2020
Saiga/Skroutz
714/2020
UCPH1
EL
Επιτροπή Ανταγωνισμού
01.03.2021
OPAP/Kaizen Gaming Internaional
725/2021
UCPH1
17
EL
Επιτροπή Ανταγωνισμού
18.04.2022
Delivery Hero/Alfa
Distributions/Inkat/Delivery.gr/E-table
775/2022
CCPH2
43
ES
Comisión Nacional de los
Mercados y la Competencia
20.11.2014
Schibsted/Milanuncios
C/0573/14
CCPH2
44
ES
Comisión Nacional de los
Mercados y la Competencia
31.03.2016
Just Eat/La Nevera Roja
C/0730/16
CCPH1
45
ES
Comisión Nacional de los
Mercados y la Competencia
24.11.2016
Daimler/Hailo/MyTaxi/Negocio Hailo
C/0802/16
UCPH1
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
112
ID
Country
Decisional body
Date
Case name
Case number
Outcome
46
ES
Comisión Nacional de los
Mercados y la Competencia
10.09.2019
Just Eat Spain/Canary Delivery Company
C/1046/19
UCPH1
47
ES
Comisión Nacional de los
Mercados y la Competencia
05.12.2019
MIH Food Delivery Holdings/Just Eat
C/1072/19
CCPH1
48
ES
Comisión Nacional de los
Mercados y la Competencia
19.10.2021
Turnitin/Ouriginal Group
C/1220/21
UCPH1
ES
Comisión Nacional de los
Mercados y la Competencia
23.02.2022
Delivery Hero/Glovo
C/1260/21
UCPH1
5
FR
Autorité de la concurrence
16.01.2013
Rakuten Europe/Alpha Direct Services
13-DCC-08
UCPH1
6
FR
Autorité de la concurrence
12.08.2015
Crédit Mutuel Arkéa/Latour
Capital/BlackFin/Primonial
15-DCC-105
UCPH1
7
FR
Autorité de la concurrence
01.02.2018
Axel Springer/Concept Multimédia
18-DCC-18
UCPH2
8
FR
Autorité de la concurrence
23.04.2018
TF1/Aufeminin
18-DCC-63
UCPH1
18
HU
Gazdasági Versenyhivatal
20.02.2017
Magyar RTL Televízió/Central Digitális
Média
Vj/87-198/2016
PROH
HU
Gazdasági Versenyhivatal
14.11.2018
Renesas Electronics Corporation/Integrated
Device Technology
VJ/35-10/2018
UCPH1
19
HU
Gazdasági Versenyhivatal
17.10.2019
eMAG/Extreme Digital
VJ/14/2019
UCPH2
20
HU
Gazdasági Versenyhivatal
12.12.2019
Netrisk.hu/Biztosítás.hu
VJ/12/2019
UCPH2
21
IE
Competition and Consumer
Protection Commission
15.01.2016
Paddy Power/Betfair
M/15/059
UCPH1
22
IE
Competition and Consumer
Protection Commission
10.03.2016
Ladbrokes/Gala Coral
M/16/007
UCPH1
23
IE
Competition and Consumer
Protection Commission
18.06.2018
Stars Group/Sky Betting & Gaming
M/18/038
UCPH1
24
IE
Competition and Consumer
Protection Commission
18.09.2018
EQT Fund Management/SUSE
M/18/066
UCPH1
25
IE
Competition and Consumer
Protection Commission
11.10.2019
Applied Materials/Kokusai Electric
Corporation
M/19/027
UCPH1
IE
Competition and Consumer
Protection Commission
14.02.2020
BoyleSports/GT Retail
M/19/032
UCPH1
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
113
ID
Country
Decisional body
Date
Case name
Case number
Outcome
26
IE
Competition and Consumer
Protection Commission
11.05.2020
Flutter Entertainment/Stars Group
M/20/001
UCPH1
27
IE
Competition and Consumer
Protection Commission
15.02.2021
Booster/Liftoff Mobile
M/21/002
UCPH1
28
IT
Autoritá Garante della
Concorrenza e del Mercato
04.08.2020
OEP 14 Coöperatief/Techedge
28331
UCPH1
29
MT
Malta Competition and Consumer
Affairs Authority
21.03.2018
GVC Holdings/Ladbrokes Coral Group
COMP-
MCCAA/4/18
UCPH1
30
NL
Autoriteit Consument & Markt
28.08.2019
Sanoma/Iddink
ACM/19/034816
CCPH2
31
NL
Autoriteit Consument & Markt
10.04.2020
DPG/Sanoma
ACM/19/038207
UCPH1
32
NL
Autoriteit Consument & Markt
20.05.2020
NS Groep/Pon Netherlands
ACM/20/038614
CCPH1
33
PL
Urząd Ochrony Konkurencji i
Konsumentów
22.12.2015
1&1 Internet/Home.pl
DKK-216/2015
UCPH2
34
PT
Autoridade da Concorrência
19.07.2018
Sonae/CTT - Correios de Portugal JV
Ccent. 27/2018
UCPH1
PT
Autoridade da Concorrência
08.11.2018
KKR/Cabolink
Ccent. 41/2018
UCPH1
PT
Autoridade da Concorrência
07.02.2019
Siris/Travelport
Ccent. 1/2019
UCPH1
PT
Autoridade da Concorrência
25.06.2021
Claranet Portugal/Bizdirect
Ccent. 27/2021
UCPH1
PT
Autoridade da Concorrência
24.08.2021
Claranet Portugal/OutScope Solutions
Ccent. 38/2021
UCPH1
PT
Autoridade da Concorrência
25.01.2022
Delivery Hero/Glovo
Ccent. 61/2021
NONAPP
35
RO
România Consiliul Concurenței
24.11.2016
Dante International/PC Garage
84/24.11.2016
CCPH1
36
RO
România Consiliul Concurenței
22.11.2021
Glovoappro/Foodpanda
86/22.11.2021
CCPH1
37
SI
Javna agencija Republike
Slovenije za varstvo konkurence
12.04.2018
Sully System/CENEJE
3061-27/2017-71
CCPH1
38
SI
Javna agencija Republike
Slovenije za varstvo konkurence
25.04.2019
ECE/ELTUS PLUS
3061-41/2018
UCPH1
39
SI
Javna agencija Republike
Slovenije za varstvo konkurence
24.04.2020
Shoppster/IDEO PLUS
3061-9/2020-14
UCPH1
40
SI
Javna agencija Republike
Slovenije za varstvo konkurence
24.01.2022
Allegro.eu/MIMOVRSTE
3061-25/2021-6
UCPH1
47
SE
Stockholms tingsrätt
16.12.2014
Swedbank Franchise/Svensk
Fastighetsförmedling
T 3629-14
PROH
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
114
ID
Country
Decisional body
Date
Case name
Case number
Outcome
48
SE
Konkurrensverket
2016
Blocket/Hemnet
84/2016
WITHDR
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
23.02.2015
esure Group/Gocompare.com
ME/6495-14
UCPH1
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
26.03.2015
Ticketmaster/Seatwave/Timbre
ME/6505-14
UCPH1
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
02.09.2015
Compagnie Financière Richemont/Net-A-
Porter
ME/6538-15
UCPH1
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
11.12.2015
CliniSys Group/Roper Technologies
ME/6564/15
UCPH1
49
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
17.12.2015
Betfair Group/Paddy Power
ME/6572/15
UCPH1
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
30.06.2016
Mapil Bidco/Chain Reaction Cycles/Decade
ME/6569/16
UCPH1
50
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
29.06.2017
ZPG/Websky
ME/6690/17
UCPH1
51
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
08.09.2017
Blackbaud/Giving
ME/6700/17
UCPH1
52
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
16.11.2017
Just Eat/Hungryhouse
ME/6659-16-II
UCPH2
53
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
07.08.2018
Moneysupermarket.com/Decision
Technologies
ME/6749/18
UCPH1
54
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
12.02.2019
eBay/Motors.co.uk
ME/6774/18
UCPH1
55
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
12.06.2019
PayPal Holdings/iZettle
ME/6766/18-II
UCPH2
56
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
22.11.2019
Salesforce/Tableau Software
ME/6841/19
UCPH1
57
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
15.08.2019
Tobii/Smartbox
ME/6780/18-II
PROH
58
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
13.02.2020
Google/Looker
ME/6839/19
UCPH1
59
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
09.04.2020
Sabre/Farlogix
ME/6806/19-II
PROH
60
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
04.08.2020
Amazon/Roofoods
ME/6836/19-II
UCPH2
61
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
02.02.2021
Pug/StubHub
ME/6868/19-II
CCPH2
62
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
16.02.2021
Adevinta/eBay Classifieds Group
ME/6897/20
CCPH1
63
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
29.03.2021
Uber International/GPC Computer Software
ME/6903/20
UCPH1
64
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
28.06.2021
SK hynix/Intel
ME/6913/20
UCPH1
65
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
29.06.2021
Advanced Micro Devices/Xilinx
ME/6915/20
UCPH1
66
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
26.07.2021
Turnitin/Ouriginal Group
ME/6931/21
UCPH1
67
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
27.09.2021
Meta/Kustomer
ME/6920/20
UCPH1
68
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
29.09.2021
Auction Technology Group/Live Auctioneers
ME/6942/21
UCPH1
69
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
06.12.2021
Meta/Giphy
ME/6891/20-II
PROH
UK
Competition & Markets Authority
02.03.2022
Microsoft/Nuance
ME/6940/21
UCPH1
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
115
Annex II: 69 particularly relevant national cases on digital and technology mergers, coded by theories
of harm
Outcome
Horizontal theories of harm
Vertical theories of harm
Unconditional clearance phase 1
HAC
Loss of an actual competitor
VIF
Input foreclosure
Unconditional clearance phase 2
HPC
Loss of a potential competitor
VCF
Customer foreclosure
Conditional clearance phase 1
HCOORD
Coordinated effects
VNONOTHR
Other non-coordinated effects
Conditional clearance phase 2
HOTHR
Other
VCOORD
Coordinated effects
Prohibition
Withdrawal
Conglomerate theories of harm
Remedies
CFOR
Foreclosure through linking sales
STR
Structural remedy
ID
running number of the case
summaries provided in Annex
III
CCOORD
Coordinated effects
BEH
Behavioural remedy (other than
access)
COTHR
Other
ACC
Access remedy
NO
No remedies
PROH
Concentration prohibited
ID
Country
Date
Case name
Case number
Horizontal
Vertical
Conglomerate
Remedy
1
AT
03.12.2019
CTS Eventim/Barracuda
Holding
BWB/Z-4651
NA
VIF; VCF
NA
ACC;
BEH
2
AT
18.06.2021
eBay/Adevinta
BWB/Z-5141, Z-5142,
Z-5420 and Z-5421
HAC
NA
NA
STR
3
AT
07.02.2022
Meta/Giphy
28 Kt 8/21t and 28 Kt
9/21i
HPC; HOTHR
VIF
NA
ACC
4
CZ
16.05.2016
Rockaway
Capital/Heureka
ÚOHS-
S0013/2016/KS-
21123/2016/840/DVá
NA
VNONOTHR
CFOR
BEH
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
116
ID
Country
Date
Case name
Case number
Horizontal
Vertical
Conglomerate
Remedy
5
FR
16.01.2013
Rakuten Europe/Alpha
Direct Services
13-DCC-08
NA
VIF; VCF
NA
NO
6
FR
12.08.2015
Crédit Mutuel Arkéa/
Latour
Capital/BlackFin/
Primonial
15-DCC-105
HAC
NA
CFOR
NO
7
FR
01.02.2018
Axel Springer/Concept
Multimédia
18-DCC-18
HAC;
HCOORD
NA
CFOR
NO
8
FR
23.04.2018
TF1/Aufeminin
18-DCC-63
HOTHR
NA
CFOR
NO
9
DE
20.04.2015
Axel Springer/Immowelt
B6-39/15
HAC;
HCOORD
NA
NA
NO
10
DE
24.07.2015
ProSiebenSat.1/Verivox
B8-76/15
HCOORD
VIF
NA
NO
11
DE
22.10.2015
OCPE II
Master/EliteMedianet
B6-57/15
HAC;
HCOORD;
HOTHR
NA
NA
NO
12
DE
03.01.2017
CTS Eventim/FKP
Scorpio
B6-53/16
HAC
VIF
NA
NO
13
DE
23.11.2017
CTS Eventim/Four
Artists
B6-35/17
HAC
VCF
NA
PROH
14
DE
17.12.2019
PayPal/Honey Science
B6-86/19
NA
VIF; VCF
CFOR
NO
15
DE
11.11.2019
Cisco Systems/Acacia
Communications
B7-205/19
HAC
VIF
NA
NO
16
DE
11.02.2022
Meta/Kustomer
B6-21/22
HAC
NA
COTHR
NO
17
EL
18.04.2022
Delivery Hero/Alfa
Distributions/Inkat/Deli
very.gr/E-table
775/2022
NA
NA
CFOR
BEH
18
HU
20.02.2017
Magyar RTL
Televízió/Central
Digitális Média
VJ/87-198/2016
HOTHR
NA
NA
PROH
19
HU
17.10.2019
eMAG/Extreme Digital
VJ/14/2019
HAC
NA
NA
NO
20
HU
12.12.2019
Netrisk.hu/Biztosítás.hu
VJ/12/2019
HAC
NA
NA
NO
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
117
ID
Country
Date
Case name
Case number
Horizontal
Vertical
Conglomerate
Remedy
21
IE
15.01.2016
Paddy Power/Betfair
M/15/059
HAC
VIF
NA
NO
22
IE
10.03.2016
Ladbrokes/Gala Coral
M/16/007
HAC
VIF
NA
NO
23
IE
18.06.2018
Stars Group/Sky Betting
& Gaming
M/18/038
HAC
VIF; VCF
NA
NO
24
IE
18.09.2018
EQT Fund
Management/SUSE
M/18/066
NA
VIF; VCF
NA
NO
25
IE
11.10.2019
Applied
Materials/Kokusai
Electric Corporation
M/19/027
HAC
NA
NA
NO
26
IE
11.05.2020
Flutter
Entertainment/Stars
Group
M/20/001
HAC
VIF
CFOR
NO
27
IE
15.02.2021
Booster/Liftoff Mobile
M/21/002
HAC
NA
NA
NO
28
IT
04.08.2020
OEP 14
Coöperatief/Techedge
28331
HAC
NA
NA
NO
29
MT
21.03.2018
GVC
Holdings/Ladbrokes
Coral Group
COMP-MCCAA/4/18
HAC
NA
NA
NO
30
NL
28.08.2019
Sanoma/Iddink
ACM/19/034816
NA
VIF; VCF;
VNONOTHR
CFOR
ACC
31
NL
10.04.2020
DPG/Sanoma
ACM/19/038207
HAC
VIF
CFOR
NO
32
NL
20.05.2020
NS Groep/Pon
Netherlands
ACM/20/038614
HAC
VIF; VCF
NA
ACC
33
PL
22.12.2015
1&1 Internet/Home.pl
DKK-216/2015
HAC
NA
NA
NO
34
PT
19.07.2018
Sonae/CTT - Correios
de Portugal JV
Ccent. 27/2018
NA
VIF; VCF
NA
NO
35
RO
24.11.2016
Dante International/PC
Garage
84/24.11.2016
HAC
NA
NA
STR
36
RO
22.11.2021
Glovoappro/Foodpanda
86/22.11.2021
HAC
NA
NA
BEH
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
118
ID
Country
Date
Case name
Case number
Horizontal
Vertical
Conglomerate
Remedy
37
SI
12.04.2018
Sully System/CENEJE
3061-27/2017-71
NA
VIF;
VNONOTHR
NA
BEH
38
SI
25.04.2019
ECE/ELTUS PLUS
3061-41/2018
HAC
NA
NA
NO
39
SI
24.04.2020
Shoppster/IDEO PLUS
3061-9/2020-14
HAC
NA
NA
NO
40
SI
24.01.2022
Allegro.eu/MIMOVRST
E
3061-25/2021-6
HAC
NA
NA
NO
41
ES
20.11.2014
Schibsted/Milanuncios
C/0573/14
HAC
NA
NA
ACC
42
ES
31.03.2016
Just Eat/La Nevera Roja
C/0730/16
HAC
NA
NA
BEH
43
ES
24.11.2016
Daimler/Hailo/MyTaxi/
Negocio Hailo
C/0802/16
HAC
NA
NA
NO
44
ES
10.09.2019
Just Eat Spain/Canary
Delivery Company
C/1046/19
HAC
NA
NA
NO
45
ES
05.12.2019
MIH Food Delivery
Holdings/Just Eat
C/1072/19
HAC
NA
NA
BEH
46
ES
19.10.2021
Turnitin/Ouriginal
Group
C/1220/21
HAC
VIF
NA
NO
47
SE
16.12.2014
Swedbank
Franchise/Svensk
Fastighetsförmedling
T 3629-14
HAC
VIF
NA
PROH
48
SE
2016
Blocket/Hemnet
84/2016
HAC
NA
NA
WITHDR
49
UK
17.12.2015
Betfair Group/Paddy
Power
ME/6572/15
HAC
VIF
NA
NO
50
UK
29.06.2017
ZPG/Websky
ME/6690/17
HAC
VIF
NA
NO
51
UK
08.09.2017
Blackbaud/Giving
ME/6700/17
HAC
NA
CFOR
NO
52
UK
16.11.2017
Just Eat/Hungryhouse
ME/6659-16-II
HAC
NA
NA
NO
53
UK
07.08.2018
Moneysupermarket.com/
Decision Technologies
ME/6749/18
HAC
VIF
NA
NO
54
UK
12.02.2019
eBay/Motors.co.uk
ME/6774/18
HAC
NA
NA
NO
55
UK
12.06.2019
PayPal Holdings/iZettle
ME/6766/18-II
HAC; HPC
NA
NA
NO
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
119
ID
Country
Date
Case name
Case number
Horizontal
Vertical
Conglomerate
Remedy
56
UK
22.11.2019
Salesforce/Tableau
Software
ME/6841/19
HAC
NA
CFOR
NO
57
UK
15.08.2019
Tobii/Smartbox
ME/6780/18-II
HAC
VIF; VCF
NA
PROH
58
UK
13.02.2020
Google/Looker
ME/6839/19
HAC
VIF
NA
NO
59
UK
09.04.2020
Sabre/Farlogix
ME/6806/19-II
HAC
NA
NA
PROH
60
UK
04.08.2020
Amazon/Roofoods
ME/6836/19-II
HPC
NA
CFOR
NO
61
UK
02.02.2021
Pug/StubHub
ME/6868/19-II
HAC
NA
NA
STR
62
UK
16.02.2021
Adevinta/eBay
Classifieds Group
ME/6897/20
HAC; HPC
NA
NA
STR
63
UK
29.03.2021
Uber International/GPC
Computer Software
ME/6903/20
HPC
VIF;
VNONOTHR
NA
NO
64
UK
28.06.2021
SK hynix/Intel
ME/6913/20
HAC
NA
NA
NO
65
UK
29.06.2021
Advanced Micro
Devices/Xilinx
ME/6915/20
NA
NA
CFOR
NO
66
UK
26.07.2021
Turnitin/Ouriginal
Group
ME/6931/21
HAC
NA
NA
NO
67
UK
27.09.2021
Meta/Kustomer
ME/6920/20
HOTHR
VIF; VCF
CFOR
NO
68
UK
29.09.2021
Auction Technology
Group/Live Auctioneers
ME/6942/21
HAC
NA
CFOR
NO
69
UK
06.12.2021
Meta/Giphy
ME/6891/20-II
HPC
VIF
NA
YS
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
120
Annex III: Concise summaries of 69 national cases on digital
and technology mergers
Note: In order to provide some context, the summaries below briefly describe the market
upon which the national competition authority (NCA) relied, even where the NCA did
not provide a final delineation of the relevant market. The names of NCAs are provided
in the original language.
(1) Austria: CTS Eventim/Barracuda Holding (3 December 2019)
NCA: Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde
Case number: BWB/Z-4651
Concentration: CTS Eventim, a German provider of ticketing and live entertainment
with a strong market presence in Austria through oeticket, wanted to acquire 71% of
shares and sole control of Barracuda Holding, an Austrian provider of concerts.
Horizontal theories of harm: NA
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The authority was concerned that, post-merger, the
merged entity could engage in input foreclosure by making it harder for ticketing
providers to access organisers of live events. In addition, the authority was concerned that
the merged entity could engage in customer foreclosure by providing its ticketing services
at above market prices to companies that do not belong to the CTS Eventim group.
Outcome: Conditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: In order to address the competition concerns raised by the authority in relation
to customer foreclosure, CTS Eventim committed that oeticket (i) would provide its
customers that wanted to use its ticketing services with non-discriminatory access to its
full range of services, including advertising contracts, and (ii) would not self-preference
in relation to the content and the way that events are promoted on the ticketing platform
oeticket.com (all for a duration of five years).
In order to address competition concerns related to vertical input foreclosure, oeticket
would (i) not require exclusivity from brick-and-mortar resellers, (ii) not require
exclusivity from customers of its JetTicket brand, and (iii) not impose exclusivity beyond
two years with white label ticketing platforms in Austria (all for a duration of five years).
Further commitments related to promoting local and national artists for a duration of five
years, and to ensuring there were festival passes for youth (up to 16 years) for festivals in
Austria.
Noteworthy: Acquisitions by CTS Eventim were also cleared by the German authority,
once subject to conditions.
(2) Austria: eBay/Adevinta (18 June 2021)
NCA: Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde
Case numbers: BWB/Z-5141, Z-5142, Z-5420 and Z-5421
Concentration: Adevinta wanted to acquire the eBay Classifieds Group (eCG) from
eBay, while eBay would acquire 33% of voting rights and 44% of the financial shares in
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
121
Adevinta. Adevinta holds a 50% interest and exercises joint control over the leading
Austrian online classifieds portal willhaben.at. Until 6 February 2021, Adevinta was also
present in Austria through its online classifieds portal shpock.at.
Horizontal theories of harm: eBay’s online marketplace and willhaben.at were close
competitors on the Austrian market, particularly as regards online sales among consumers
(C2C transactions). This became apparent through market surveys and was also
confirmed by internal documents of the parties. The market was already concentrated,
and in the eyes of the authority the risk of non-coordinated effects was considerable.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Conditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: To address the authority’s competition concerns, the parties proposed the
following commitments: (i) in order to eliminate incentives for anti-competitive
behaviour, eBay reduces its economic stake in Adevinta to 33% or less within 18 months;
(ii) in order to prevent eBay’s ability to engage in anti-competitive behaviour, both parties
take measures to prevent the exchange of information and to reduce the economic
influence of eBay on willhaben.at. In particular, eBay commits to restrict the voting rights
of eBay-appointed board members on issues related to willhaben.at and Adevinta
commits not to exercise its right to appoint a managing director as well as several board
members at willhaben.at. The commitments are binding as long as eBay appoints a
director to Adevinta’s board and eBay’s financial or voting interest in Adevinta is 25%
or higher; but for a maximum of ten years.
Noteworthy: The merger was originally notified in Austria in December 2020, but
subsequently withdrawn; at that time, shpock was still controlled by Adevinta. The
merger was cleared subject to conditions in the UK (see below).
1
In Germany, it was
unconditionally cleared.
2
The Austrian authority drew attention to its close cooperation
with the German and UK authorities.
(3) Austria: Meta/Giphy (22 July 2021),
3
(7 February 2022),
4
(23 June 2022)
5
NCA: Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde; Kartellgericht; Kartellobergericht
Case numbers: BWB/Z-5549 (Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde); 28 Kt 6/21y
(Kartellgericht, 22 July 2021 gun jumping); 28 Kt 8/21t and 28 Kt 9/21i (Kartellgericht,
7 February 2022); 16 Ok 3/22k and 16 Ok 4/22g (Kartellobergericht, 23 June 2022)
Concentration: Global technology company Meta (formerly Facebook) acquired the GIF
library Giphy. After Meta received a €9.6million fine for not notifying this acquisition to
1
Competition & Markets Authority, Adevinta/eBay Classifieds Group (ME/6897/20, 16 February 2021).
2
Bundeskartellamt, Adevinta/eBay Classifieds Group (B6-41/20, 23 November 2020); Bundeskartellamt,
‘Bundeskartellamt clears merger between eBay Classifieds Group and Adevinta’ (24 November 2020)
<https://www.bundeskartellamt.de/SharedDocs/Publikation/EN/Pressemitteilungen/2020/24_11_2020_eb
ay_Adevinta.pdf?__blob=publicationFile&v=5>.
3
Kartellgericht, 22 July 2021, 28 Kt 6/21y Facebook/Giphy (fine for gun-jumping and non-notification).
4
Kartellgericht, 7 February 2022, 28 Kt 8/21t and 28 Kt 9/21i Meta/Giphy (conditional clearance).
5
Kartellobergericht, 23 June 2022, 16 Ok 3/22k and 16 Ok 4/22g Meta/Giphy. On this case, see also
Oberster Gerichtshof, ‘Bestätigung der kartellrechtlichen Nicht-Untersagung eines Zusammenschlusses
unter Auflagen’ (24 June 2022) <https://www.ogh.gv.at/entscheidungen/entscheidungen-ogh/bestaetigung-
der-kartellrechtlichen-nicht-untersagung-eines-zusammenschlusses-von-m-und-g-unter-auflagenv/>.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
122
the Austrian NCA,
6
the authority carried out an in-depth investigation and referred the
acquisition to the Cartel Court (phase 2). The Cartel Court cleared the acquisition subject
to conditions, a decision which was confirmed by the Supreme Cartel Court.
Horizontal theories of harm: In terms of horizontal unilateral effects, the authority
pointed out that the acquisition might stifle potential competition between Meta and
Giphy for advertising clients.
The authority was also concerned that the acquisition could lead to other horizontal
unilateral effects by granting Meta access to sensitive commercial information about
competing online services based on other apps’ integrated interface with the Giphy
library.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: In terms of vertical input foreclosure, the authority
noted that the acquisition may restrict non-discriminatory access to Giphy for other online
services.
Outcome: Conditionally cleared in phase 2.
Remedies: To address the competition concerns raised by the acquisition, the Cartel
Court imposed the following conditions for clearance of the merger: Meta has to (i)
provide non-discriminatory access to Giphy’s GIF library for competing social media
providers (for a duration of five years) and (ii) grant alternative GIF libraries, under
certain conditions, access to Giphy’s GIF library via programming interfaces (APIs) to
allow the establishment of an additional GIF provider other than Giphy (Meta) and Tenor
(Google) (for a duration of seven years).
Noteworthy: This merger had to be notified based on the transaction value threshold that
Austria introduced in 2017. Based upon an application by the authority, the Cartel Court
conditionally cleared the concentration in February 2022.
7
The conditional clearance was
confirmed by the Supreme Cartel Court in June 2022.
8
(4) Czechia: Rockaway Capital/Heureka (16 May 2016)
9
NCA: Úřad pro ochranu hospodářské soutěže
Case number: ÚOHS-S0013/2016/KS-21123/2016/840/DVá
Concentration: Private equity company Rockaway Capital intended to acquire control
of Heureka.cz, a Czech comparison shopping website.
10
Rockaway Capital also
controlled CZC.cz, an online electronics retailer, and other online businesses.
Horizontal theories of harm: NA
Non-horizontal theories of harm: Comparison shopping site Heureka.cz had a market
share between 45-55%. The authority was concerned that, post-merger, Heureka.cz would
6
Kartellgericht, 22 July 2021, 28 Kt 6/21y Facebook/Giphy.
7
Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde, ‘Meta (Facebook)/Giphy merger: AFCA appealing against conditional
clearance’ (4 March 2022) <https://www.bwb.gv.at/en/news/news-2022/detail/meta-facebook-giphy-
merger-afca-appealing-against-conditional-clearance>.
8
Kartellobergericht, 23 June 2022, 16 Ok 3/22k and 16 Ok 4/22g Meta/Giphy.
9
This summary is based on Jiří Kindl and Michal Petr, ‘Czech Republic’ in Daniel Mândrescu (ed), EU
Competition Law and the Digital Economy: Protecting Free and Fair Competition in an Age of
Technological (R)Evolution (XXIX FIDE Congress 2020) 165, 176.
10
Rockaway Capital also intended to acquire mall.cz, a major Czech online shopping mall. This acquisition
was unconditionally cleared; see Úřad pro ochranu hospodářské soutěže, Rockaway Capital/Sully
System/Netretail (ÚOHS-S0223/2016/KS-26867/2016/840/DVá, 27 June 2016).
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
123
give preferential treatment to online businesses already controlled by Rockaway Capital.
A further concern related to the possibility that Heureka.cz could ask online shops to
collect excessive amounts of data about their users, data that could then be used in the
interest of Rockaway Capital’s businesses.
Outcome: Conditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: In order to address the concerns voiced by the authority, Rockaway proposed
the following commitments: (i) a clear link between Heureka.cz and other Rockaway
Capital activities would be published on the website, ensuring transparency, (ii) it would
not discriminate against independent sellers (especially as regards the prescribed number
of positions of recommended shops that should have been increased in order to avoid a
decrease in the number of positions available to independent shops as compared with pre-
merger situation and the minimum number of search results of goods compared solely by
price), and (iii) it would limit the possibility to gather excessive data related to a specific,
score-based service that shows reliability of the online store from the customers
perspective. In particular, Heureka.cz would not oblige sellers to provide other data than
the users’ email addresses, and it was not allowed to favour sellers that provided more
data or disadvantage those who did not.
(5) France: Rakuten/Alpha Direct Services (16 January 2013)
NCA: Autorité de la concurrence
Case number: 13-DCC-08
Concentration: Rakuten, which is active in e-commerce through its electronic
marketplace PriceMinister and several price comparison websites, wanted to acquire
exclusive control over Alpha Direct Services, a company specialising in inbound logistics
services for e-commerce and catalogue-based distance selling.
Horizontal theories of harm: NA
Non-horizontal theories of harm: As logistics costs are an important part of the cost
structure in e-commerce, the authority considered that this transaction would allow
PriceMinister to internalise some of these costs. This could lead to an anti-competitive
outcome if the transaction foreclosed the access of competing marketplaces to such
services (input foreclosure), or foreclosed the access of inbound logistics services to
distance sellers (customer foreclosure). Below a market share of 30%, competition
authorities generally rule out these types of effects. Alpha Direct Services had market
shares on the national market for upstream logistics services between 0 and 5%, while a
great number of bigger competitors existed on the market. On a possible national market
for inbound logistics services for e-commerce, its market shares were estimated at 10 to
20%, again with a number of competitors on the market. Therefore, no input foreclosure
was expected to arise.
Concerning a possible customer foreclosure, the authority noted that the target and its
competitors offered their services to many different distance sellers. While PriceMinister
was one of the most visited marketplaces, a number of important competitors (including
Amazon, eBay, CDiscount and Fnac) operated on the market and PriceMinister’s vendors
did not have exclusivity contracts. Also, PriceMinister remained a relatively small e-
commerce actor. Therefore, the authority expected no vertical restraints to arise.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
124
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: The authority assessed possible vertical theories of harm in-depth, but
concluded that such effects were unlikely to arise.
(6) France: Crédit Mutuel Arkéa, Primonial Management, Blackfin, Latour
Capital/Primonial Holding (12 August 2015)
NCA: Autorité de la concurrence
Case number: 15-DCC-105
Concentration: Crédit Mutuel Arkéa, Primonial Management, Blackfin and Latour
Capital wanted to acquire joint control of Primonial Holding. Amongst many others, this
transaction concerned the market for price comparison websites regarding insurance and
loans in which the Blackfin fund is involved, and the authority analysed possible
conglomerate effects relating to this market.
Horizontal theories of harm: Assessed by the authority, but not relevant in the present
context.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: As the parties involved were active on several
connected markets, the authority considered possible conglomerate effects. Only the
analysis regarding conglomerate effects relating to price comparison websites is
discussed here. The authority noted that Comparadise, owned by Blackfin, operated a
comparison website for loans and insurance on markets where Crédit Mutuel Arkéa and
Blackfin were present. The authority observed that Comparadise had low market shares
on the market for comparison websites in general as well as on possible markets for
comparing insurance (10-20%) or for comparing loans (0-5%). In addition, the website
faced competition from a number of specialised comparison websites, both in insurance
and in loans. In both banking and insurance, the market shares of the parties involved
were between 0-5%. Based on its view that foreclosure effects usually do not arise where
market shares are below 30%, the authority did not consider that the merger gave rise to
a potential risk.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
(7) France: Axel Springer/Concept Multimédia (1 February 2018)
NCA: Autorité de la concurrence
Case number: 18-DCC-18
Concentration: The Axel Springer group, which acquired the real estate web portal
SeLoger in 2010 (case 10-DCC-152), wanted to acquire Concept Multimédia, which
through Logic-Immo runs a web portal as well as print magazines on real estate. The
transaction concerned the market for online real estate classified ads, the market for
classified ads in print media and the national market for online advertising markets.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority’s main competition concern was related to
possible horizontal effects on the market for online real estate classified ads for
professionals due to the creation of a new entity with a market share exceeding 50% in
value. The authority particularly investigated a possible rise of prices, a risk of competitor
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
125
foreclosure due to bundling or related to the acquisition of data, and coordinated effects.
First, the risk of price increases resulting from the transaction were ruled out since, prior
to the transaction, the parties did not exert any significant competitive pressure on each
other. Second, the bundled offer likely to be implemented by the new entity on the market
for online real estate classifieds would not lead to a significant elimination of competition.
Third, the risks of coordinated effects between the new entity and the Le Bon Coin group
could be ruled out insofar as the detection condition, one of the three criteria necessary to
identify such an effect, was not met. The authority noted that these two players, which
have significant differences in their positioning and business models, operated in a market
with limited price transparency.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed whether there was a risk of
conglomerate effects due to the target’s presence on the market for real estate classified
ads in print media as well as online. The authority considered that while Logic-Immo had
an important share of the market for real estate classified ads in print media, that market
was in decline. Therefore, the market power of Logic Immo on the market for real estate
classified ads in print media would not be sufficient to create a leverage effect on a
connected market. There was thus no risk of foreclosure on the market for online real
estate classified ads. The authority also assessed whether foreclosure was likely on the
market for real estate classified ads in print media, as Logic-Immo already offered an
online/offline bundle and SeLoger’s internal documents showed that such an offer was
also considered by it. The authority concluded that the merged entity would have the
ability to propose such bundles or bundled rebates. Based on three different scenarios (a
discount on print ads; a discount on online ads; tying or a price increase), the authority
concluded that the incentive to implement such discounts for bundles or to enforce ties
would be limited. It also concluded that, in any case, the effect of such a bundle would
only lead to a marginal reduction of competition in the market for property advertisements
in the print media.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 2.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: Conglomerate effects were not considered an issue because of the decline
of an offline market. Also note the German decision (case B6-39/15) on Axel Springer’s
purchase of Immowelt AG, another online portal for online real estate classified ads. On
the market for online advertising, the authority considered that the strong presence of
Google and Facebook with a combined market share exceeding 65% meant that no
anti-competitive effects should be expected on that relevant market.
(8) France: TF1/Aufeminin (23 April 2018)
NCA: Autorité de la concurrence
Case number: 18-DCC-63
Concentration: TF1, a group active in free and pay-TV, wanted to acquire sole control
of Aufeminin, a digital company involved mainly in publishing websites, selling online
advertising space and online retailing. TF1 also operated websites. Aufeminin was
previously controlled by the Axel Springer group. Markets concerned included the sale
of television advertising space, the sale of advertising space in the printed press, the sale
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
126
of online advertising space, the operation of websites and marketing and commercial
communication services.
Horizontal theories of harm: No horizontal effects were expected due to the low market
shares of the merging parties on those markets where there was a horizontal overlap (i.e.,
especially printed press, marketing services and various retailing activities). Only the
overlap on the markets for the sale of online advertising space and the operation of
websites led to closer scrutiny. Regarding the market for the sale of online advertising,
the authority emphasised that post-merger TF1 could use the data obtained through
Aufeminin to improve its monetisation of online advertising spaces. However, the merged
entity would only cover, on a daily basis, between 5 and 7% of the female population it
aims at, compared to coverage rates of 79% for Google and 68% for Facebook. Therefore,
the authority did not expect horizontal effects to arise in this respect. Concerning the
operation of websites dedicated to female topics, the merged entity would have a low
market share below 15% and would continue to be subject to strong competition.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: Based on TF1’s low market shares as an online
advertising agency on the online advertising sales and intermediation markets, the
authority did not expect any vertical effects to arise.
The authority more closely assessed possible conglomerate effects between TF1’s market
presence in selling television advertising space and markets on which the target was
present, notably the sale of online advertising space and marketing and commercial
communication services. When assessing a possible bundling strategy in the sale of online
and television advertising space, the authority found that TF1 certainly had the ability to
engage in such a strategy. It also highlighted, however, that bundling TV advertising with
online or radio advertising was a common strategy in this sector that TF1’s competitors
also engaged in. TF1’s incentive to carry out this strategy was assessed through several
factors. The authority particularly emphasised that TF1 could benefit from the
complementarity of its bundle, the merging of data sets, and cost synergies, and concluded
that the implementation of such bundles appeared to be one of the objectives of the
acquisition. The authority considered that TF1 would use its position on the market for
television advertising space as leverage to strengthen its position on the market for online
advertising space. On the latter market, however, the new entity would have a market
share below 10%. Based on the strong position of TF1’s competitors and low barriers to
entry, and especially considering the competitive pressure emanating from GAFAM (with
Google’s market share in online advertising at 50-60%, Facebook at 10-20% and the new
entity at only 0-5%), the authority concluded that conglomerate effects could be
discarded.
Further conglomerate effects the authority briefly assessed (but dismissed) related to the
sale of advertising space on television and in the printed press, and to the sale of television
advertising space on television and marketing and commercial communication services.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: On the market for online advertising, the authority considered that the
strong presence of Google and Facebook meant that no conglomerate effects would arise
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
127
even if the merged entity were to engage in bundling of online and television advertising
space as was to be expected.
(9) Germany: Axel Springer/Immowelt (20 April 2015)
NCA: Bundeskartellamt
Case number: B6-39/15
Concentration: Axel Springer planned to acquire Immowelt on the market for online real
estate platforms, and its daughter company Immonet should enter into a joint venture with
the target.
Horizontal theories of harm: The acquisition would lead to the merging of the second-
biggest and the third-biggest online real estate platforms in Germany, meaning that this
narrow market would be further concentrated. However, Immoscout would undoubtedly
remain the market leader, with only a few smaller, sometimes specialized further
competitors and meta search engines present on the market. Despite this concentrated
market, the Bundeskartellamt found that the merger would indeed be pro-competitive as
it would help ensure that the market would not tip. It also noted that users in this market
tended to multi-home, further safeguarding against market tipping.
The authority also considered whether coordinated effects would arise, but concluded that
the risk of collusion in such a two-sided market was lower than in traditional markets,
especially as the two remaining players had considerable structural differences.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: Not only did the German Bundeskartellamt not regard this horizontal
merger as harmful for competition on the narrow market of online real estate platforms,
it also found that the merger was indeed pro-competitive as it would help to ensure that
the market would not tip.
(10) Germany: ProSiebenSat.1/Verivox (24 July 2015)
NCA: Bundeskartellamt
Case number: B8-76/15
Concentration: The media company ProSiebenSat.1 proposed to acquire the comparison
platform Verivox on the market for the operation of online platforms for final consumer
contracts, including electricity and gas contracts, insurance, banking, mobile telephony,
etc.
Horizontal theories of harm: No noteworthy horizontal overlaps.
Concerning coordinated effects, the authority assessed whether the merger could increase
the likelihood of collusion between Verivox and Check24, its main competitor. It found
that by leading to further asymmetries among these competitors, the opposite was the
case.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The Bundeskartellamt assessed whether, post-merger,
ProSiebenSat.1 might have the ability and the incentive to grant Verivox better
advertising space at more favourable conditions than it does to Verivox’s competitors,
and whether this could restrict effective competition. Verivox was the market leader,
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
128
Check24 its main competitor (both together held 95% of the market). ProSiebenSat.1’s
ability and incentive to engage in such input foreclosure would be restricted as it would
miss out on advertising revenue from Verivox’s competitors. Also, TV commercials at
ProSiebenSat.1 were not the only advertising channels available to Verivox’s
competitors. In addition, sellers usually used several price comparison platforms in
parallel (multi-homing). The Bundeskartellamt therefore concluded that this would not
result in an appreciable restriction, also not through market tipping.
Remedies: NA
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Noteworthy: This conglomerate merger was unconditionally cleared after a careful
analysis of the various effects that arise in digital multi-sided markets.
(11) Germany: OCPE II Master (Parship)/EliteMedianet (22 October 2015)
NCA: Bundeskartellamt
Case number: B6-57/15
Concentration: The fund OCPE II Master is, amongst others, the owner of the online
dating portal Parship.de, which it acquired in 2015 (cleared by the Bundeskartellamt on
24 March 2015). It proposed to acquire EliteMedianet, which runs two popular online
dating portals (ElitePartner.de and AcademicPartner.de), on the national market for
online dating platforms.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority analysed whether this horizontal acquisition
by one online dating platform of another could lead to competitive harm. Despite the high
combined turnover-based market shares of the merging parties, the authority concluded
that the case raised no competition concerns. Concerning non-coordinated effects due to
obtaining a dominant position, the authority concluded that the market environment was
such that the merging parties would not obtain a single dominant position post-merger,
and in particular there was no danger of tipping. Contrary to other digital markets,
network effects on this market are limited because users (singles) tend to multi-home,
there is a large degree of platform differentiation, and online dating platforms constantly
need to acquire new users due to users (singles) leaving the market as customers when
they find a match or because they are dissatisfied when they do not find a match (no lock-
in). Users also have a sufficient number of alternatives available to them, and market
entry barriers are rather low.
Concerning non-coordinated effects other than obtaining a dominant position, the
authority concluded that the merging parties were not close enough in competition to lead
to any such effects. Due to the presence of a varied field of competitors, the authority also
did not expect any coordinated effects to arise.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 2.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: This case showed what type of digital market environment would not
warrant intervention; the specific characteristics of online dating platforms led to the
unconditional clearance of this merger. In 2020, similar considerations led to the
unconditional clearance of the acquisition of The Meet Group (which operates the Lovoo
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
129
online dating platform) by Parship and ElitePartner, which were by then owned by media
group ProSiebenSat.1.
11
(12) Germany: CTS Eventim/FKP Scorpio (3 January 2017)
NCA: Bundeskartellamt
Case number: B6-53/16
Concentration: CTS Eventim, a company active in live entertainment, event venues and
ticketing, wanted to increase its stake in FKP Scorpio, an organiser of rock/pop festivals
and tours.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed whether the increase in CTS
Eventim’s stake in FKP Scorpio could lead to horizontal unilateral effects in a range of
markets. Concerning rock/pop tour concerts, the authority considered that CTS Eventim’s
importance on that market had taken a dive since 2016, while FKP Scorpio did not have
an important position on that market. Therefore, no competition concerns would arise.
On regional markets for music festivals, the authority concluded that there was no
considerable overlap in the geographic market between the parties’ activities, other music
events could be a constraining factor, and there were low barriers to entry; no competition
concerns would arise.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed whether vertical foreclosure
effects could arise because events organised by FKP Scorpio were also sold via CTS
Eventim’s ticketing system. It assessed this two-sided market in some depth, and
concluded that FKP Scorpio’s events were already available via CTS Eventim’s ticketing
system, which was probably dominant (both vis-à-vis event organisers and vis-à-vis
points of sale). The increase in CTS Eventim’s stake would, however, not further
strengthen that market position and would therefore not lead to input foreclosure.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 2.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: While the authority did not consider that this acquisition would strengthen
the market leader’s dominant position, this was seen differently in CTS Eventim/Four
Artists, decided in the same year.
(13) Germany: CTS Eventim/Four Artists (23 November 2017)
NCA: Bundeskartellamt
Case number: B6-35/17
Concentration: CTS Eventim, a company active in live entertainment, event venues and
ticketing, wanted to acquire a majority stake in Four Artists, a company active in
organising live events and as a booking agent for a range of famous German artists.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority considered that the acquisition would further
strengthen CTS Eventim’s already dominant position on the market for ticket system
services for event organisers and booking offices. The authority underlined how the (then)
new German provision of § 18 para 3a ARC
12
on assessing market dominance in multi-
11
Bundeskartellamt, Parship and ElitePartner/Lovoo (B6-29/20, 6 July 2020).
12
Act against Restraints of Competition, German Federal Law Gazette I 2013/1750 as amended.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
130
sided markets allowed the conclusion that CTS Eventim was indeed dominant on these
markets, and how indirect network effects worked to the incumbent’s advantage. It found
that high barriers to entry, considerable lock-in effects and limited multi-homing by the
other market side led to a strong market position, while no innovation-driven competition
was discernible. The acquisition would lead to a strengthening of CTS Eventim’s market
position on the market for ticket system services, thereby significantly impeding effective
competition.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: CTS Eventim’s competitors already had restricted
access to customers, both because of CTS Eventim’s vertical integration and because of
CTS Eventim’s exclusivity clauses with event organisers. Through recent transactions,
CTS Eventim had further strengthened its dominant position.
13
This further acquisition
would contribute to CTS Eventim’s strategy of customer foreclosure.
Outcome: Prohibited.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: The parties appealed the prohibition before the Higher Regional Court
Dsseldorf, which confirmed the Bundeskartellamt’s prohibition decision.
14
Upon further
appeal, this was also confirmed by the German Federal Court.
15
The authority underlined that it regarded CTS Eventim’s exclusivity contracts with event
organisers as contributing to an abusive customer foreclosure vis-à-vis competing
ticketing platforms; the same analysis had to apply when assessing this concentration.
(14) Germany: PayPal/Honey Science (17 December 2019)
NCA: Bundeskartellamt
Case number: B6-86/19
Concentration: PayPal, a provider of payment services including a popular ‘digital
wallet’, wanted to acquire Honey Science, a developer of browser extensions that
automatically apply coupon and discount codes during virtual check-out.
Horizontal theories of harm: NA
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The authority took into consideration that PayPal has
quite a strong market position on the market for payment systems, and assessed possible
vertical and conglomerate effects. On the market for online payment systems, it did not
expect an appreciable restriction of competition because a number of strong payment
service providers had emerged in recent years (including Klarna, WireCard, Adyen). It
also mentioned Apple Pay and Google Pay as possible competitive constraints, as these
have significant resources and a large user base. These can therefore be expected to make
use of network effects. This competition would act as a competitive constraint
13
See Bundeskartellamt, CTS Eventim/FKP Scorpio (B6-53/16, 3 January 2017).
14
Oberlandesgericht Düsseldorf, 5 December 2018, Kart 3/18 (V) CTS Eventim/Four Artists.
15
Although the Higher Regional Court had not allowed a further appeal on legal grounds, the Federal Court
decided to accept such an appeal (even after the parties had abandoned the merger); Bundesgerichtshof, 24
March 2020, KVZ 3/19 CTS Eventim/Four Artists. Subsequently, the Federal Court confirmed the
Bundeskartellamt’s decision that the strengthening of a dominant position can be a valid reason for
prohibiting a merger where competition would be further limited by a concentration; Bundesgerichtshof,
12 January 2021, KVR 34/20 CTS Eventim/Four Artists.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
131
countervailing vertical or conglomerate effects, eg in the shape of foreclosure practices
or tying and the leveraging of market power to third markets.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: This merger had to be notified based on the transaction value threshold that
Germany introduced in 2017. In the assessment of whether Honey’s activity on the
German market was substantial, the authority emphasised that many online businesses
are easily scalable with minimal effort. It also underlined the fact that many online
businesses can only be monetised a significant period of time after their market entry,
meaning that current sales figures do not reflect their competitive potential.
(15) Germany: Cisco Systems/Acacia Communications (6 February 2020)
NCA: Bundeskartellamt
Case number: B7-205/19
Concentration: Cisco Systems, a worldwide developer and producer of network devices,
proposed to acquire Acacia Communications, which produces semiconductors for
specific applications.
Horizontal theories of harm: Based on the relevant markets at issue, the authority found
that Acacia’s and Cisco’s respective market positions would not be strengthened.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: To assess possible vertical concerns related to input
foreclosure, the authority analysed the downstream markets for optical networks,
switches and routers. While Acacia was not active on those markets, Cisco had high
market shares on them. The authority expected no appreciable restrictions of competition
to arise, however, as there were a great number of competitors active on the various
market levels. Customers usually buy individual network components and employ a (at
least) dual vendor strategy. In terms of a possible foreclosure of competitors in relation
to digital signal processors, the authority concluded that while the merged entity would
have the ability for this type of conduct, it would have no incentive to do so and there
would also be no effects on the market following such behaviour. Reasons for this
conclusion included high profit margins for digital signal processors, the high number of
competitors and vertically integrated companies. Similarly, for optical networks the
authority found that while the merged entity might have the ability to foreclose
competitors as regards optical transceiver modules, it would have no incentive to do so
based on a sufficient number of credible competitors remaining on the market.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: In China, the merger was only cleared subject to conditions.
16
In Austria,
the merger was unconditionally cleared,
17
while in the US the Hart-Scott-Rodino waiting
period expired.
18
16
State Administration for Market Regulation, Cisco Systems/Acacia Communications (14 January 2021).
17
Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde, Cisco Systems/Acacia Communications (BWB/Z-4545, 3 September 2019).
18
Cisco-Acacia merger receives antitrust approval in US, still needs OK in Germany and China’ MLex (27
September 2019) <https://content.mlex.com/#/content/1131563?referrer=portfolio_openrelatedcontent>.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
132
(16) Germany: Meta/Kustomer (11 February 2022)
NCA: Bundeskartellamt
Case number: B6-21/22
Concentration: The digital platform Facebook (now Meta) intended to acquire
Kustomer, the provider of a cloud-based customer relationship management (CRM)
platform to business users.
Horizontal theories of harm: There is a small horizontal overlap between Meta’s
Unified Inbox service, which only encompasses communication channels offered by
Meta, and Kustomer’s CRM service. Based on the commitments Meta made vis-à-vis the
European Commission,
19
the German authority considered that the concentration would
only have negligible effects on that market.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The German authority emphasised that the
concentration also needed to be assessed against the background of Meta’s social media
ecosystem. In particular, it investigated whether the acquisition could enable Meta to
safeguard, further develop or strengthen its own digital ecosystem. This could then
manifest itself on particular relevant markets, such as in social media advertising. In this
respect, the authority particularly considered the data advantage that the acquisition of
Kustomer would provide Meta with. It also analysed to what extent the acquisition could
help Meta to further develop its offerings. The authority concluded that, overall, anti-
competitive effects on markets in which Meta already has significant market power were
entirely possible. However, the authority refrained from opening phase 2 proceedings as
it was not possible to establish, to the required standard of probability, that the services
and capabilities associated with Kustomer were of sufficient importance to lead to a
strengthening of Meta’s ecosystem as sketched by the authority.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: This case had to be notified in Austria and Germany due to the transaction
value threshold that both countries adopted in 2017. This was not a case of the one-stop-
shop rule, as Austria had referred the case to the Commission while Germany had not. At
the time of the Austrian referral, the German authority had not yet concluded whether the
transaction did, in fact, have to be notified to it.
20
The president of the Bundeskartellamt
stated that ‘it is with unease that we ultimately had to acknowledge that the effects of the
acquisition would not have warranted a prohibition under existing competition law’.
21
The European Commission had conditionally cleared this merger.
22
Australia and the UK
19
European Commission Decision of 27 January 2022, M.10262 Meta/Kustomer.
20
This was then established in a separate decision, which at the time of writing is on appeal before the
Oberlandesgericht Düsseldorf. See Bundeskartellamt, Meta/Kustomer (B6-37/21, 9 December 2021).
21
Andreas Mundt in Bundeskartellamt, ‘Bundeskartellamt clears acquisition of Kustomer by Meta
(formerly Facebook)’ Press Release (11 February 2022)
<https://www.bundeskartellamt.de/SharedDocs/Meldung/EN/Pressemitteilungen/2022/11_02_2022_Meta
_Kustomer.html>.
22
European Commission Decision of 27 January 2022, M.10262 Meta/Kustomer.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
133
had also cleared this merger.
23
In its press release, the Bundeskartellamt emphasised that
the European Commission had cleared this transaction on 27 January 2022.
24
(17) Greece: Delivery Hero/Alfa Distributions/Inkat/Delivery.gr/E-table (18 April
2022)
25
NCA: Επιτροπή Ανταγωνισμού (Hellenic Competition Commission)
Case number: 775/2022
Concentration: Delivery Hero operated e-food, the leading online food delivery platform
in Greece, which is also active, inter alia, in the market for online intermediation for the
sale of groceries. It wanted to acquire the following companies: Alfa Distributions, which
is active in the wholesale supply of consumer goods to supermarkets; Inkat, which is
active in the wholesale supply of groceries and operates a retail grocery store chain;
Delivery.gr, which provides online delivery intermediation services for restaurants,
supermarkets, convenience stores and other local stores; and E-table, which provides
online intermediation services for reservations in restaurants.
Horizontal theories of harm: NA
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The authority’s investigation found that by combining
the acquirer’s online food ordering platform with the targets’ online intermediation
services for reservations in restaurants, conglomerate effects would arise. Both E-table
and Delivery Hero had significant market power in their respective Greek markets. Post-
merger, conglomerate foreclosure effects through bundling were likely to arise, as the
merged entity would have the ability and incentive to bundle their services for business
users. A further concern voiced by the authority related to the combination of data sets
from both services that would allow for targeted advertisements with which no
competitors could effectively compete.
Outcome: Conditionally cleared in phase 2.
Remedies: Delivery Hero committed (i) not to tie online intermediation services for food
ordering (e-food) with online reservation services in restaurants (e-table) when offered to
business users (ie, restaurants). This also extends to special discounts and reduced fees
that would have the same effect. Furthermore, Delivery Hero would (ii) not use end user
data collected from one platform to run targeted advertisements on the other, unless end
users have previously provided consent to this, in accordance with existing data protection
rules. A monitoring trustee will ensure the implementation of these commitments over
the course of two years, which is the time during which they apply. The authority may,
however, decide to extend this duration by one year depending on how the market
evolves.
23
Competition & Markets Authority, Meta/Kustomer (ME/6920/20, 27 September 2021); Australian
Competition & Consumer Commission, Meta/Kustomer (18 November 2021).
24
European Commission Decision of 27 January 2022, M.10262 Meta/Kustomer.
25
This summary is based on the press release published by the Hellenic Competition Commission,
‘Decision No. 775/2022 approval of Delivery Hero’s acquisition of companies Alpha Distributions SA,
Inkat SA, Delivery.gr Single Member P.C. and E-Table Single Member P.C., subject to commitments’
<https://www.epant.gr/en/enimerosi/press-releases/item/2189-press-release-the-hellenic-competition-
commission-approves-delivery-hero-s-acquisition-of-four-companies-subject-to-commitments.html>
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
134
Noteworthy: The authority noted that, post-merger, the merged entity’s e-food and
delivery.gr platforms will together have a high combined market share on the market for
online intermediation for the sale of groceries. Due to other supermarkets’ bargaining
power, however, it did not consider that the merged entity would be able to restrict
competition in this respect. The authority imposed a data separation remedy to Delivery
Hero’s ecosystem with the intention of limiting the likelihood of a data leveraging
strategy from online delivery to online intermediation markets and vice versa.
(18) Hungary: Magyar RTL Televízió/Central Digitális Média (24 January 2017)
26
NCA: Gazdasági Versenyhivatal
Case number: VJ/87/2016
Concentration: Magyar RTL Televízió (RTL) intended to acquire 30% of the shares of
Central Digitális Média (CDM), providing RTL the right of control over CDM by holding
more than 50% of the voting rights in CDM and having the power to designate, appoint
or dismiss the majority of CDM’s executive officers. RTL was a member of the
Bertelsmann group, which operates a number of TV channels, provides broadcasting
services and advertising time, and operates the websites www.rtl.hu/rtlklub and
www.rtl.hu/most. CDM published online press products and advertising space therein.
The main portals operated by CDM were startlap.hu (portal), 24.hu (news site), NLCafé
(content for women), HaziPatika.com (health site), Vezess.hu (content on cars),
Hírstart.hu (news aggregator), Citromail.hu (email client/service) and SegementAd
(email database).
Horizontal theories of harm: No assessment was carried out by the competition
authority, see below.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: No assessment was carried out by the competition
authority, see below.
Outcome: Prohibited.
Conditions: NA
Noteworthy: The Media Council of the National Media and Infocommunications
Authority (NMIA), based on the Hungarian Media Services Act, refused to approve the
concentration based on concerns related to media pluralism. However, the Media Council
of the NMIA also established its lack of jurisdiction in terms of the email client
citromail.hu and email database SegmentAd. As regards the relevant market, the NMIA
established that it was the combination of media content for information and orientation
that appeared on the Hungarian television and digital platforms. The Hungarian authority
is bound by the resolution of the Media Council of the NMIA and, due to the latter’s
refusal, it prohibited the concentration without investigating the competitive effects of the
merger neither in case of citromail.hu, nor SegmentAd as the transaction would have
only been implemented in whole by the parties.
26
Thank you to Dániel Élő for providing a summary of this case, which was subsequently shortened by the
author of this Report.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
135
While the Metropolitan Court of Budapest as the first instance court upheld the authority’s
decision,
27
the Hungarian Supreme Court annulled it and ordered the authority to conduct
a new competition proceeding.
28
Although the authority initiated competition proceedings
in March 2020, the transaction was abandoned by the vendor, thus leading to a
termination of these proceedings. RTL continues to pursue this case before the
Constitutional Court of Hungary.
(19) Hungary: eMAG/Extreme Digital (17 October 2019)
29
NCA: Gazdasági Versenyhivatal
Case number: VJ/14/2019
Concentration: Dante operates the online store eMAG and intended to acquire sole
control over Extreme Digital, the operator of an online store (edigital.hu) as well as of 16
brick-and-mortar retail outlets in Hungary. There was a particular overlap in the parties
in the sale of consumer electronics.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority concluded that the sale of consumer
electronics constitutes one single market, no matter whether distribution occurs online or
offline. The parties’ combined market share on this market was below 20%, meaning that
no anti-competitive effects would be found to arise. Even when only looking at the online
segment, however, the authority found that it would be unlikely for anti-competitive
effects to arise because of a transparency in market prices, the price sensitivity of online
consumers, the remaining competition from competitors, and market contestability.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 2.
Conditions: NA
Noteworthy: The case demonstrates how the interplay between online and offline
markets is increasingly incorporated into the antitrust assessment.
(20) Hungary: Netrisk.hu/Biztosítás.hu (12 December 2019)
30
NCA: Gazdasági Versenyhivatal
Case number: VJ/12/2019
Concentration: Netrisk.hu, an insurance mediation company, intended to acquire direct
and sole control over its competitor Biztosítás.hu. The two companies were the most
important online market participants in the relevant market concerned, which was
determined to be the market of non-life insurance mediation by brokers.
27
Fővárosi Törvényszék, Magyar RTL Televízió/Central Digitális Média (21.K.700.023/2018/12, 8 June
2018).
28
Kúria, Magyar RTL Televízió/Central Digitális Média (Kf.IV.38.095/2018/10, 9 December 2019).
29
The present summary is based on the press release of the Hungarian NCA; Gazdasági Versenyhivatal,
The Hungarian Competition Authority authorised the acquisition of Extreme Digital by eMAG (17
October 2019)
<https://www.gvh.hu/en/press_room/press_releases/press_releases_2019/the_hungarian_competition_aut
hority_authorised_the>.
30
The present summary is based on the press release of the Hungarian NCA; Gazdasági Versenyhivatal,
The GVH authorised the merger of Netrisk and Biztosítás.hu (12 December 2019)
<https://www.gvh.hu/en/press_room/press_releases/press_releases_2019/the-gvh-authorised-the-merger-
of-netrisk-and-biztositas.hu>.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
136
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority analysed both the impact the transaction
would have on the market, and the competitive pressure that can be expected from
traditional (ie, non-online) insurance mediators and insurers’ online platforms. It found
that the transaction would not lead to an anti-competitive outcome, especially as the price
of an insurance is set by insurers and agents, while insurance mediators cannot directly
increase prices. The authority also took into account the bargaining power of insurance
companies. The merging of databases through the acquisition would not, in the eyes of
the authority, have a substantial impact on data usability.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 2.
Conditions: NA
Noteworthy: The case demonstrates how the interplay between online and offline
markets is increasingly incorporated into the antitrust assessment.
(21) Ireland: Paddy Power/Betfair (15 January 2016)
NCA: Competition and Consumer Protection Commission
Case number: M/15/059
Concentration: Paddy Power, an international multi-channel betting and gaming
company with an online as well as a brick-and-mortar presence in the UK and in Ireland,
wanted to enter into a merger with Betfair, an international online-only gambling
operator. Markets affected included the national market for the provision of online fixed-
odds betting services and the national market for the provision of online gaming services.
Horizontal theories of harm: On the market for online betting services, the authority
concluded that the merging parties were not such close competitors on this market that
they would find it profitable to increase their prices post-merger.
On the market for the provision of online fixed-odds betting services, the merged entity
would face strong competition from various large competitors, and was therefore unlikely
to be able to increase its prices.
On the very competitive market for online gaming services, the merged entity would only
have a slight increase in market share compared to Paddy Power’s pre-merger market
share, and no anti-competitive effects were therefore considered to arise.
Overall, the authority noted that although Paddy Power was the market leader in a number
of relevant markets, its market shares had declined over the last years.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The authority analysed possible vertical effects in the
provision of live betting exchange data to online betting service providers, data that
Betfair provided and Paddy Power had previously purchased from it. This kind of data is
used by providers of online betting services to set their prices for fixed-odds events. The
authority assessed a possible input foreclosure of competing fixed-odds betting service
providers through restricting their access to Betfair’s live betting exchange data. They
concluded, however, that Betfair’s data did not constitute an essential input for these
providers, which is also seen in the fact that a number of online betting service providers
did not purchase this data from Betfair. In addition, there were an array of alternative
sources for this data. The authority thus concluded that the merger would not lead to
vertical input foreclosure.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
137
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
(22) Ireland: Ladbrokes/Gala Coral (10 March 2016)
NCA: Competition and Consumer Protection Commission
Case number: M/16/007
Concentration: Ladbrokes is a multi-channel betting and gaming company with online
and brick-and-mortar presence in Ireland, the UK, Spain and Belgium. It also owns the
online betting exchange Betdaq. Ladbrokes intended to merge with businesses of the Gala
Coral group that equally runs a multi-channel betting and gaming company with online
presence in Ireland and brick-and-mortar presence in the UK and Italy. Markets affected
included the national market for the provision of online fixed-odds betting services and
the national market for the provision of online gaming services
Horizontal theories of harm: The horizontal overlap in online betting, online gaming
and telephone betting services was assessed. The authority considered that a number of
large competitors operated on these markets that would act as competitive constraints on
the merged entity, and that the target’s share of these markets was rather insignificant.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: A potential vertical overlap between the parties
concerned the sale of betting exchange data, which Ladbrokes sold in Ireland. When
assessing whether this could lead to the foreclosure of competing fixed-odds betting
service providers, the authority relied on the same analysis it had carried out in Paddy
Power/Betfair (case M/15/059) and highlighted that not only was this not essential input,
but there were also alternative sources for obtaining such data.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
(23) Ireland: Stars Group/Sky Betting & Gaming (18 June 2018)
NCA: Competition and Consumer Protection Commission
Case number: M/18/038
Concentration: Stars Group is a global provider of technology-based products and
services related to online gaming and interactive entertainment. Amongst others, it offers
online gaming and online sportsbook betting, operates real-world poker tournaments, and
provides affiliate marketing services and odds comparison through iBus. Stars Group
intended to acquire Cyan Blue, which controls the Sky Betting & Gaming group. The Sky
Betting & Gaming group is active in online and mobile betting and gaming services and
also operates Oddschecker, an odds comparison service that provides customers with
price/odds comparisons but also offers betting and gaming providers advertising space.
Markets affected included the national market for the provision of online fixed-odds
betting services, the national market for the provision of online gaming services, the
national market for the supply of online advertising space on gambling-related websites,
and the national market for the provision of odds comparison services.
Horizontal theories of harm: In terms of horizontal overlaps, the authority considered
effects on the following markets: online betting services, online gaming services, online
advertising space on gambling-related websites, and online gambling affiliate marketing
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
138
services. Based on the low combined market shares of the merged entity and the large
number of competitors active in these markets, the transaction did not raise competition
concerns in the eyes of the authority. In particular, the authority underlined that in online
gaming services, there was a high degree of market transparency for consumers, including
through odds comparison websites, and consumers tended to multi-home, thereby
ensuring there would not be anti-competitive effects.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: In terms of vertical relationships, the authority
assessed odds comparison and online affiliate marketing. In odds comparison, Stars
Group had an affiliate contract with Sky’s Oddschecker. The authority thus analysed
whether, post-merger, the merged entity may have the ability and incentive to foreclose
competing providers from accessing odds comparison or to foreclose competing odds
comparison services. It concluded that neither would be the case based on the large
number of online fixed-odds betting providers and online gaming providers present on
the market, and in the light of the small market share increase in these markets for the
merged entity. The authority also held that Oddschecker was unlikely to refuse to display
competing offers on its comparison site, as displaying multiple offerings is required for
these types of sites. In addition, there are several competing odds comparison services
active on the market. In conclusion, the authority found that the merged entity would have
neither the ability nor the incentive to foreclose competing providers from accessing odds
comparison.
On the market for online affiliate marketing services, the authority analysed whether,
post-merger, the merged entity may have the ability and incentive to foreclose competing
online fixed-odds betting providers or online gaming providers from accessing online
affiliate marketing services, or to foreclose competing online affiliate marketing services.
It concluded that based on the high number of international online market affiliates
specialising in the gambling sector, the high number of competing online fixed-odds
betting providers and online gaming providers, and the low market involvement of iBus,
no vertical foreclosure concerns would materialise.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
(24) Ireland: EQT Fund Management/SUSE (18 September 2018)
NCA: Competition and Consumer Protection Commission
Case number: M/18/066
Concentration: EQT, a group of private equity funds investing in portfolio companies,
wanted to acquire SUSE, an open source software provider with a focus on infrastructure
software and middleware. EQT already held four companies active in software, but none
of these horizontally overlapped with SUSE.
Horizontal theories of harm: NA
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The transaction would lead to vertical integration
between SUSE in infrastructure software and middleware (upstream) and EQT’s software
companies in application software (downstream). The authority therefore assessed
possible vertical foreclosure, once upstream in the supply of infrastructure, middleware
and database software; and once downstream in the purchasing of infrastructure,
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
139
middleware and database software. On input foreclosure, the authority considered that the
low market shares held by the merged entity would not allow it to engage in the
foreclosure of Linux operating systems for servers or any of the types of software. On
customer foreclosure, EQT’s low turnover in application software led the authority to
conclude that the merged entity would not be able to foreclose upstream competitors from
accessing application software providers.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
(25) Ireland: Applied Materials/Kokusai Electric Corporation (11 October 2019)
NCA: Competition and Consumer Protection Commission
Case number: M/19/027
Concentration: Applied Materials proposed to acquire sole control of Kokusai Electric
Corporation, a transaction that affected the national market for the supply of wafer
fabrication equipment tools (semiconductors).
Horizontal theories of harm: Based on the intricacies and great differentiation within
the sector of wafer fabrication equipment, the authority found that the deposition tools
offered by the acquirer and the target were not substitutes and did not compete with each
other; there was only a minimal overlap that was not considered to raise any competition
concerns.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
(26) Ireland: Flutter Entertainment/Stars Group (12 May 2020)
NCA: Competition and Consumer Protection Commission
Case number: M/20/001
Concentration: Flutter Entertainment, a gambling operator active amongst others online
as well as through 620 Paddy Power outlets in the UK and Ireland, proposed to acquire
Stars, a Canadian operator of technology-based product offerings in the gambling and
interactive entertainment industries. Stars did not operate local betting offices in Ireland.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed the horizontal overlap in the
provision of online gambling services in Ireland and the likelihood of unilateral effects
following the merger. In online betting services, it found that the parties were not each
other’s closest competitors and that a high degree of transparency allowed consumers
easy comparison and switching. It concluded that unilateral effects post-merger were
unlikely to be successful. In online fixed-odds betting services, it found similar market
conditions as those outlined above.
In online gaming services, the authority found that the merged entity would not have the
ability to unilaterally raise prices. And in online poker services, the authority found that
there were relatively low entry barriers and market transparency contributed to easy
switching for consumers, making unilateral effects unlikely.
The authority did not raise any concerns relating to the small horizontal overlap in the
supply of odds comparison services.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
140
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The authority identified a number of (actual and
potential) vertical relationships between the merging parties. As concerns odds
comparison services, the authority noted that Stars’ service Oddschecker had an affiliate
contract with Flutter. However, two competitors that were more important than
Oddschecker would continue to represent a competitive constraint for Oddschecker. The
authority also highlighted that the merged entity was unlikely to foreclose rival online
betting services providers from accessing odds comparison services, because that would
make Oddschecker less compelling in the eyes of consumers.
Concerning online affiliate marketing services, the authority noted that Stars’ iBus
affiliate marketing services were of limited relevance in Ireland, and over 35,000 online
marketing affiliates specialising in the gambling sector continued to provide such services
after the merger. On the provision of horse racing and football data, the authority
considered that a number of alternative horse racing and football data providers would
continue to exist post-merger, representing a competitive constraint. Finally, the authority
did not believe any vertical competition concerns would arise in relation to the provision
of gaming developments services and the provision of online betting exchange data.
Concerning the adjacent market of matched betting services, the authority concluded that
the merged entity would neither have the ability nor the incentive to foreclose matched
betting services providers from the market, as these could gather the data required through
other means and constituted a means for customer acquisition for online betting services
providers.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: The authority assessed the closeness between competitors by analysing
their Google AdWord spending as directed at their competitors. As Oddschecker was not
a service with a dominant position, the likelihood of it engaging in self-preferencing by
providing a better positioning for its own services was not assessed.
This concentration was also unconditionally cleared in Bulgaria,
31
Malta,
32
Spain
33
and
the UK.
34
(27) Ireland: Booster/Liftoff Mobile (15 February 2021)
NCA: Competition and Consumer Protection Commission
Case number: M/21/002
Concentration: Booster proposed to acquire Liftoff Mobile on the national market for
mobile app advertising intermediation. Booster is owned by Blackstone, an alternative
asset manager and provider of financial advisory services. Among its assets is Vungle, a
provider of technology-enabled advertising services to advertisers. Liftoff Mobile
provides mobile online advertising services.
31
Комисия за защита на конкуренцията, Flutter Entertainment/Stars Group (269/16.04.2020, 16 April
2020).
32
Malta Competition and Consumer Affairs Authority, Flutter Entertainment/Stars Group (COMP-
MCCAA/03/2020, 18 February 2020).
33
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Flutter Entertainment/Stars Group (C/1094/20
12 Mar 2020, 12 March 2020).
34
Competition & Markets Authority, Flutter Entertainment/Stars Group (ME/6865/19, 31 March 2020).
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
141
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority identified a horizontal overlap between
Liftoff Mobile and Vungle. However, it found that the transaction would raise no
competition concerns because this overlap was minimal and the parties’ combined market
share would be below 5%. In addition, a number of important competitors were present
on the market, including Google and Facebook, which would continue to exert important
competitive pressure.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: No relevant vertical relationship was identified.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: In the eyes of the authority, the presence of Google and Facebook indicated
that the merged entity would be subject to intense competition.
(28) Italy: OEP 14 Coöperatief/Techedge (4 August 2020)
NCA: Autoritá Garante della Concorrenza e del Mercato
Case number: 28331
Concentration: OEP 14 Coöperatief, a private equity firm, proposed to acquire
Techedge, an Italian company active in the management and digitalisation of business
processes.
Horizontal theories of harm: Due to the low market shares of the undertakings involved,
both in the area of information technology and in the area of software services, and due
to the presence of important competitors, the authority did not consider any anti-
competitive effects to arise.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
(29) Malta: GVC Holdings/Ladbrokes Coral Group (21 March 2018)
NCA: Malta Competition and Consumer Affairs Authority
Case number: COMP-MCCAA/4/18
Concentration: GVC Holdings, a multinational sports betting and gaming group, wanted
to acquire the Ladbrokes Coral Group, a multinational multi-channel betting and gaming
company that operates betting shops as well as online betting and gaming. The markets
affected were found to be the national market for the provision of online fixed-odds
sportsbook betting services and the national market for the provision of online gaming
services.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority found that the aggregate market share for
the supply of online fixed-odds betting services via sportsbook would be between 15-
25%. In online gaming services, the combined market share would amount to 25-35%.
Post-merger, a number of important competitors would continue constraining the merged
entity some with the same or higher market shares than the latter. The authority also
noted that a substantial number of gaming licenses had been awarded and that many
international online gaming companies would be authorised to operate in Malta. It
described the market as dynamic with noticeable fluctuations.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
142
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
(30) Netherlands: Sanoma/Iddink (28 August 2019)
35
NCA: Autoriteit Consument & Markt
Case number: ACM/19/035555
Concentration: Sanoma, a publisher of (digital) learning materials, wanted to acquire
Iddink, a distributor of (digital) learning materials and electronic learning environments
in secondary education
Horizontal theories of harm: NA
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The authority was concerned that the acquisition
could foreclose competitors of Iddink’s electronic learning environments by providing
preferential treatment or better compatibility with Sanoma products on the market for
issuing educational materials (input foreclosure). As a result, competitors would become
less effective, barriers to entry would be raised and opportunities for innovation would be
harmed. In view of the digital nature of the market and the need for further digitization in
the educational resource chain, this would have a negative impact on price, quality and
innovation.
On customer foreclosure regarding the issuance of educational materials, the authority
did not believe the merged entity would have an incentive to foreclose after the proposed
concentration.
The authority considered it plausible that Sanoma would have access to commercially
sensitive information from competitors after the proposed concentration, giving it an
advantage over its competitors and possibly impeding competition in the market for the
issuance of teaching materials in secondary education.
The authority found that the merged entity could not profitably implement a foreclosure
strategy through bundling based on the limited income resulting from such a foreclosure
strategy.
Overall, the authority found that the concentration would significantly impede effective
competition.
Outcome: Conditionally cleared in phase 2.
Conditions: To address the competition concerns it had identified, the authority cleared
the concentration subject to the following conditions: Sanoma would (i) grant publishers
access to the Magister
36
API under fair, reasonable and non-discriminatory (FRAND)
conditions, including the necessary information to enable the same link with Magister for
all publishers; (ii) provide information about Magister to publishers who request this
under FRAND conditions, if they provide similar information to Sanoma; (iii) implement
internal measures to ensure that Sanoma does not have access to competitively sensitive
information about other publishers; and (iv) conclude a service agreement with publishers
for the disclosure and use of digital learning resources of publishers via Magister, which
35
Thank you to Dániel Élő for providing a summary of this case, which was subsequently shortened by the
author of this Report.
36
Magister is an educational platform that provides a digital learning environment, student administration
functionalities and an app for students and parents; see Magister, <https://www.magister.nl/>.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
143
includes the option for publishers to have it established by means of their own audit that
the publisher in question gains access to the Magister API in a FRAND manner and a
dispute settlement procedure is to be arranged.
Noteworthy: After the Court of Rotterdam’s ruling partially setting aside the initial
decision,
37
the authority carried out additional investigations and retained the conditions
for the clearance of the acquisition.
38
On 12 July 2022, , the Trade and Industry Appeals
Tribunal (College van Beroep voor het Bedrijfsleven) ruled that the authority had rightly
cleared the transaction subject to conditions, and consequently upheld the authority’s
decision of 28 August 2019.
39
(31) Netherlands: DPG/Sanoma (10 April 2020)
40
NCA: Autoriteit Consument & Markt
Case number: ACM/19/038207
Concentration: DPG intended to acquire Sanoma. DPG was active in the field of news
media, including the publishing of newspapers and door-to-door papers, radio and online
services, including in the field of online job advertisements, price comparison and car and
technology websites and also on the Dutch radio market. The target was active in the field
of publishing a large number of magazines, offering online news and online services,
including comparison websites.
Horizontal theories of harm: The activities of the parties horizontally overlapped in the
provision of general (online) news and the provision of online advertising space.
Although DPG would become an important provider of unpaid general online news, it
would continue to experience competitive pressure from other (unpaid) online news
media (e.g., NOS, Mediahuis and RTL) and from other news channels such as print, radio
and TV. In addition, DPG had no incentive to degrade the quality of its unpaid general
online news offerings given the reach achieved with these offerings and the importance
of reach for (i) generating advertising revenue and (ii) referral to e-commerce services.
In terms of advertising space, the merged entity would only have limited market power
and would experience fierce competition from Google and Facebook. The authority
therefore did not expect any negative consequences for competition in this area.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The authority investigated vertical as well as
conglomerate theories of harm, but concluded that the concentration was unlikely to
significantly impede effective competition. While DPG could use the concentration to
improve its position in paid general online news, such a strategy would not foreclose
competitors. DPG might also be able to bundle its activities on various markets with its
online advertising services, but the authority concluded that DPG would not have market
power in any advertising market that it could transfer to adjacent advertising markets.
37
Rechtbank Rotterdam, Sanoma/Iddink (ROT 19/5120, 4 March 2021), ECLI:NL:RBROT:2021:1766.
38
Autoriteit Consument & Markt, ‘After follow-up investigation, ACM still conditionally clears acquisition
of Iddink Group by Sanoma Learning’ (27 August 2021) <https://www.acm.nl/en/publications/after-
follow-investigation-acm-still-conditionally-clears-acquisition-iddink-group-sanoma-learning>.
39
College van Beroep voor het Bedrijfsleven, Sanoma/Iddink (21/467, 21/468 & 21/469, 12 July 2022),
ECLI:NL:CBB:2022:411.
40
Thank you to Dániel Élő for providing a summary of this case, which was subsequently shortened by the
author of this Report.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
144
Post-merger, DPG would also have the ability to use its position in unpaid general online
news to refer visitors to its own e-commerce activities, but again this would be unlikely
to foreclose competitors. This is because in online job and car advertisements, the
concentration would not lead to market power. Sufficient alternative channels would
remain available for recruiting visitors for providers of job and car advertisements. The
same was true for price comparison services, where placing hyperlinks from unpaid
general online news to price comparison services would not lead to foreclosure.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Conditions: NA
Noteworthy: As in many other cases, the strong market position of Facebook and Google
in online advertising was seen as an important constraining factor on the merged entity.
(32) Netherlands: NS Groep/Pon Netherlands (20 May 2020)
41
NCA: Autoriteit Consument & Markt
Case number: ACM/20/038614
Concentration: NS Groep (NS) and Pon Netherlands (Pon) intended to set up a full-
function joint venture (JV) in the field of shared mobility through one central mobile
application and specific mobility hubs. NS was the largest provider of public transport by
train in the Netherlands and also offered shared bicycles at train stations under the OV-
fiets brand. Through a subsidiary, it offered shared (electric) bicycles, shared (electric)
cars and shared (electric) cargo bikes. Pon produced and imported means of transport
such as (electric) bicycles, (electric) scooters and cars. These constituted an important
input for the provision of such services. In addition, Pon was also active in the field of
partial transport services through other companies.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed a range of markets in which both
parties were active, including the provision of shared bicycles (NS, Hely
42
and Next
43
),
the provision of shared cars (Pon, Hely and Next) and the distribution of transport and
mobility services via an app (Hely and Next).
Concerning the provision of (e-)shared bicycles to the general public, the authority
concluded that competition would not be significantly impeded as Next’s offer was
largely aimed at private hubs, its market share added very little to the JV, and there was
competitive pressure from other parties in Amsterdam.
In relation to the provision of shared cars, the authority found that several factors
indicated that the JV would not significantly impede effective competition, namely the
low joint market share of the parties, the existing competitive pressure from other
suppliers of station-based shared cars, the (potential) competitive pressure from suppliers
of free-floating shared cars and the fact that the market was still in full development.
Concerning the (retail) market for the integrated provision of transport and mobility
services via an app, the authority found that this market was developing strongly. The JV
would experience competitive pressure from both local providers of transport modalities
41
Thank you to Dániel Élő for providing a summary of this case, which was subsequently shortened by the
author of this Report.
42
Hely was a subsidiary of NS.
43
Next Urban Mobility was a subsidiary of Pon.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
145
and from providers of integrated mobility services, leading the authority to conclude that
no anti-competitive effects would arise.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed a range of vertical
relationships. The authority believed that, due to the JV, NS would have both the ability
and the incentive to engage in a partial input foreclosure strategy regarding its train
services and the integrated provision of transport and mobility services via an app. This
could lead to (i) foreclosure of current providers of integrated mobility services via an
app, and (ii) raise barriers to entry into the national market for the integrated provision of
transport and mobility services via an app. Based on this, the authority believed that the
JV could result in a significant restriction of competition. The commitments submitted by
the parties removed this risk in the eyes of the authority (see below).
In terms of shared bicycles and shared cars, the authority concluded that it was not
plausible that NS would have the ability and incentive to implement a customer
foreclosure strategy vis-à-vis providers of bicycle-sharing and providers of car-sharing.
Outcome: Conditionally cleared in phase 1.
Conditions: To address the authority’s competition concerns, the parties offered to grant
(potential) competitors of the JV access to the application programming interfaces (APIs)
of the train and OV-fiets services on equal (commercial) conditions as these will made
available to the JV.
Noteworthy: In this case, vertical input foreclosure concerns alone led to the necessity
of commitments on the part of the notifying parties.
(33) Poland: 1&1 Internet/Home.pl (22 December 2015)
44
NCA: Urząd Ochrony Konkurencji i Konsumentów
Case number: DKK-216/2015
Concentration: 1&1, which belongs to the United Internet Group (UI) and offers cloud
computing services, proposed to acquire Home.pl on the national market for .pl national
domains (registration and operation), the national market for hosting services and the
national market for cloud computing.
Horizontal theories of harm: On the market for the .pl national domain (registration and
operation), the authority assessed the market shares of the merging parties and found that
as regards registration services, those were at 40-50%, while for operation services they
were at 30-40%. The target’s market share in both had recently dropped, while the main
competitor’s share of the market (Nazwa for registration services, Name for operation
services) was steadily increasing. Also, the HHI delta did not exceed 150, from which the
authority concluded that the likelihood of strengthening the market position of the merged
entity was very small. Post-merger, the merged entity would continue to be constrained
by other companies. Also, entry barriers were low, as was evidenced by 203 companies
that had the status of ‘NASK Partner’ (NASK stands for the Polish Research and
Academic Computer Network) in 2014, meaning they could provide registration and
operation services related to the national domain .pl.
44
Thank you to Klaudia Majcher for providing a summary of this case, which was subsequently shortened
by the author of this Report.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
146
On the market for hosting services, the merged entity would have a market share below
40% (the national dominance benchmark). The target’s market share was much larger
than the acquirer’s. Post-merger, market concentration would only increase
insignificantly and the merged entity would face competition from other companies.
The authority rejected the argument that the transaction would impair competition due to
the capital potential of UI. UI, which started to operate in Poland in 2010, had not
achieved any considerable market success and had not created a recognisable brand in
Poland despite its capital and significant advertising efforts. Hence, UI’s financial
position would not contribute to the strengthening of the merged entity’s position in a
way that could distort competition.
The authority also noted that entry barriers in both markets under investigation were low,
and switching rates indicated low customer loyalty.
In the national market for cloud computing, the aggregate market shares of both
companies were insignificant (0-5%), which is why it was not further investigated.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The undertakings concerned did not operate in any
upstream or downstream market in which their individual or joint market shares would
exceed 30%. No markets were affected by the concentration in a conglomerate sense.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 2.
Remedies: NA
(34) Portugal: Sonae/CTT - Correios de Portugal JV (19 July 2018)
NCA: Autoridade da Concorrência
Case number: Ccent. 27/2018
Concentration: Sonae and CTT - Correios de Portugal (Post Portugal) notified the
creation of a joint venture (JV) dedicated to the operation of an e-commerce platform for
the provision of intermediation services between traders and consumers. A number of
markets were affected, including the market for the provision of online marketplace
services, the market for online advertising and the markets for information technology
services, cybersecurity services and data analytics services.
Horizontal theories of harm: NA
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The JV would create a new player on the market for
the provision of online marketplace services, possibly leading to more diverse offerings
on that market. The authority noted that the main players on that market consisted of
Aliexpress, Amazon, eBay and Rakuten, all of which were B2C platforms with generalist
offerings. There were also non-generalist players, C2C platforms and non-transactional
platforms active on that market. While Sonae was active in online advertising, its market
presence was not significant. Also due to the strong market presence of Facebook and
Google on that market, the authority did not express competition concerns related to
online advertising.
The authority also assessed the presence of CTT on a number of markets related to an
online marketplace, such as logistics services, express delivery and payment processing.
Due to the low market shares, the authority generally considered that no competition
concerns would arise. It then considered the presence of Sonae on a number of vertically
related markets, including IT services and the retail sale of children’s clothing, sporting
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
147
goods and consumer electronics. It concluded that Sonae would not be able to adopt any
strategy that would involve the termination or deterioration of supply conditions to
customers that operated on the same market as the JV (input foreclosure). It also held that
Sonae would not be able to foreclose the JV’s competitors by no longer reselling products
to competing marketplaces. Despite its relatively high market share in certain retail
markets (sporting goods, consumer electronics), there remained multiple competitors that
would constrain such a strategy of input foreclosure. Based on the ownership structure of
certain companies associated with Sonae, it was also unlikely that they would have an
incentive to adopt such a strategy to the benefit of the JV. Overall, the authority therefore
found that the JV would neither be able to nor have the incentive to engage in input
foreclosure of other marketplaces. Also, it found it unlikely that Sonae and CTT would
adopt a strategy of customer foreclosure by preventing Sonae’s competitors in various
markets from providing services to the JV or reselling its products on its marketplace.
This would prevent the success of a marketplace, which requires two market sides to
come on board.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: The authority relied on two-sided market economics to explain why the
envisaged JV would not have an incentive to engage in customer foreclosure. It also drew
attention to market leaders Google and Facebook in online advertising.
(35) Romania: Dante International/PC Garage (24 November 2016)
45
NCA: România Consiliul Concurenței
Case number: 84/24.11.2016
Concentration: Dante International is a company that provides an online platform and
also acts as a retailer thereon (dual presence). It also provides electronics and IT products.
Dante wanted to acquire PC Garage, an online consumer goods retailer with a focus on
IT products and electronics.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority found that the acquisition would serve to
further strengthen Dante’s market position, and would therefore significantly impede
effective competition in certain products.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: Dante’s vertical integration was noted by the
authority.
Outcome: Conditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: In order to address the competition concerns raised by the authority, Dante
committed (i) to divest four online stores active in the non-food retail market (namely,
pcfun.ro, shopit.ro, garagemall.ro and electrofun.ro) as an ongoing concern, (ii) not to be
involved in the divested activities for at least 10 years.
45
This summary is based on the account of Raluca Dinu, ‘Romania’ in Daniel Mândrescu (ed), EU
Competition Law and the Digital Economy: Protecting Free and Fair Competition in an Age of
Technological (R)Evolution (XXIX FIDE Congress 2020) 451, 451-452; ‘Dante International, PC Garage
merger gets conditional Romanian approval’ MLex (29 November 2016)
<https://content.mlex.com/#/content/846719?referrer=search_linkclick>.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
148
(36) Romania: Glovoappro/Foodpanda (22 November 2021)
46
NCA: România Consiliul Concurenței
Case number: 86/22.11.2021
Concentration: Glovo wanted to acquire Foodpanda on the national market for online
food delivery platforms and the national market for online platforms for delivery of
multicategory consumer goods.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority was concerned that the merged entity would
have a dominant position and would then be able to impose exclusivity clauses on
restaurants. While users tend to multi-home on this market, such exclusivity clauses
would reduce the beneficial effect of this multi-homing.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Conditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: In order to address the authority’s competition concerns, Glovo proposed not
to impose exclusivity obligations on restaurants. This included the following, more
detailed commitments: (1) not to impose an exclusive obligation on restaurants in current
or future intermediation agreements with restaurants, (2) not to contractually base the
level of commissions paid by restaurants on exclusivity, (3) not to penalise restaurants
for joining another online food ordering platform, and (4) not to renew the target’s
exclusivity obligations vis-à-vis restaurants.
(37) Slovenia: Sully System/CENEJE (12 April 2018)
47
NCA: Javna agencija Republike Slovenije za varstvo konkurence
Case number: 3061-27/2017-71
Concentration: With the contract on the sale of business shares, Sully System acquired
sole control over Ceneje, a company active in the market of online advertising through
search engines.
Horizontal theories of harm: NA
Non-horizontal theories of harm: In the proposed concentration there were vertical
overlaps as the online price comparison market in which Ceneje was present, is vertically
linked to the online retail market for non-food consumer goods, in which Sully System
operated. The authority first assessed the effects of the proposed concentration on the
online price comparison market (the upstream market) and then on the online retail market
for non-food consumer goods (the downstream market). The merged entity would have a
market share of more than 30% in at least one relevant market. Its main concerns were
twofold. First, the merged entity could engage in input foreclosure, especially by
discriminating between offers of online retailers and by using of non-objective search and
ranking algorithms of online retailers offers which would be preferential to the merged
entity. Secondly, the authority was also concerned with regard to the merged entity’s
access to commercially sensitive information regarding competitors’ activities in the
downstream market.
46
This summary is based on the summary provided on the Caselex Platform, <caselex.eu> (Remedies
Module).
47
Thank you to Martina Repas for providing a summary of this case, which was subsequently shortened by
the author of this Report.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
149
Outcome: Conditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: To address these competition concerns, the parties offered the following
commitments to the authority: (i) Ceneje would not discriminate, either directly or
indirectly, between online retailer ads, in particular with regard to appearance and display,
(ii) Ceneje would maintain neutral and objective search and ranking algorithms used for
online retailers ads, (iii) Ceneje would maintain neutral and objective recommendations,
(iv) Sully System’s website would include a statement that Ceneje is a member of the
Rockaway Group, (v) Sully System would ensure that Ceneje meets all its obligations in
the proposed commitments, (vi) Sully System would provide historical price data to the
authority every six months for a period of 30 months.
The authority decided that the proposed commitments were appropriate and thus able to
eliminate the competition concerns.
Noteworthy: As in the Czech case of Rockaway Capital/Heureka,
48
a transparency
commitment was regarded as an important aspect to counter competition concerns.
(38) Slovenia: ECE/ELTUS PLUS (25 April 2019)
49
NCA: Javna agencija Republike Slovenije za varstvo konkurence
Case number: 3061-41/2018
Concentration: Under a contract for the sale and purchase of assets, ECE would become
the owner of ELTUS PLUS’s online store. ECE is a company dealing with the sale of
energy, and also offers online shopping services.
Horizontal theories of harm: In the proposed concentration there were horizontal
overlaps in the online non-food retail market, on which the undertakings concerned only
had negligible market shares.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: In assessing the market shares of the undertakings concerned on the market
of online retail sale of non-food goods in Slovenia, the authority took into account only
competitors with a seat in Slovenia whose activities are exclusively the online retail sale
of non-food goods. Among these, it considered only those who offered products of all
those categories that are common to the online offers of the undertakings concerned.
(39) Slovenia: Shoppster/IDEO PLUS (24 April 2020)
50
NCA: Javna agencija Republike Slovenije za varstvo konkurence
Case number: 3061-9/2020-14
Concentration: Shoppster, owned by Slovenia Broadband in Luxembourg, acquired
100% of shares in IDEAL PLUS under a contract for the sale of shares. Shoppster was
48
Úřad pro ochranu hospodářské soutěže, Rockaway Capital/Heureka (ÚOHS-S0013/2016/KS-
21123/2016/840/DVá, 16 May 2016).
49
Thank you to Martina Repas for providing a summary of this case, which was subsequently shortened by
the author of this Report.
50
Thank you to Martina Repas for providing a summary of this case, which was subsequently shortened by
the author of this Report.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
150
established to provide retail services by mail order or online, while IDEO PLUS provides
online retail services.
Horizontal theories of harm: There was a partial horizontal overlap between the
activities of the associated undertaking of Shoppster and IDEO PLUS in the segment of
mobile phone sales. The authority found that the sale of mobile phones by these
undertakings was not substitutable: While IDEO PLUS sold mobile telephones over-the-
counter, the associated undertaking of Shoppster exclusively sold them through a range
of packages, i.e. by linking those sales to its mobile telephony services. IDEO PLUS also
sold mobile phones through its online store for non-food goods, while Shoppster’s
associated undertaking Telemach is a telecommunication operator that operates in the
market of telephony services, where it offered the option of buying mobile phones online.
Considering the market shares of the undertakings concerned, the presence of competitors
and low barriers to entry, the authority concluded that the proposed concentration would
not eliminate effective competition in the relevant market.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
(40) Slovenia: Allegro.eu/MIMOVRSTE (24 January 2022)
51
NCA: Javna agencija Republike Slovenije za varstvo konkurence
Case number: 3061-25/2021-6
Concentration: The subject of the concentration is the acquisition of the entire business
share in Mimovrste, which is fully owned by Mall Group, which is owned by EC
Investment, Bonak and Rockaway e-commerce. With the contract, the parties agreed that
Allegro.eu would buy 100% of the shares of Mall Group, and later the shares would be
transferred to Allegro.pl. Allegro.pl would eventually become the sole shareholder of
Mall Group, thus acquiring sole control over Mimovrste. Mimovrste provides retail
services by mail order or online. Its core business is managing an online store platform.
Allegro.eu is an online platform operating in Poland.
Horizontal theories of harm: In the proposed concentration there was a horizontal
overlap between the activities of the undertakings concerned. However, there was no such
overlap in the relevant Slovenian market, since Allegro.eu and its associated undertakings
did not operate in Slovenia. Consequently, the authority was of the opinion that the
proposed concentration would not have negative effects on competition in the food retail
market and in the non-food retail market in Slovenia, especially due to actual and potential
competition as well as low entry barriers.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
(41) Spain: Schibsted/Milanuncios (20 November 2014)
51
Thank you to Martina Repas for providing a summary of this case, which was subsequently shortened by
the author of this Report.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
151
NCA: Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia
Case number: C/0573/14
Concentration: Schibsted, a multinational media group, wanted to acquire Milanuncios,
an online platform specialised in classified advertisements.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority was concerned that this acquisition could
raise horizontal unilateral effects by strengthening Schibsted’s market power vis-à-vis
professional advertisers, which would be faced with price increases for classified
advertisements.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Conditionally cleared in phase 2.
Remedies: In order to address the authority’s competition concerns, Schibsted would
allow a third party to exploit on an exclusive basis professional advertisements
displayed on the platform related to the motor segment of milanuncios.com. The merged
entity also had to give automatic access to professional advertisers’ data. The licensee
would also be allowed to redirect traffic to their own website. The exclusive license would
be valid for two years.
(42) Spain: Just Eat/La Nevera Roja (31 March 2016)
NCA: Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia
Case number: C/0730/16
Concentration: Just Eat planned to acquire La Nevera Roja on the Spanish market for
the management of food orders at home via online platforms, accessed via internet or
mobile applications. While Just Eat had its seat in London, La Nevera Roja was founded
in Spain in 2010.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority considered that this horizontal merger may
raise competition concerns because the acquirer and the target were close competitors and
constituted, pre-merger, the biggest and second biggest players on the market for the
management of food orders via online platforms. After the merger, they would have a
combined market share of about 70-80%, possibly even higher. In addition, several
companies had recently exited that market. The authority emphasised the importance of
network effects in these markets, and high barriers to entry consisting of investments to
be made in publicity and marketing. The authority was concerned that the merged entity
may have both the ability and the incentive to start implementing a strategy of exclusivity,
thus foreclosing competing platforms from access to restaurants (customer foreclosure).
Nevertheless, the authority also noted that online food delivery platforms only accounted
for 10% of the local food delivery markets in Spain, meaning that the market power of
these platforms over restaurants was overall limited. Restaurants also had the option of
opting for providing home delivery themselves, further restricting the platform’s market
power over it.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Conditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: In order to address the authority’s competition concerns relating to a possible
foreclosure of other food order platforms, Just Eat proposed the following commitments:
(1) not to impose exclusivity on restaurants (currently or in the future) affiliated with it;
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
152
(2) no tying of commissions paid by affiliated restaurants (current or in the future) to an
exclusivity obligation; (3) no penalisation of affiliated restaurants (current or in the
future) for joining third platforms. The public documents did not state the duration of
these commitments. Just Eat further promised to communicate these commitments to its
affiliates within two weeks of them being accepted by the authority.
The authority considered that these commitments would severely limit Just Eat’s ability
to engage in exclusivity strategies, thus allowing restaurants to continue multi-homing.
Bearing in mind the expansive nature of the relevant market and different competitive
strategies employed by different platforms, the authority considered that the
commitments would allow the market to remain competitive.
Noteworthy: This acquisition involved a multinational acquiring a local competitor in a
market that has been uprooted due to digitalisation.
52
In the case of Just Eat Spain/Canary Delivery Company,
53
the authority emphasised that
the commitments accepted in Just Eat/La Nevera Roja had favoured market entry in Spain
for digital food order platforms and thus led to a more competitive market.
(43) Spain: Daimler/Hailo/MyTaxi/Negocio Hailo (24 November 2016)
NCA: Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia
Case number: C/0802/16
Concentration: Daimler and Hailo wanted to jointly aquire MyTaxi and Hailo, which
enabled end users to hire taxi services online. The two businesses should be merged after
the joint acquisition. Markets affected included, among others, the Barcelona and Madrid
markets for intermediary services for contracting taxi routes or journeys through apps.
Horizontal theories of harm: Concerning horizontal unilateral effects, the authority
found that the concentration would significantly strengthen the market power of the
resulting entity, which combined two close competitors. It also considered that end users
could turn to other means for hailing a ride radiotaxi, street hailing, third apps that
constrained the resulting entity. Also, market penetration by the resulting entity was low
among end users (5%) and a little higher among taxis (20-30%). Taxis did not enter into
exclusivity contracts. Although the new entity would likely enjoy market power post-
merger, the authority considered that this was a dynamic market that had seen rapid
expansion, and there were no barriers to expansion despite the economies of scale and
network effects at work in this market. Therefore, no competition concerns would arise.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: The characteristics of this particular digital market directly affected the
competitive assessment of the merger.
52
José Marino García García and Pablo Ibáñez Colomo, ‘Spain’ in Daniel Mândrescu (ed), EU Competition
Law and the Digital Economy: Protecting Free and Fair Competition in an Age of Technological
(R)Evolution (XXIX FIDE Congress 2020) 499, 500-501.
53
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Just Eat Spain/Canary Delivery Company
(C/1046/19, 10 September 2019).
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
153
(44) Spain: Just Eat Spain/Canary Delivery Company (10 September 2019)
NCA: Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia
Case number: C/1046/19
Concentration: Just Eat Spain, which started operating in 2010 and covers 95% of
Spanish territory with its digital platform for food orders, wanted to acquire the local
Canary Delivery Company, which provides an online food order management platform
in the Canary Islands.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority found that while Just Eat would increase its
market share in the national market for the management of food orders at home via online
platforms, that increase would only be marginal. In addition, in the years preceding the
transaction Just Eat had continuously lost market share. The foreseen market entry of
Uber Eats and the consolidation of Deliveroo were also seen as indicators of a dynamic
market. The authority noted that these market entries occurred at a time when the
remedies from the transaction Just Eat/La Nevera Roja
54
were still in force, favouring
market entry in Spain.
In the local market for online food order management platforms, the transaction would
lead to an important increase in market share of 50-70%, leading to a market share of 80-
90%. Assessing the risk that the merging entity would raise prices or have the ability and
incentive to foreclose restaurants for competitors by entering into exclusivity contracts
with them, the authority considered that the recent and successful entry of competitor
Glovo in 2018 and the entry of Uber Eats in the summer of 2019 indicated that this was
not realistic. The authority also highlighted that the target had a very limited turnover and
only a single employee (the owner).
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: The authority emphasised that the remedies imposed in the case of Just
Eat/La Nevera Roja had favoured market entry in Spain for digital food order platforms
and had thus led to a more competitive market.
(45) Spain: MIH Food Delivery Holdings/Just Eat (5 December 2019)
NCA: Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia
Case number: C/1072/19
Concentration: MIH Food Delivery Holdings, which is owned by Prosus, wanted to
engage in a hostile takeover of Just Eat on the national market for food order handling
through online platforms. MIH held several stakes in assets related to the digital consumer
home delivery sector, and in particular a minority share in Delivery Hero, an online food
delivery platform active in more than 40 countries (but not Spain). Delivery Hero,
however, also had a minority stake in Glovo, Spain’s second largest food delivery
platform.
54
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Just Eat/La Nevera Roja (C/0730/16, 31 March
2016).
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
154
Horizontal theories of harm: Through the acquisition, MIH would go from only having
an indirect presence in Spain through its minority stake in Glovo to occupying an
important market share with Just Eat. This could lead to an incentive for MIH to prevent
Glovo’s expansion. In addition, MIH’s stakes in Glovo and Just Eat could also facilitate
coordination amongst these competitors.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Conditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: In order to address the authority’s competition concerns relating to non-
coordinated and coordinated effects, MIH proposed the following commitments: (1) MIH
would not obtain access to commercially sensitive information of either Delivery Hero or
Glovo; (2) MIH would not be able to influence Glovo’s strategy in markets where it
competes (or may compete) with Just Eat in Spain; (3) Delivery Hero (and Glovo) would
not be able to access commercially sensitive information of Just Eat. These commitments
would be binding for three years.
Noteworthy: Following on the heels of Just Eat’s acquisition of Canary Delivery, this
hostile takeover did not succeed as only an insignificant number of Just Eat shareholders
took MIH up on its final offer.
55
(46) Spain: Turnitin/Ouriginal Group (19 October 2021)
NCA: Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia
Case number: C/1220/21
Concentration: Turnitin, an international provider of a wide range of software solutions
for the educational sector, wanted to acquire sole control over the Swedish Ouriginal
Group, which is only active on the market for plagiarism detection software.
Horizontal theories of harm: Following the acquisition, the merged entity would obtain
a market share of 50-60% on the Spanish market for anti-plagiarism software, with an
increase of 0-10% due to the acquisition. The next biggest competitor, Blackboard, had a
market share of 10-20%. On a European scale, however, Blackboard was the market
leader (20-30%), with Grammarly and the merged entity each having a market share of
about 10-20%. The authority found that a number of factors mitigated the risk of anti-
competitive effects, including the small size of the national market, the possibility of a
supranational market and the presence of competitors both in Spain and in the EEA
where they had a larger market share. Also, the market share of Ouriginal both in Spain
and in the EEA was small, meaning that the additional market share gained by Turnitin
through the was is small. The authority also considered that this was an expanding market
without significant barriers to entry apart from the necessary investment to develop a
database. The Spanish authority also considered that the recent and successful market
entry by Google and Microsoft would exert competitive pressure on the merged entity.
55
‘Prosus Statement: Lapse of the Offer for Just Eat plc By Prosus N.V. Through Its Wholly-owned Indirect
Subsidiary MIH Food Delivery Holdings B.V.’ Businesswire.com (10 January 2020)
<https://www.businesswire.com/news/home/20200110005400/en/Prosus-Statement-Lapse-of-the-Offer-
for-Just-Eat-plc-By-Prosus-N.V.-Through-Its-Wholly-owned-Indirect-Subsidiary-MIH-Food-Delivery-
Holdings-B.V.>.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
155
Non-horizontal theories of harm: Although Ouriginal offered its product to third parties
so they could incorporate it into their integrated offerings, in the light of its low market
shares the authority considered that there was no risk of foreclosure effects due to the
merger. In the same vein, the authority did not consider conglomerate effects to arise.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Noteworthy: The acquisition was also cleared in the UK
56
and in Australia.
57
The Spanish
authority regarded the recent market entry by Google and Microsoft as important
competitive pressure on the merged entity.
(47) Sweden: Swedbank Franchise/Svensk Fastighetsförmedling (16 December 2014)
58
NCA: Stockholms tingsrätt
Case number: T 3629-14
Concentration: Swedbank Franchise acquired Svensk Fastighetsförmedling, a real estate
agency. Swedbank Franchise’s subsidiary, Fastighetsbyrån, and Svensk
Fastighetsförmedling were the two most important players on the Swedish real estate
market and each others closest competitors. The dominant platform for real estate online
advertisements, Hemnet, was owned by Fastighetsbyrån (25%), Svensk
Fastighetsförmedling (25%) and two associations of real estate agents, where
Fastighetsbyrån and Svensk Fastighetsförmedling were members of one of them.
Horizontal theories of harm: The acquisition would create a dominant position on real
estate agency services in a large number of local markets in Sweden and result in a
significant impediment of competition. This aspect is not further analysed here.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: After the acquisition, Swedbank Franchise would
directly and indirectly (via one of the associations) strengthen its influence over Hemnet.
Swedbank Franchise would be able to change Hemnet’s business model. Not only did
Hemnet have high market shares, but it was also an unavoidable trading partner. Barriers
to entry for potential competitors were high, as Hemnet was owned by real estate agents
themselves and they would thus have no incentive to support a new platform. Hemnet
would have the ability and incentive to engage in input foreclosure vis-à-vis competing
real estate agents, eg by extracting monopoly profits or by engaging in price
differentiation. As Hemnet would strengthen its dominant position, the authority
concluded that this would significantly impede effective competition.
Outcome: Prohibited.
Remedies: Divestiture.
Noteworthy: Based on an application from the Swedish authority (Konkurrensverket),
the Stockholm District Court prohibited the concentration.
Because the individual turnover thresholds were not met, the concentration had not been
notified prior to its implementation. Later, a voluntary notification was submitted.
56
Competition & Markets Authority, Turnitin/Ouriginal (ME/6931/21, 26 July 2021).
57
Australian Competition and Consumer Commission, Turnitin/Ouriginal Group (25 November 2021).
58
This summary is based on Peter Forsberg, Xandra Carlsson and Sebastian Wiik, ‘Sweden, Overview of
merger control activity during the last 12 months’ in Nigel Parr and Catherine Hammon (eds), Merger
Control (5th edn, 2016) 191, 194-195; Björn Lundqvist, ‘Sweden’ in Daniel Mândrescu (ed), EU
Competition Law and the Digital Economy: Protecting Free and Fair Competition in an Age of
Technological (R)Evolution (XXIX FIDE Congress 2020) 517, 517-518.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
156
This was the first time a Swedish court prohibited a merger. While the parties initially
appealed the Stockholm District Court’s judgment before the Market Court, they
subsequently withdrew their appeal.
(48) Sweden: Hemnet/Blocket (2016)
59
NCA: Konkurrensverket
Case number: 84/2016
Concentration: Blocket, Sweden’s largest online marketplace that was also active in
digital property listings, wanted to buy Hemnet, the by far largest player in digital
property listings.
Horizontal theories of harm: As Blocket was the second largest player in digital
property listings and Hemnet’s only credible competitor , this proposed acquisition
was thought to give rise to horizontal unilateral effects through the creation of a single
major player on this market. The authority was concerned this would lead not only to
higher prices for digital property listings, but also to a decrease in quality of the products
and services provided and to increased barriers to entry and expansion.
Blocket pointed out that its acquisition would end the loyalty between real estate agencies
and Hemnet (on this, see the Swedbank Franchise/Svensk Fastighetsförmedling case),
60
thereby making this market considerably more competitive.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Withdrawal.
Remedies: To address concerns related to horizontal unilateral effects, Blocket proposed
to grant an exclusive license to a smaller website (Bovision) for a certain period of time,
whereby Blocket would automatically refer users that were accessing its website for
properties sold through realtors to Bovision. This would have, in the acquirer’s view,
removed the horizontal overlap between Blocket and Hemnet. As Bovision was only a
very small player, the authority did not consider this an effective remedy.
In relation to real estate agencies, the remedies proposed by Blocket involved limitations
of sellers’ commitments to future advertising on Hemnet, a time-limited price cap for
advertisements, and further commitments. As the market test was overall negative, and
the authority did not believe this to be an effective remedy, the authority moved to block
the concentration.
Noteworthy: This acquisition was abandoned when it became clear to the parties that the
authority intended to apply to the court to prohibit the concentration.
(49) United Kingdom: Betfair Group/Paddy Power (17 December 2015)
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6572/15
59
This summary is based on Sweden, ‘Agency decision-making in merger cases: from a prohibition
decision to a conditional clearance’ (3 November 2016) DAF/COMP/WP3/WD(2016)70, 4-5; Sweden,
‘Annual Report on Competition Policy Developments in Sweden’ (9 June 2017) DAF/COMP/AR(2017)16,
7; Lundqvist (n 58) 519-520.
60
Stockholms tingsrätt, Swedbank Franchise/Svensk Fastighetsförmedling (T 3629-14, 16 December
2014).
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
157
Concentration: Paddy Power, an international multi-channel betting and gaming
company with an online as well as a brick-and-mortar presence in the UK, wanted to enter
into a merger with Betfair, an international online-only gambling operator. Markets
affected included the national market for the provision of online fixed-odds betting
services, the national market for the provision of online gaming services and the at-least
national market for the supply of betting exchange data
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed whether the merger would lead to
less competitive fixed odds or prices on the market for online betting and gaming services.
For fixed-odds betting, it found that the parties were not each other’s closest competitors
and that a number of suppliers remained post-merger that would exercise a competitive
constraint on the merged entity.
For online gaming, it concluded that the merged entity’s combined share of supply would
be rather low, with at least three competitors having a higher market share, in addition to
the parties not being particularly close competitors.
Overall, the authority concluded that no horizontal unilateral effects should arise.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed whether, post-merger, the
merged entity could engage in input foreclosure related to the supply of exchange data.
However, it concluded that Betfair’s exchange data while useful did not constitute an
essential input, with plenty of alternative information sources available. Therefore, it
concluded that no vertical input foreclosure was likely to arise.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: The Competition & Markets Authority relied on Google AdWord spending
in its analysis of whether the parties were close competitors. This merger was also
unconditionally cleared by the Ireland (case M/15/059).
61
The number of operators would
be reduced from eight to seven through the merger this is often not the case when Big
Tech platforms are involved.
(50) United Kingdom: ZPG/Websky (29 June 2017)
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6690/17
Concentration: ZPG, which owns a customer relationship management (CRM) software
for real estate agents as well as the online property portal Zoopla, acquired Websky,
which runs the CRM property software Expert Agent. Markets affected included the
national market for the supply of CRM property software, the national market for the
provision of services to estate agents and consumers through property portals, and the
national market for the automatic uploading of property information to property portals.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed whether the horizontal overlap in
the provision of CRM property software could lead to competition concerns. As the
merged entity would remain subject to a sufficient number of credible and effective
competitors on that market, it concluded that no anti-competitive effects would arise. Pre-
61
Competition and Consumer Protection Commission, Paddy Power/Betfair (M/15/059, 15 January 2016).
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
158
merger, the CRM property software offered by the parties was not in particularly close
competition due to the differentiated nature of the offerings.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed whether the merged entity
could engage in input foreclosure of property portals in the vertical relationship between
online property portals such as Zoopla (downstream) and CRM property software
(upstream). In particular, it analysed whether the merged entity could degrade the quality
of the upload feed to property portals that are competing with Zoopla. However, the
authority concluded that the merged entity would not have the ability to adopt a
foreclosure strategy vis-à-vis rival property portals due to the high number of competitors
operating on the market.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: As is pertinent in digital cases, the authority emphasised that an anti-
competitive effect didn’t necessarily need to relate to prices but could also consist in a
degradation of quality.
(51) United Kingdom: Blackbaud/Giving (8 September 2017)
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6700/17
Concentration: Blackbaud (everydayhero) was in the process of acquiring Giving
(JustGiving), both of which operated online fundraising platforms (OFPs) in the UK.
Blackbaud also provided payment services and customer relationship management
(CRM) software for non-profit organisations (NPOs).
Horizontal theories of harm: JustGiving is the UK’s leading OFP, while everydayhero
is a smaller and lesser-known OFP. The increment in market share through the merger
was limited, and everydayhero was not an important competitive constraint on
JustGiving. However, a significant number of competitors were active on the market for
direct OFPs (especially Virgin Money Giving, BT MyDonate) that would continue to
constrain the merged entity’s market power.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: In terms of conglomerate effects, the authority
assessed whether, post-merger, the merged entity could link its CRM software for NPOs
with its OFPs, thereby foreclosing competitors in CRM software for NPOs or in OFPs. It
concluded that, in general, CRM software for NPOs and OFPs were not complements and
it would be difficult for the merged entity to engage in a foreclosure strategy. Customers
did not usually buy these two products from a single source, nor at the same time.
Relating to the possibility that the merged entity could foreclose CRM competitors by
bundling its CRM and OFP offerings, the authority found that Blackbaud had previously
and unsuccessfully tried such a strategy. In addition, a discounted bundle could be pro-
competitive, as long as CRM competitors were not forced out of the market. Therefore,
the authority concluded that no conglomerate foreclosure concerns arose.
Concerning the possibility that the merged entity could foreclose CRM or OFP
competitors by reducing the quality of data integration either between competing OFPs
and Blackbaud’s CRM software or between competing CRM software and the merged
entity’s OFPs, the authority underlined that improving data integration between
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
159
Blackbaud’s CRM and its future OFPs would be pro-competitive. In addition, customers
did not choose CRM software based on how well it integrated with one tool, leading the
authority to conclude that the merged entity would not have the ability to engage in such
a foreclosure strategy.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: In the face of multiple competitors active on a relevant market, the NCA
regarded improved data integration as a pro-competitive aspect of the merger at issue.
(52) United Kingdom: Just Eat/Hungryhouse (16 November 2017)
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6659-16-II
Concentration: Just Eat, a major online food ordering platform, wanted to acquire
Hungryhouse, another online food ordering platform and subsidiary of Delivery Hero.
Such food ordering marketplaces are an intermediary between consumers and restaurants.
Horizontal theories of harm: As the market for online food ordering platforms had
become more concentrated in the years preceding the acquisition, the authority analysed
whether it might give rise to horizontal unilateral effects. The merged entity would have
a market share of 80% in UK online food ordering platforms, with an increment of under
10% due to the acquisition. However, ordering and logistics specialists also constrained
competition on that market. Already pre-merger, Hungryhouse had only posed a limited
competitive constraint on Just Eat, and had been loss-making for years. The authority also
expected this sector to be dynamic, with new competition on the horizon. Therefore, it
did not believe that horizontal unilateral effects would arise.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 2.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: Just Eat’s M&A activity also gave rise to several merger cases in Spain.
62
(53) United Kingdom: Moneysupermarket.com/Decision Technologies (7 August
2018)
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6749/18
Concentration: Moneysupermarket.com agreed to acquire Decision Technologies. Both
parties supply digital comparison tool services for mobile and home communications
switching. Decision Technologies also operates upstream, providing white label and
application programming interface (API) services to providers of digital comparison
tools.
62
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Just Eat/La Nevera Roja (C/0730/16, 31 March
2016); Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Just Eat Spain/Canary Delivery Company
(C/1046/19, 10 September 2019); Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, MIH Food
Delivery Holdings/Just Eat (C/1072/19, 5 December 2019).
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
160
Horizontal theories of harm: While this horizontal merger involved two of the more
important competitors on the market for digital comparison tool services for mobile and
home communications switching with a combined share of supply of 25-30%, a sufficient
number of competitors would remain active on that market as well as through other
switching routes that would restrain the merged entity. Also, the merging parties were not
particularly close competitors. In particular, uSwitch as the market leader for home
communications switching would continue to provide an important competitive
constraint.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed whether the merged entity
might engage in a vertical input foreclosure strategy by foreclosing the supply of white
label and API services for the use by digital comparison tool providers. White label
services were considered an important input. However, such a strategy could lead to
switching away from the merged entity but also to a revenue gain for the merged entity
where customers switch to the merged entity’s own digital comparison tool. While a
number of alternative white label service providers operate on the market, Decision
Technologies was the market leader and no entry was on the horizon, meaning that it had
at least some ability to engage in such a foreclosure strategy. The authority then assessed
a number of factors that would curtail the merged entity’s incentive to foreclose, and
found that this strategy would not be profitable. For this reason, it concluded that no
competition concern would arise based on vertical input foreclosure.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
(54) United Kingdom: eBay/Motors.co.uk (12 February 2019)
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6774/18
Concentration: eBay agreed to acquire Motors.co.uk. Both parties supply online
classified vehicle advertising services. eBay has two brands dedicated to this business:
eBay Motors and Gumtree Motors.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed possible horizontal unilateral
issues. It found that although the merging parties offered relatively similar online
classified vehicle advertising services, they were not each other’s closest competitors. In
addition, there was only a limited increment in the merged entity’s market position
through the merger. Autotrader was a closer competitor that constrained both parties, and
CarGurus had been gaining market share and competed aggressively. Overall, this led the
authority conclude that no competition concerns would arise.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: In terms of the closeness of competition, it is possible that a number of
digital merger cases underestimate the network effects and the impact of digital
ecosystems on this analysis.
(55) United Kingdom: PayPal/iZettle (12 June 2019)
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
161
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6766/18-II
Concentration: PayPal, a technology platform company that provides online and offline
payment services, acquired iZettle, a financial technology company providing (primarily
offline, but to a limited extent also online) payment services to small businesses. In the
UK, the companies overlapped in the provision of offline payment services through
mobile point of sale (mPOS) services, a relatively new technology that involves a card
reader and an app that allows merchants to accept card payments.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority underlined that mPOS was a fast-moving
and dynamic market in which a particular emphasis had to be put on future competition.
However, it also found that traditional point of sale providers significantly constrained
mPOS providers, and that there were a whole range of such competitors (including
Worldpay, Barclaycard, Shopify). Also, two further major providers of mPOS (Square,
SumUp) continued to operate on the market.
The authority also considered whether iZettle would have developed an omni-channel
offer competing with PayPal’s service, leading to a situation in which potential
competition was eliminated. It concluded, however, that absent the merger, iZettle was
likely to have focused on its core business rather than on developing an omni-channel
service.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
(56) United Kingdom: Salesforce.com/Tableau Software (22 November 2019)
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6841/19
Concentration: Salesforce acquired Tableau Software. Both parties supply business
intelligence (BI) software, and in particular modern BI software making use of artificial
intelligence and business analytics. Salesforce also offers a customer relationship
management (CRM) platform that integrates with third-party products.
Horizontal theories of harm: As the parties were not close competitors, and a number
of BI suppliers remained on the market that would exert a competitive constraint on the
merged entity, the authority did not think that any horizontal unilateral effects would
arise.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed two conglomerate theories of
harm related to foreclosure. First of all, it assessed whether the merged entity could
foreclose competing BI software providers through technical restrictions or
bundling/tying of CRM products with BI products. While the merged entity could have
the ability to pursue such a foreclosure strategy, there was no incentive to do so. Second,
the authority considered whether the merged entity could foreclose competing CRM
software providers through technical restrictions or bundling/tying of BI products with
CRM products. The authority emphasised that a BI tool was more valuable when it
connected to multiple data sources, and in any case the costs would outweigh the benefits
for the merged entity.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
162
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: In Austria, Salesforce was fined €100,000 for gun jumping in the same
merger case.
63
Considering the integration or improvement of interoperability within a
merged entity’s services, the issue regularly arises that such behaviour can prove pro-
competitive, while at the same time further entrenching a dominant company’s market
power. Here it appears that competition authorities are called upon to make a nearly
impossible choice. Further research into this issue is required.
(57) United Kingdom: Tobii/Smartbox (15 August 2019)
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6780/18-II
Concentration: Tobii had acquired Smartbox Assistive Technology and Sensory
Software International (together: Smartbox). Both produce augmentative assistive
communication (AAC) solutions, i.e., communication aids for those that find
communication difficult, eg due to a disability or a medical condition. AAC solutions
consist of AAC hardware, AAC software, access means (e.g., a switch, an eye gaze
camera), and customer support. Markets affected included the national market for supply
of dedicated AAC solutions, the global market for upstream supply of AAC software and
the equally global market for upstream supply of eye gaze cameras in AAC.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority considered that the main horizontal overlap
between acquirer and target occurred in the supply of dedicated AAC solutions. It did not
accept the argument that the providers faced strong competition from AAC solutions
based on mainstream consumer devices because this was not consistent with its market
analysis nor with internal documents of the parties outlining their competition. Prices for
dedicated AAC solutions had remained constant over preceding years, and qualitative
evidence also pointed to a lack of such competition.
The authority assessed the possibility of horizontal unilateral effects, particularly as
regards price increases, quality deterioration and a reduction in the range of services
and/or product development. It emphasised that, pre-merger, the parties had been close
competitors and competition among them had led to increased innovation and R&D. The
closeness of competition was also supported by diversion ratios between Tobii and
Smartbox products. The merged entity now had a market share of 60-70% in the UK and
competitors did not provide a sufficient constraint on the merged entity. The authority
emphasised that part of the merger strategy was indeed to reduce the range of products
available as well as R&D.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed three vertical theories of harm
relating to possible foreclosure effects.
Concerning a possible input foreclosure of Smartbox’s Grid software, the authority found
that the merged entity would likely have both the ability and incentive to rely on its strong
market position in AAC software in order to foreclose downstream competitors, eg by
making their access to its popular software more expensive or of lower quality. This is
63
Kartellgericht, 22 April 2021, 27 Kt 9/21g Tableau/Salesforce.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
163
enabled by downstream competitors being unable to switch away from Smartbox’s
software due to consumer demand. The merger, according to the authority, increased the
incentive to engage in such a foreclosure strategy. This would, in the end, harm consumers
and end users.
Relating to a possible customer foreclosure of competitors to Tobii’s eye gaze camera,
the authority found that the merged entity would likely have both the ability and incentive
to limit the compatibility of eye gaze cameras produced by competitors with Smartbox’s
software. This strategy would be profitable, as dedicated AAC solution providers were
not very likely to switch to an alternative software in order to use an alternative eye gaze
camera. This foreclosure strategy would lead to lower innovation in eye gaze cameras
and higher prices, and thus affect AAC solutions overall.
Finally, the authority assessed possible input foreclosure of Tobii’s eye gaze cameras but
found that it was unlikely that the merged entity would make access to Tobii’s eye gaze
cameras more expensive, because of alternatives available on the market. There would
also be a lack of incentives for such a strategy, as this might lead to switching to
alternative eye gaze cameras rather than switching to the merged entity’s dedicated AAC
solutions.
The authority emphasised that the market was not very dynamic, with no evidence of
recent successful entry or expansion and buyer power not very strong.
Outcome: Prohibited in phase 2.
Remedies: Tobii had proposed two different sets of remedies to the authority, with a
structural element to address the horizontal competition concerns and a behavioural
element to address the vertical competition concerns. Concerning the structural element,
Tobii proposed to divest Smartbox’s AAC hardware business (partial divestiture) and to
keep Smartbox’s AAC software business, while granting the buyer a perpetual license for
Smartbox’s popular software on FRAND terms as well as allowing it to resell Tobii’s eye
gaze cameras. However, the authority concluded that these would not effectively address
the competition concerns it had identified, based on a risk framework including
specification risks, circumvention risks, distortion risks and monitoring and enforcement
risks. Based thereon, the authority concluded that the proposed remedies would not fully
address these risks and would only have a limited impact in addressing the competition
concerns identified. Full divestiture was regarded as the only effective remedy available.
Noteworthy: In case 1332/4/12/19, the Competition Appeal Tribunal upheld the
Competition and Markets Authority’s divestiture decision on all but one ground.
64
In
particular, the Competition Appeal Tribunal agreed with Tobii that the authority had not
provided sufficient evidential basis for its concern relating to partial input foreclosure. In
another judgment, Tobii was not granted permission to appeal that decision.
65
Tobii has
since divested Smartbox.
66
64
Tobii/Smartbox, [2020] CAT 1, 10 January 2020.
65
Tobii/Smartbox, [2020] CAT 6, 17 February 2020.
66
‘Tobii divests Smartbox’ (6 October 2020) <https://www.tobii.com/group/news-media/press-
releases/2020/10/tobii-divests-smartbox/>.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
164
The relevant market underlying the authority’s analysis is noteworthy, as the authority
considered both a cluster market (dedicated AAC solutions) as well as the individual
components of the latter.
(58) United Kingdom: Google/Looker (13 February 2020)
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6839/19
Concentration: Google, a global technology company, acquired Looker, a provider of
business intelligence (BI) tools, ie software that supports corporate decision-making by
analysing, visualising and interpreting business data. Google operates both GDS, a free
BI tool that is interoperable with Google’s many products and services, and GBQ, a
cloud-based data warehouse. Google’s products are not currently interoperable with
leading rival data warehouses (e.g., provided by Amazon, Microsoft, Oracle, Snowflake
and others). Looker’s BI tools interoperate with over 45 data warehouses.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed whether the loss of competition by
an actual competitor would raise competition concerns. It found that the market for BI
tools was very competitive and dynamic, and customers tended to multi-home. In
addition, the merged entity had a low combined share of supply, with customers not
regarding GDS as a viable alternative to Looker. Post-merger, there were also significant
competitive constraints present on the market. The authority concluded that the merger
did not raise competitive concerns in this regard.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed whether the merged entity
could engage in a partial foreclosure strategy based on Google’s substantial market power
in web analytics and online advertising. As Google generates a wealth of data, the
authority assessed whether Google could restrict competing BI tool providers from access
to Google-generated data. It found that Google would indeed have the ability to engage
in such an input foreclosure strategy: it is important to many businesses to be able to
analyse Google-generated data, Google has market power in web analytics and online
advertising and can offer a combined product (possibly further enhancing its market
power), and it could implement various price- and non-price-based foreclosure
mechanisms to restrict access to Google-generated data. However, the authority did not
consider that Google had an incentive to engage in such a strategy, and its internal
documents did not reveal any plans to carry out such a strategy. Switching by customers
may to some extent hamper the profitability of such a strategy. Targeting individual
competing BI tools with such a strategy would also be costly.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: The Competition & Markets Authority investigated a number of mergers in
business intelligence tools, including Salesforce/Tableau Software (2019)
67
and
Google/Looker (2020). This could indicate an ongoing concentration of this market.
(59) United Kingdom: Sabre/Farelogix (9 April 2020)
67
Competition & Markets Authority, Salesforce.com/Tableau Software (ME/6841/19, 22 November 2019).
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
165
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6806/19-II
Concentration: Sabre, a US company providing technology solutions to airlines and
travel agents, intended to acquire Farelogix, another US company supplying technology
solutions for airlines.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed whether the acquisition would raise
horizontal unilateral effects in the supply of merchandising solutions or distribution
solutions to airlines. Issues raised included slower rates of innovation and product
development, reduced product range or quality, and higher prices or less favourable terms
of service.
While Farelogix was a strong player in merchandising solutions for airlines, Sabre was
not (yet). However, the authority considered that Sabre would become a strong competitor
absent the acquisition. Post-merger, only one strong competitor would remain, namely
Amadeus. The loss of competition resulting from the acquisition would be significant.
As regarded distribution solutions for airlines, the authority noted that the product
offerings by the merging parties were differentiated, and that there were several
competitors that posed a credible competitive constraint. Overall, however, it concluded
that Farelogix would play an important role in that market absent the merger, and the loss
of competition resulting from the acquisition would be significant, with a substantial and
long-lasting impact on consumers.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Prohibited in phase 2.
Remedies: The parties offered commitments to the authority, which included (i) making
Farelogix’s FLX Services available at the same or lower prices to those at the time,
including levels of support, for an agreed-upon period of time, (ii) offering all current
Sabre GDS
68
customers and all current FLX OC customers the opportunity to extend their
existing contract on the same terms for a period of at least three years, (iii) to continue
investing in the development of FLX Services capabilities at levels no less than current
levels, for an agreed-upon period of time, and (iv) to continue to offer and support FLX
Services capabilities to any third parties and all outlets that wish to use them to connect
to Sabre, other GDSs, other distribution partners, or directly to travel agents on an
agnostic basis, for an agreed-upon period of time.
The authority concluded, however, that the parties’ remedies proposal did not manage to
weigh up the loss of competition that would result from Farelogix no longer being an
independent player that competes to meet airlines’ evolving needs. It thus regarded the
prohibition of the merger as the only effective remedy.
Noteworthy: The Competition Appeal Tribunal dismissed Sabre’s appeal of the
decision.
69
As a result of this case, the merger was terminated on 1 May 2020.
70
In the
United States, the Department of Justice equally sought to prohibit the merger and called
it ‘a dominant firm’s attempt to eliminate a disruptive competitor after years of trying to
68
Global Distribution System.
69
Sabre/Farelogix, [2021] CAT 11, 21 May 2021.
70
Sabre and Farelogix $360m merger deal cancelled’ (1 May 2020) <https://www.phocuswire.com/sabre-
farelogix-merger-terminated>.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
166
stamp it out.’
71
While this case was cleared by a US District Court in a rather controversial
judgment,
72
the case was subsequently vacated because the parties had abandoned their
merger.
73
(60) United Kingdom: Amazon/Roofoods (4 August 2020)
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6836/19-II
Concentration: Amazon wanted to acquire a 16% minority shareholding and certain
rights (including board representation) in Roofoods, which operates restaurant delivery
platform Deliveroo. This transaction occurred on the national market for the supply of
online restaurant platforms. The authority did not consider Deliveroo to be a failing firm.
Horizontal theories of harm: Following a referral for further investigation, the authority
mainly considered horizontal effects that could arise in the form of a loss of potential
competition as a result of the transaction. It emphasised that Amazon had previously had
a market presence in online restaurant platforms in the UK (2016-2018). The authority
assessed whether it would be likely absent the transaction that Amazon would re-enter
that market. It indicated that Amazon’s global strategy to promote and grow Prime could
fit with re-entering this market. Internal documents showed that Amazon regards
restaurant delivery as an integral part of its food strategy. The authority concluded that
this indicated a strong and continued interest by Amazon in the online restaurant
platforms market, in which it could benefit from its vast logistics expertise. Amazon could
either build its own offering, acquire or invest in an existing platform, or partner with one.
The authority then asked whether Amazon would be likely to re-enter the market in the
absence of the merger, and whether such entry would lead to greater competition. The
fact that Amazon would only acquire a 16% shareholding in Deliveroo, rather than a
larger stake, was particularly emphasised. Two scenarios were assessed by the authority:
Concerning (i) unilateral effects on the entry decision, the authority concluded that based
on mixed evidence it was not sufficiently likely that Amazon’s 16% stake in Deliveroo
would keep it from re-entering the market in the face of strong financial incentives to do
so. Regarding (ii) post-entry unilateral effects, the authority considered what could occur
should Amazon re-enter the market. While Amazon could adopt a strategy to compete
less aggressively to internalise Deliveroo’s profits, the authority concluded that the 16%
stake in Deliveroo would not provide a strong enough incentive for this theory of harm
to be credible or to influence market outcomes. Also, Amazon could encourage Deliveroo
to compete less aggressively against it. However, the authority considered that there was
71
Sabre/Farelogix, Complaint in Case 1:19-cv-01548-UNA (20 August 2019).
72
US v Sabre/Farelogix, 452 F. Supp. 3d 97 (D. Del. 2020). That court applied two-sided market theory in
a way that does not correspond to market realities (see p 136), holding that two-sided platforms cannot
compete with one-sided market offerings based on Ohio v American Express, 138 S. Ct. 2274, 2285 (2018).
73
As the Department of Justice explained when asking the US Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit to
vacate the District Court judgment, it also did so because that judgment’s pronouncements regarding
competition among one- and two-sided businesses would have too much of a bearing on future antitrust
cases; US Department of Justice’s Motion to Vacate, Case No. 20-1767 (12 May 2020). The District Court’s
judgment was vacated on 20 July 2020.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
167
strong competition between Deliveroo, Uber Eats and Just Eat, limiting Deliveroo’s scope
to compete less vigorously.
The authority also considered possible horizontal unilateral effects in the supply of online
convenience grocery (OCG) shopping. The authority considered the offerings by Amazon
and Deliveroo in OCG to be quite differentiated, and also listed a range of competitors
on that market, including online restaurant delivery providers (e.g., Just Eat, Uber Eats),
traditional grocers and convenience stores (e.g., Waitrose, Sainsbury’s, Co-op), as well
as grocery delivery specialists (e.g., Ocado). Further expansion was to be expected, also
against the background of Covid-19. As a first theory of harm, it assessed (i) Amazon’s
ability to discourage Deliveroo from competing against Amazon in OCG. It then asked
(ii) whether Amazon could protect its investment by avoiding direct competition with
Deliveroo in OCG. In both cases, it concluded that while Amazon would have material
influence on Deliveroo, its 16% stake would not allow it to set Deliveroo’s policies single-
handedly, and outside competition would constrain it in doing so. Finally, the authority
assessed (iii) whether Amazon could rely on Deliveroo for its presence in OCG rather
than developing its own service. Here, it was also considered that Amazon might regard
the transaction as a first step towards full acquisition of the target. Viewed within the
broader context of the OCG market, the authority concluded that other competitors were
well-placed to compete in the OCG market and no substantiated competition concerns
would arise.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: Already in phase 1, the authority had dismissed a
possible bundling of Amazon Prime and Deliveroo Plus, ie the latter’s subscription
service, as there would be no sufficient incentive to do so.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 2.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: This is a rare case in which the authority assessed whether the loss of
potential competition could lead to competition concerns. It was primarily due to the low
stake of 16% that the concerns were dismissed. The case is a good indication that in the
case of platform mergers that involve an important ecosystem orchestrator, attention also
needs to be paid to (even loosely) connected markets (potentially) served by the digital
ecosystem in question.
(61) United Kingdom: Pug/StubHub (2 February 2021)
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6868/19-II
Concentration: Pugnacious Endeavors, which trades as viagogo, is a global provider of
online exchange platforms for buying and selling tickets to live events. It acquired
StubHub, which is owned by eBay, and is a global provider of online exchange platforms
for buying and selling tickets to live events; it is the largest secondary ticketing platform
in the world.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority focused on horizontal effects between two
close competitors that made up between 90-100% of the relevant market post-merger.
The merger resulted in an increment in the range of 30-40%. While viagogo had high
market shares for a number of consecutive years, StubHub had shown strong growth in
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
168
previous years. There was no meaningful competitor on the market for secondary
ticketing platform services in the UK. The platforms operated in similar ways, and
invested heavily in advertising. viagogo was found to bid ‘on a sizeable proportion of
StubHub’s keywords’, indicating close competition among them. Resellers regarded the
parties as substitutes, and regularly multi-homed. Ticketing platforms on the primary
market, such as Ticketmaster, were not regarded as a viable alternative in many instances,
and therefore did not constitute a competitive constraint. Neither non-specialist online
channels nor social media or offline channels were regarded as viable alternatives to
secondary ticketing platforms.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Conditionally cleared in phase 2.
Remedies: The authority required a partial divestiture of StubHub, namely of the
StubHub International business (ie, StubHub outside of North America). This was
regarded as the only effective remedy for this completed transaction.
Noteworthy: The authority considered advertising spend on a competitor’s keywords to
assess closeness of competition. StubHub International was subsequently acquired by
Digital Fuel Capital.
74
(62) United Kingdom: Adevinta/eBay Classifieds Group (16 February 2021)
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6897/20
Concentration: Adevinta agreed to acquire the eBay Classifieds Group (eCG) from
eBay, while eBay agreed to acquire 33.3% of voting rights (44% of economic interest) in
Adevinta. Schibsted was the majority shareholder in Adevinta; its voting rights would be
reduced to 39.5% post-merger (33.1% of economic interest). Adevinta provides online
classified advertising services (Shpock; MB Diffusion). eCG provides online classified
advertising services (Gumtree; Motors.co.uk), and eBay operates the online marketplace
eBay.co.uk. The merger affected the markets for the supply of online generalist classified
advertising services and C2C online marketplaces and the market for the supply of online
classified advertising platforms and online marketplaces for motor vehicles, among
others. The authority found that generalist online classified advertising services (such as
Adevinta’s Shpock and eCG’s Gumtree) were in the same relevant market as online
marketplaces (e.g., eBay Marketplace).
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority was concerned that the merger would lead
to a substantial lessening of competition due to horizontal unilateral effects, risking less
choice and innovation as well as higher fees. It found eBay Marketplace to be the largest
platform on the market, over twice the size of its next biggest competitor (ie, Facebook
Marketplace). Gumtree was third or fourth (depending on the metric), while Shpock was
relatively small but had recently increased its competitive constraint on eBay
Marketplace. The parties’ platforms were close competitors (either actual or potential).
74
Competition & Markets Authority, ‘Merger investigation into the Completed acquisition by PUG LLC
(viagogo) of the StubHub business of eBay Inc.’ (8 September 2021)
<https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/media/61379adfe90e07044435c8d0/Viagogo_StubHub_Case_cl
osure_summary.pdf>.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
169
The authority also found that under eBay’s ownership, Gumtree had not competed as
aggressively as it could have. It reasoned that part of eBay’s motivation to sell Gumtree
to Adevinta consisted in eBay continuing to exercise some influence on that platform.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Conditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: In order to address the horizontal unilateral theories of harm identified by the
authority, the parties proposed the following commitments: (i) divestiture of Gumtree UK
(incl Motor.co.uk) on a debt-free basis, (ii) divestiture of Shpock to RussMedia Equity
Partners on a debt-free basis, (iii) provision of transitional services in relation to Shpock
and Gumtree UK. The authority accepted these commitments.
Noteworthy: This concentration was also cleared subject to conditions in Austria,
75
although the conditions due to different online classified advertising platforms
operating on that geographic market were different. Germany unconditionally cleared
this transaction.
76
(63) United Kingdom: Uber International/GPC Computer Software (29 March 2021)
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6903/20
Concentration: Uber, a provider of ride-hailing services, wanted to acquire GPC
Computer Software (Autocab), a company that (i) develops and supplies booking and
dispatch technology (BDT) enabling taxi companies to connect drivers to end customers,
and that (ii) operates the iGo network that connects demand for taxi trips with supply for
taxi trips.
Horizontal theories of harm: At the time of the proposed merger, Uber and Autocab
only competed to a limited extent. The authority assessed a loss of competition between
the merging parties in the supply of BDT services and referral networks, particularly with
a view to future potential competition. However, Autocab was unlikely to develop a
stand-alone consumer-facing app that would directly compete with Uber’s app. It was
also unlikely that iGo would grow to become a significant competitor to Uber. Overall,
the authority concluded that horizontal competition would not be substantially lessened
due to the merger.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: Under a vertical foreclosure theory of harm, the
authority assessed whether the quality of Autocab’s BDT and iGo services may decline
post-merger, thereby putting taxi companies and aggregators using Autocab’s services
(i.e., downstream competitors) at a disadvantage. The authority found that a quality
degradation by Autocab would need to be significant in order to cause customers to switch
to competitors (such as Uber). As there were enough BDT providers operating on the
market, taxi companies could switch to those, with relatively low switching costs.
Regarding iGo, the merged entity would not have the ability to foreclose aggregators
(e.g., travel companies, emergency transport companies) because there were a number of
alternatives present on the market and these aggregators already multi-homed.
75
Bundeswettbewerbsbehörde, eBay/Adevinta (BWB/Z-5141, Z-5142, Z-5420 and Z-5421, 18 June 2021).
76
Bundeskartellamt, Adevinta/eBay Classifieds Group (B6-41/20, 23 November 2020).
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
170
In terms of further vertical non-coordinated effects, the authority also assessed whether
the acquisition would give Uber access to commercially sensitive information about
competitors that would allow it to compete more aggressively. The authority considered
that more intense competition would, in fact, be beneficial. In addition, competing taxi
companies could switch to other BDT providers in such a case.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
(64) United Kingdom: SK hynix/Intel (28 June 2021)
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6913/20
Concentration: SK hynix, a multinational active in the design and manufacturing of
semiconductor products, wanted to acquire sole control of the NAND
77
and SSD
78
business of Intel.
Horizontal theories of harm: SK hynix’s business includes the design and manufacture
of NAND flash memory, NAND-based SSDs and managed NAND products. It overlaps
with Intel’s business in this respect. Therefore, the authority assessed whether horizontal
unilateral effects would arise in one of the two markets affected due to the acquisition.
SK hynix holds investments in Kioxia, which also manufactures NAND and SSDs. The
authority concluded, however, that this has not softened competition in the past.
In 3D NAND, the authority found that the acquisition would reduce the number of
competitors from 6 to 5, meaning that a number of credible competitors would continue
to exercise a competitive constraint on the merged entity. The merged entity would have
a market share of 20-30%. Pre-merger, the parties were not particularly close competitors.
In enterprise SSDs, the merged entity would have a market share of 30-40%, with 4 bigger
and a number of smaller competitors remaining active on the market. Again, the parties
were not particularly close competitors. The authority also noted the buyer power present
in that market.
The authority concluded that no horizontal unilateral effects were likely to arise post-
merger.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: This acquisition was also cleared in the EU.
79
(65) United Kingdom: Advanced Micro Devices/Xilinx (29 June 2021)
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6915/20
77
NAND is a type of flash memory.
78
Solid-state drive.
79
European Commission Decision of 20 May 2021, M.10059 SK Hynix/Intel’s NAND and SSD Business.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
171
Concentration: Advanced Micro Devices (AMD), a global semiconductor company
supplying central processing units (CPUs), agreed to acquire Xilinx, another global
semiconductor company supplying field programmable gate arrays (FPGAs).
Horizontal theories of harm: NA
Non-horizontal theories of harm: As there was no horizontal overlap, the authority
considered conglomerate effects. Given that the merged entity would have a strong
market position in FPGAs for datacentre applications, the authority assessed whether the
merged entity could engage in a foreclosure strategy by bundling or tying the sale of
FPGAs with the sale of its CPUs for datacentre services. It found, however, that the
merged entity would not have the ability or incentive to foreclose datacentre CPU
suppliers, as datacentre CPUs are mostly not bought together with datacentre FPGAs.
Given the merged entity’s strong market position in FPGAs for embedded applications,
the authority also assessed whether the merged entity could foreclose competitors
supplying CPUs for embedded applications through linking sales. Again, it concluded
that embedded CPUs and FPGAs were not usually used together, meaning no anti-
competitive outcome was to be expected.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: This acquisition was also cleared in China,
80
the EU
81
and Singapore.
82
(66) United Kingdom: Turnitin/Ouriginal (26 July 2021)
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6931/21
Concentration: Turnitin, an international provider of a wide range of software solutions
for the educational sector, wanted to acquire sole control over the Swedish Ouriginal
Group, which is only active on the market for plagiarism detection software. The authority
considered the affected market to be the national market for the supply of anti-plagiarism
software to higher education customers.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority found that the parties involved were close
competitors, with the acquirer being the target’s main competitive constraint. The parties
also had a very high aggregate share of supply (90%), with few additional competitors on
the market. The additional market share gained by the acquirer would not be high,
however. The authority noted that Google and Microsoft had recently entered the market.
Overall, the authority considered that there was a realistic prospect the merger would lead
to a significant lessening of competition.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: NA
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
80
State Administration for Market Regulation, Advanced Micro Devices/Xilinx (27 January 2022). In
China, the acquisition was cleared in phase 2 subject to conditions.
81
European Commission Decision of 30 June 2021, COMP/M.10097 Advanced Micro Devices/Xilinx.
82
Competition and Consumer Commission of Singapore, Advanced Micro Devices/Xilinx
(400/140/2021/003, 30 August 2021).
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
172
Noteworthy: This merger was also cleared in Spain
83
and Australia.
84
While the Spanish
authority had considered entry barriers to be low in this market, the UK authority believed
they were high. The Competition & Markets Authority could not rule out that competition
would be harmed based on horizontal unilateral effects, but relied on the de minimis
exception in this case.
(67) United Kingdom: Meta/Kustomer (27 September 2021)
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6920/20
Concentration: Global technology company Meta (formerly: Facebook) intended to
acquire Kustomer, the provider of a software as a service (SaaS) customer relationship
management (CRM) software that can be used for business to consumer (B2C)
communications. Markets affected included not only the market for the supply of B2C
communication via messaging channels but also the market for service and support
related to CRM software and the market for online display advertising.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed whether Meta’s data advantage in
online display advertising would be strengthened based on the merger, leading to higher
barriers to entry and expansion and reduced competition. While the authority emphasised
Meta’s competitive advantage due to its access to data, and while it acknowledged that
the merger would increase that advantage, it also underlined that additional data gains
through Kustomer would be small and wouldn’t raise competition concerns. The authority
also pointed to the possibility for competitors to access data similar to the one Meta would
gain through the acquisition.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: Related to a possible vertical input foreclosure, the
authority assessed whether Meta could foreclose other providers of CRM software by
limiting or degrading their access to Meta’s messaging channels. This is because CRM
providers require Meta APIs to integrate them into their software. While Meta would have
the ability to engage in such foreclosure, the authority did not believe that it had a
sufficient incentive for this strategy. B2C messaging is growing, and such a foreclosure
strategy would cut Meta off from revenue-generating CRM providers, as not all customers
would switch to relatively small Kustomer. This was therefore not seen as a credible
theory of harm.
Under a further possible theory of harm related to vertical customer foreclosure, the
authority assessed whether Meta could foreclose other B2C messaging services by
preventing them from integrating their services with Kustomer. As Kustomer is a small
provider specialised in serving small and medium-sized businesses, this was not seen as
a credible theory of harm.
Finally, under a conglomerate theory of harm, the authority also considered whether Meta
could cross-subsidise a free(mium) version of Kustomer with profits from online display
advertising, thereby foreclosing competing CRM providers. This would fit within Meta’s
83
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, Turnitin/Ouriginal Group (C/1220/21, 19
October 2021).
84
Australian Competition and Consumer Commission, Turnitin/Ouriginal Group (25 November 2021).
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
173
overall business strategy, and it would have both the ability and incentive to do so.
However, the authority concluded that this would not have a negative impact on
competition. While some competitors may be hard-hit by such a strategy, CRM providers
compete on more than just price and the authority concluded that there would remain
sufficient competition on that market even if such a conglomerate foreclosure strategy
were to be adopted.
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Remedies: NA
Noteworthy: This case was equally cleared subject to conditions by the European
Commission,
85
while the German Bundeskartellamt cleared it unconditionally.
86
The
analysis that the Competition & Markets Authority engaged in for this merger did not
follow the usual approach of horizontal/vertical/conglomerate, but instead the CMA
formulated four distinct theories of harm that reflect the specificity of digital markets
including the importance of data in these markets. This could mark the beginning of the
development of theories of harm that no longer clearly distinguish between horizontal,
vertical and conglomerate effects, but that are more closely adapted to the market realities
of digital platforms and ecosystems.
(68) United Kingdom: Auction Technology Group/Live Auctioneers (29 September
2021)
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6942/21
Concentration: Auction Technology Group (ATG) agreed to acquire Live Auctioneers.
Both operate online auction marketplaces for arts and antiques, a market which the
authority noted was national in scope because of the complexity of international
transactions in these goods.
Horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed horizontal effects related to the
provision of auction marketplaces for arts and antiques. As the acquirer was primarily
focused on UK bidders, while the target was primarily focused on North American
bidders, and they each provided different offerings to their clients, the authority found
that pre-merger they were not close competitors. It also noted competitive constraints in
the UK from two further online auction marketplaces for arts and antiques, as well as out-
of-market constraints (e.g., white label solutions). The merger would not change the
competitive dynamics on the UK market.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed conglomerate effects that may
arise if the merged entity can leverage the target’s strong market position in the US in
order to increase the number of auction houses that use ATG’s services in the UK, eg by
engaging in a bundling strategy regarding the target’s US bidder base. Based on shares of
supply, however, the authority concluded that the target did not have market power in the
US, while ATG was already an important market player in the UK and would gain little
85
European Commission Decision of 27 January 2022, M.10262 Meta/Kustomer.
86
Bundeskartellamt, Meta/Kustomer (B7-119/21, 11 February 2022).
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
174
from such a strategy. Therefore, the merged entity would only have a limited ability to
engage in such a leveraging strategy.
Remedies: NA
Outcome: Unconditionally cleared in phase 1.
Noteworthy: Despite the worldwide reach of online auction marketplaces, the authority
emphasised that the acquirer and the target were not close competitors because they each
focused on a different geographic market, due to buyer preferences but also the
complexity of international transactions in arts and antiques.
(69) United Kingdom: Meta/Giphy (6 December 2021)
NCA: Competition & Markets Authority
Case number: ME/6891/20-II
Concentration: Global technology company Meta (formerly Facebook), with strong
market positions in both social media and display advertising, acquired Giphy, the
world’s leading provider of free GIFs and GIF stickers. Markets affected included the
market for searchable GIF libraries, social media and display advertising.
Horizontal theories of harm: In terms of horizontal unilateral effects, the authority
assessed whether there would be a loss of potential competition in display advertising that
could lead to a substantial lessening of competition. While Meta is an important player in
display advertising. Giphy had recently come up with its Paid Alignment advertising
offering that allowed it to monetise its services. Through this offering, brands could raise
brand awareness, meaning this service was competing with display advertising (until
Meta terminated it upon acquisition). Giphy had plans to move into the UK market. In
light of Meta’s significant market power, the authority considered that this acquisition of
a potential competitor was significant because Giphy had the potential to compete with
Meta. Network effects in those markets and high barriers to entry were equally
considered. The authority concluded that based on the acquisition of a potential
competitor, the acquisition would substantially lessen competition.
Non-horizontal theories of harm: The authority assessed the possibility of vertical input
foreclosure of Giphy’s GIFs, thereby foreclosing competitors in social media markets.
The authority emphasised that users of social media platforms heavily relied on GIFs,
with sometimes over 25% of content including a GIF. Apart from Giphy, the only other
comparable service is Google’s Tenor. Post-merger, Meta would have the ability to
engage in input foreclosure. Based on the benefits awaiting Meta, it would also have the
incentive to do so because users wanting to use Giphy’s GIF library may very well switch
to one of the Meta platforms. Here, the authority emphasised the network effects at work.
This strategy would further strengthen Meta’s market power in social media and have a
negative impact on competition.
The authority highlighted the dynamic nature of the multi-sided markets at issue, which
meant that a lessening of competition on one market (such as social media) exacerbated
anti-competitive effects on another (such as display advertising).
Outcome: Conditionally cleared in phase 2. The decision required a full divestiture of
Giphy, thereby effectively constituting a prohibition of the completed acquisition.
Robertson, Merger review in digital and technology markets: Insights from national case law
175
Remedies: In order to address the authority’s concerns, Meta offered a number of
commitments: (i) an open access remedy relating to APIs, (ii) a commingling remedy that
would allow Giphy search results to be interspersed with results from another GIF
provider, and (iii) a white label licensing remedy to sell a white label copy of Giphy’s
content library and a license to use Giphy’s search algorithm for five years.
The authority was not satisfied with these proposed behavioural commitments as the
competition concerns that arose in this dynamic market would not be alleviated by time-
limited behavioural changes. It also highlighted a risk of Meta circumventing the
commitments, and difficulties in monitoring and enforcing.
Noteworthy: In October 2021, Meta was fined GBP 50.5million for disregarding the
freeze order imposed by the Competition & Markets Authority.
87
Meta continuously
disregarded the Competition & Markets Authority’s freeze order and was therefore
subjected to an additional fine of GBP 1.5million in February 2022.
88
This case was on
appeal before the Competition Appeal Tribunal on six grounds, of which the Tribunal
dismissed five and only upheld one in relation to a failure on the part of the UK NCA to
properly consult with the parties.
89
It now remains to be seen how the parties resolve this
issue.
90
The acquisition was conditionally cleared by Austria’s Cartel Court, where the Austrian
NCA unsuccessfully appealed the conditional clearance before the Supreme Cartel Court
in March 2022.
91
87
Competition & Markets Authority, Decision to impose a penalty on Facebook, Inc., Tabby Acquisition
Sub Inc., and Facebook UK Limited under section 94A of the Enterprise Act 2002 (20 October 2021).
88
Competition & Markets Authority, Decision to impose a penalty on Meta Platforms, Inc., Tabby
Acquisition Sub Inc., and Facebook UK Limited under section 94A of the Enterprise Act 2002 (4 February
2022).
89
Meta/Giphy, [2022] CAT 26, 14 June 2022.
90
Victoria Ibitoye, ‘Meta scores procedural win in appeal of UK Giphy selloff order, but impact remains
to be seenMLex (14 June 2022)
<https://content.mlex.com/#/content/1385154?referrer=portfolio_openrelatedcontent>.
91
Kartellgericht, 7 February 2022, 28 Kt 8/21t and 28 Kt 9/21i Meta/Giphy; Kartellobergericht, 23 June
2022, 16 Ok 3/22k and 16 Ok 4/22g Meta/Giphy.
ISBN: 978-92-76-60451-8
KD-04-22-317-EN-N
https://europa.eu/!Tc4f4Y
Competition