Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 1
Monetary and Capital Markets Department
TECHNICAL ASSISTANCE HANDBOOK
Monetary Policy Frameworks
Choice of Exchange Rate
Arrangement
Prepared by the Monetary and Macroprudential Policies Division (MCMMP)
Marco Casiraghi, Karl Habermeier, and Thomas Har
jes
DECEMBER 2022
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 2
THIS ONLINE HANDBOOK
This handbook aims to distill, document, and make widely available, the lessons learnt from Monetary
and Capital Markets Department (MCM) technical assistance (TA) over a long period while also
incorporating lessons learnt globally. It covers a wide range of central banking topics pertaining to
governance and risk management, monetary policy, monetary and foreign exchange operations, and
f inancial market development and infrastructures, while highlighting, where relevant, specific issues
for low-income resource-rich countries. It is intended to document and promote good practices and
support the consistency of advice over time. It is, however, stressed that one size solutions cannot fit
all, and all advice therefore needs to be tailored to country-specific circumstances. The handbook
comprises self-contained, issue-specific chapters with cross-references on overlapping issues where
needed. It is targeted at those who provide TA (both IMF and non-IMF personnel), and practitioners in
central banks and other relevant institutions.
THIS CHAPTER: CHOICE OF EXCHANGE RATE ARRANGEMENT
Choosing a suitable exchange rate arrangement is one of the central topics of open economy
macroeconomics. An exchange rate arrangemente.g., a free float, peg, or some intermediate form
of managed exchange rateshould be selected carefully and needs to be appropriate for a countrys
characteristics. Otherwise, it can amplify the impact of adverse shocks, impede the control of inflation,
undermine economic growth, and increase risks to financial stability. The choice of exchange rate
regime is not merely a technical matter and involves important choices in other policy areas as well.
The arrangement needs to be consistent with a country’s overall policy framework. This handbook
chapter discusses the key questions that one should ask when assisting country authorities in thinking
about regime options and develops a set of criteria that can help to inform the choice of an exchange
rate arrangement.
CHAPTER AUTHORS
Marco Casiraghi (MCasiraghi@imf.org), Karl Habermeier (khabermeier@gmail.com), and
Thomas Harjes (THarjes@imf.org).
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 3
Contents Page
GLOSSARY _________________________________________________________________________________________________4
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ___________________________________________________________________________________5
I. INTRODUCTION ______________________________________________________________________________________7
II. INSTITUTIONAL AND ANALYTICAL BACKGROUND ____________________________________________7
A. Policy Options and Role of Capacity development _________________________________________________ 7
B. Economic Foundations ________________________________________________________________________________ 8
III. CHOOSING THE EXCHANGE RATE ARRANGEMENT ____________________________________________9
A. Criteria for Choosing an Arrangement ______________________________________________________________ 9
B. Macroeconomic Initial Conditions _________________________________________________________________ 10
C. Characteristics of the Economy ____________________________________________________________________ 11
D. Types of Shocks to the Economy___________________________________________________________________ 14
E. Special Considerations for Commodity Exporters ________________________________________________ 14
F. Intermediate Exchange Rate Arrangements_______________________________________________________ 15
IV. ADDITIONAL CONSIDERATIONS ________________________________________________________________ 17
A. Elements of the Policy Framework _________________________________________________________________ 17
B. Consistency and Integration of Policy Frameworks ______________________________________________ 18
V. APPROACH AND IMF TOOLS_____________________________________________________________________ 19
A. Analytical Instruments ______________________________________________________________________________ 19
B. IMF Policies __________________________________________________________________________________________ 20
REFERENCES _____________________________________________________________________________________________ 22
FIGURES
1. Evolution of de Facto Exchange Rate Arrangements _______________________________________________ 16
TABLES
1. Key Criteria for Choosing an Exchange Rate Arrangement __________________________________________ 9
2. Selected Monetary and Exchange Rate Policy Frameworks _______________________________________ 17
APPENDICES
1. Empirical Literature on the Choice of an Exchange Rate Arrangement___________________________ 26
2. Describing Exchange Rate Arrangements and Monetary Policy Frameworks ____________________
28
3. Classification and Assignment of Policy Instruments ______________________________________________ 29
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 4
Glossary
AREAR
Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions
CD
Capacity Development
CFM
Capital Flow Management Measure
EBA
External Balance Assessment
EMDE
Emerging Markets and Developing Economies
ERM
Exchange Rate Mechanism
FSAP
Financial Sector Assessment Program
FX
Foreign Exchange
FXI
Foreign Exchange Intervention
IEO
Independent Evaluation Office
IMF
International Monetary Fund
IPF
Integrated Policy Framework
MCM
Monetary and Capital Markets Department
MPM
Macroprudential Measure
OCA
Optimal Currency Area
OMO
Open Market Operation
TA
Technical Assistance
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 5
Executive Summary
Choosing a suitable exchange rate arrangement is one of the central topics of open economy
macroeconomics. At times, countries may need to consider whether an alternative exchange rate
arrangement might better suit their needs and goals. An exchange rate arrangement that is inconsistent
with a country’s characteristics can amplify the impact of adverse shocks, impede the control of inflation,
undermine economic growth, and increase risks to financial stability. These issues have been discussed
by academics and policy makers for decades. While a full consensus has not emerged, many of the key
f actors relevant to the choice of exchange rate arrangement have been identified. Country authorities
have regularly sought the views of IMF staff on these issues.
Good arguments can be made for both fixed and floating exchange rate regimes. A key potential
benef it of a f ixed exchange rate is that it red uc es trading costs associated with frequent changes in
exchange rates, thereby facilitating trade. Provided that foreign exchange reserves are adequate, fixed
exchange rate regimes are also relatively simple to operate and provide an effective nominal anchor by
borrowing the credibility of the central bank of the anchor currency. Owing to these benefits, fixed
exchange rates can be attractive to small economies that depend heavily on international trade, and even
more so if institutional capacity is limited. On the other end of the spectrum, a f reely floating exchange
rate will normally be associated with higher trading costs, especially if foreign exchange (FX) hedging
markets are underdeveloped. It also requires an alternative nominal anchor (such as an inflation target),
which can be more demanding in terms of institutional capacity at the central bank and often requires
many years of preparation. However, once achieved, a flexible exchange rate can act as a useful shock
absorber. A flexible exchange rate also allows for an independent monetary policy that can be set based
on the needs of the domestic economy, thereby allowing for better macroeconomic management. As a
result, f lexible regimes can achieve more stable macroeconomic conditions over time. A flexible
exchange rate also reduces (and often eliminates) the need for costly currency defenses.
The choice of the exchange rate arrangement is more than a technical issue. The choice is a core
element of the authorities’ overall economic policy framework, with important implications and trade-offs
f or other key policy areas. The IMF area department will thus usually play the leading role in making any
policy recommendations. Capacity development can support the formulation of recommendations and
advise on their implementation.
The exchange rate arrangement and the overall policy framework need to be consistent. Fro m a
macroeconomic perspective, the link is provided by the so-called impossible trinity (also known as the
trilemma), which states that countries can only achieve two of the following three at any given time: a
f ixed exchange rate, free capital movements, and an independent monetary policy. Fixed exchange rates
imply tighter constraints to conducting independent monetary policy as openness to capital flows
increases.
1
Any advice on the choice of an exchange rate arrangement should be country specific. It needs to
identify and address a country's particular economic challenges, carefully assessing trade-offs among
1
Given strong global financial interconnectedness, some economists have even argued that the trilemma has
become a dilemma, since it is impossible to escap e the influence of global financial conditions.
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 6
goals such as achieving price stability and sustained economic growth, reducing crisis risk, easing
external adjustment, encouraging integration, and securing broad systemic stability. For example,
although a flexible exchange rate typically acts as a shock absorber, some empirical evidence suggests
that there are also circumstances in which a flexible exchange rate may amplify some shocks rather than
mitigate them.
There are three main approaches to the choice of exchange rate arrangements. First, the optimal
currency area (OCA) theory relates the choice of arrangement to the country’s trade concentration and
openness, and the size and type of shocks that are prevalent. Second, according to the financial view, the
key determinants of the choice are the degree of capital mobility (based on the impossible trinity) and the
extent of currency mismatches, which expose the economy to detrimental balance sheet effects following
sharp depreciations. Third, the political view holds that an exchange rate anchor can help to compensate
f or the authorities lack of policy credibility.
Combining these three approaches yields a comprehensive set of criteria that can help to inform
the choice of an exchange rate arrangement. These criteria can be organized into three groups:
(1) macroeconomic initial conditions, such as inflation, foreign exchange reserve adequacy, and fiscal
and external imbalances; (2) structural characteristics of the economy, including its size and openness,
mobility and flexibility of factors of production, and type and frequency of shocks; and (3) institutional
f eatures and prospects for their development.
The choice of exchange rate arrangement has implications for all other aspects of the policy
framework. These include the design and use of intermediate targets, operational targets, and central
bank instruments. In addition to domestic monetary operations and foreign exchange interventions,
instruments may also include capital flow management measures and macroprudential measures. The
IMF can provide capacity development on all aspects of the chosen policy framework, covering both
design and implementation.
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 7
I. Introduction
This chapter provides guidance for issues surrounding the choice of an exchange rate
arrangement. While these issues frequently come up in the context of capacity development (CD)
missions, the choice of arrangement is more than a technical issue, and the IMF area department will
normally play the leading role in providing overall policy recommendations. CD can support the
development of the detailed policy framework and advise on its implementation. The choice of
arrangement is also a complex issue. There are no simple answers, and even an in-depth analysis of
country-specific factors may often not lead to a definitive conclusion about the optimal arrangement.
Theref ore, this chapter emphasizes conceptual and methodological considerations rather than precise
prescriptions.
Issues related to the transition to greater exchange rate flexibility are taken up in a separate
Handbook chapter.
2
These include the choice of a nominal anchor, the detailed design of the exchange
rate arrangement, and key reforms needed for successful implementation.
II. Institutional and Analytical Background
A. POLICY OPTIONS AND ROLE OF CAPACITY DEVELOPMENT
Monetary and exchange rate policy frameworks should provide a nominal anchor. Without a
nominal anchor, the price level in the economy is undetermined. This could lead to unchecked inflation (or
def lation) and cause macroeconomic and financial instability. In addition to jeopardizing price stability, the
lack of a nominal anchor would also weaken the transmission of monetary policy, hindering the ability of
the central bank to affect macroeconomic and financial conditions and effectively counteract adverse
shocks to the economy.
The range of available options can be characterized in terms of increasing exchange rate
flexibility, going from a peg to a free float. These two regimes represent the two corner solutions.
Under a peg, the exchange rate serves as the nominal anchor for monetary policy. A free float requires
an alternative nominal anchor, such as an inflation target A range of available intermediate options
capture some of the benefits and costs of the corner solutions, although to different degrees. Starting
f rom a peg, some intermediate arrangements entail a more flexible exchange rate, which still plays the
role of nominal anchor. Such regimes may involve pegging to a basket of currencies (rather than to one
single currency), widening the fluctuation bands around the central parity, or letting the peg adjust over
time along some predetermined path (a “crawl”). In policy frameworks that use a nominal anchor different
f rom the exchange rate (mainly monetary-aggregate and inflation targeting), the exchange rate can
sometimes still be actively influenced through foreign exchange interventions (FXI), under a “managed”
arrangement instead of a (free) float.
The choice of exchange rate arrangement lies with country authorities, but the IMF can play an
important supporting role. In their regular surveillance activities, IMF staff may advise member country
2
For further details, see the chapter o n :Moving to Greater Exchange Rate Flexibility.”
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 8
authorities on whether the current exchange rate arrangement is sustainable and appropriate, and
provide relevant policy recommendations. IMF area departments have primary responsibility for policy
recommendations on the choice of the exchange rate arrangement. The underlying analysis should be
country-specific and provide a concise and clear account of the overall monetary and exchange rate
policy framework, economic developments, and challenges, as well as related policies. In particular, it
should apply the considerations and criteria set out below to the specific circumstances of the country.
Issues related to the choice of an exchange rate arrangement often feature in CD. The IMF's
Monetary and Capital Markets Department (MCM) is frequently called on by country authorities to provide
CD relating to the policy frameworkincluding in the context of transitionsand to advise on its
implementation. In the context of such CD, having a thorough understanding of alternative framework
options and their implications is essential. CD can also sometimes help the authorities conduct their own
analysis and assess various exchange rate regime options. Area departments, CD missions, and experts
should draw as appropriate on guidance, tools, and data developed by the IMF for use in the analysis of
exchange rate policy and help country authorities to adapt these methods for use in their policy analysis.
B. ECONOMIC FOUNDATIONS
The academic literature has identified various criteria that are relevant to choosing an exchange
rate arrangement. This section focuses on the key studies of the last 20 years. During this time, views
and policy prescriptions have changed significantly in both official and academic circles. Oftentimes, initial
simple and clear-cut prescriptions have made way for more nuanced views.
Between the Asian crisis of the late 1990s and the Global Financial Crisis, the mainstream view
was largely "bipolar," supporting the adoption of either free floats or hard pegs. Intermediate
regimes were viewed skeptically as it was thought that they could not provide the same macroeconomic
benef its and involved important shortcomings, for instance, being more prone to crises. The past decade
has seen a growing appreciation of the need for adequate exchange rate flexibility and of the benefits of
inf lation targeting, while also recognizing that exchange rate overshooting and financial vulnerabilities
may require more active management of the exchange rate. As a result, the assessment of intermediate
regimes has significantly changed, as they seem able to deliver some of the benefits of both pegs and
f ree f loats by limiting undue exchange rate volatility without significantly distorting the level of the real
exchange.
There are three main approaches in economic theory to explaining the choice of an exchange rate
arrangement.
3
First, the OCA theory is based on the Mundell-Fleming framework and relates the choice
to the country’s trade concentration and openness, and the size and type of the prevailing shocks.
Second, the financial view emphasizes the degree of capital mobility (based on the impossible trinity) and
currency mismatches, which expose the economy to detrimental balance sheet effects following sharp
depreciations. Third, the political view argues that using an exchange rate anchor is a way to compensate
f or a lack of policy credibility. The next section will discuss how in practice these three approaches can
3
The theoretical underpinnings of modern thinking on fixed versus flexible exchange rates date back to
Friedman (1953). This contribution was followed until the 1990s by a large number of studies developing theoretical
approaches to identify th e o p timal exchange rate arran g ement. Since the early 2000s, the literature has focused
more empirically, testing the predictions of the different existing theories.
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 9
inf orm the choice of regime. Detailed reviews of the approaches themselves may be found in Ghosh and
others (2003) and Levy Yeyati and Sturzenegger (2010).
III. Choosing the Exchange Rate Arrangement
A. CRITERIA FOR CHOOSING AN ARRANGEMENT
The three main theoretical approaches can be combined to develop a comprehensive set of
criteria (Table 1). The OCA theory and the financial view suggest that fixed exchange rates are
preferable if inflation and capital mobility are low, reserve levels and trade integration are high, labor
markets and fiscal policy are f lexible, production and exports are diversified, and shocks are nominal in
nature and symmetric with the anchor country.
4
The political view suggests that countries with low policy
credibility could adopt a fixed exchange rate to borrow monetary policy credibility from the anchor country
and commit to nominal stability. A review of the empirical literature on the validity of the three theories
(and their associated criteria) is found in Appendix 1.
Table 1. Key Criteria for Choosing an Exchange Rate Arrangement
Macroeconomic Initial Conditions Characteristics of the Economy Types of Shocks to the Economy
Level of inflatio n
Size of external imbalances
Foreign exchange reserves
Financial system vulnerabilities
Fiscal position
Other macroeconomic policies
Size of the economy
Openness
Diversificatio n o f exports and output
Trade and political integration
Flexibility of labor markets
Mobility of capital
Dollarization
Financial system development
Real shocks
Volatile capital flows
Source: IMF staff.
All of these criteria should be analyzed to inform the choice of an exchange rate arrangement.
More detailed considerations in conducting and applying this analysis are discussed in what follows. The
goal is to develop an overall view of the pros and cons of different exchange arrangements in a given
country. In doing so, the CD provider should understand the analytical concepts and methods described
in this chapter while exercising good policy judgment. In the following sections, we will discuss each of
the criteria in more detail.
4
Frankel (2012) pro vides a discussion of the country characteristics that bear on the choice of the exchange rate
arrangement.
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 10
B. MACROECONOMIC INITIAL CONDITIONS
Inflation. The more domestic inflation diverges from that of trading partners, the greater the need for
f requent exchange rate adjustments. For example, if under a fixed exchange rate regime, domestic
inf lation is consistently higher than that of trading partners, the real exchange rate will quickly become
overvalued, resulting in a widening current account deficit, and ultimately threatening the sustainability of
the peg. This issue may be addressed by a credible and permanent adjustment of monetary policy. If that
is difficult, the adoption of a more flexible exchange rate arrangement, such as a free float, a crawling
peg, or another other type of adjustable peg may be preferable. If the structural characteristics of a
country otherwise favor a less flexible exchange rate arrangement, steps would normally first need to be
taken to sustainably reduce inflation to a rate more in line with its trading partners, thus making the peg
more sustainable. That said, some countries with very high inflation or hyperinflation, where inflation
inertia is low and money demand is unstable, have at times adopted a hard peg exactly to support rapid
disinflation and help reestablish policy credibility. Such a strategy can work if a high level of credibility can
somehow be given to the peg, e.g., by backing the full money supply with foreign currency reserves. This
was, for example, the experience of Bulgaria, which adopted a currency board in 1997.
5
External imbalances can have a variety of causes, most commonly a substantial misalignment of the
real exchange rate, which in turn often reflects overly loose fiscal or monetary policy. Structural rigidities
or demographic factors may also contribute. While a first-best approach would be to take appropriate
policy measures to address the root causes of imbalances (see also below on the macroeconomic policy
mix required for sustainable pegs), in the absence of such measures, it will often be desirable to allow for
greater exchange rate flexibility by adopting a float or a free float, or a crawling peg.
FX reserves. An adequate level of FX reserves, which enable direct interventions in the FX market, is
necessary to maintain an exchange rate peg or keep the exchange rate within narrow bands. When the
level of FX reserves falls below a critical leveltypically against the background of persistent underlying
depreciation pressuresthis may trigger a speculative attack on the peg. The experience with the
Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM) in western Europe in the early 1990s showed that seeking to defend
an unsustainable exchange rate parity through high interest rates or unlimited FXI is unlikely to be
successful. The f ormer lacks credibility owing to collateral damage to the domestic economy. The latter
leads to an even more rapid depletion of FX reserves, further reinforcing the attack on the peg. In these
circumstances, timely exchange rate adjustment or the adoption of a more flexible exchange rate
arrangement will usually be better options.
Financial vulnerabilities can play a crucial role in the choice of an exchange rate arrangement, but the
implications largely depend on the source of risk. Unhedged currency mismatches in the balance sheets
of financial intermediaries, firms, and households (e.g., due to liability dollarization) make the economy
vulnerable to large exchange rate fluctuations. There are many examples of major crises causes by the
interplay of such financial vulnerabilities and the exchange rate arrangement. These experiences tend to
illustrate that, after shocks, a fixedor at least less flexibleexchange rate may be more desirable for
economies characterized by large unhedged if FX debt. However, as this choice effectively insures the
private sector against all exchange rate risk (at least as long as the arrangement is sustainable), it is likely
5
Other countries using a currency board to help red uce high inflation include Esto n ia in 1992 and Lithuania in 1994.
Similarly, in 1995, Latvia adopted an exchange rate arrangement with some features of a currency board.
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 11
to hinder the development of hedging markets that are required for a successful transition to greater
exchange flexibility.
6
More broadly, in cases where unhedged FX debt does not represent a threat to
f inancial stability, a f lexible exchange rate would typically provide greater benefits by allowing the country
to conduct an independent monetary policy. The central bank would then be able to support the economy,
including through the exchange rate channel, and could also address financial vulnerabilities by acting as
a lender of last resort.
Fiscal position. The sustainability of public finances is necessary to successfully maintain a fixed
exchange rate regime for several reasons. First, if a country opts for a f ixed exchange rate arrangement,
the impossible trinity will imply that monetary policy would not be able to contribute to stabilizing
macroeconomic conditions. As a consequence, the burden to implement countercyclical policies would
fall f ully on fiscal policy. Second, the exchange rate instrument would stop acting as a shock absorber,
likely f orcing more frequent and sizeable policy interventions to counteract domestic and external shocks.
Finally, unstainable fiscal policy would lead to an outflow of FX reserves, negatively affecting confidence
in the exchange arrangement and eventually threatening its survival. In light of these considerations, the
sustainability of a fixed exchange rate arrangement cannot abstract from sound fis cal conditions and
discipline.
Other macroeconomic policies. At the end of the day, all exchange rate arrangements require
consistent and responsible macroeconomic policies to be sustainable over time. This said, pegged
arrangements typically impose tighter constraints, and not all countries have been able or willing to
commit to the demanding policy mix needed to maintain a peg over the medium and longer terms. To
avoid a crisis and a disorderly exit from the peg, countries have at times opted for wide-ranging Capital
Flow Management Measures (CFM) and exchange restrictions. These measures, however, can reduce
access to international financial markets, impede the development of the financial sector, give rise to a
parallel FX market, and more generally, lead to a misallocation of resources.
7
Advice on the choice of an
exchange rate arrangement needs to take into account how a country's political economy and institutions
are likely to affect policy choices, not just at the time of the adoption of a particular arrangement, but also
in the f uture.
C. CHARACTERISTICS OF THE ECONOMY
Size of the economy. The larger the economy, the stronger the case for a flexible rate. Larger
economies will benefit from a flexible exchange rate because it provides increased room to maneuver for
domestic fiscal and monetary policies and acts as a shock absorber. By contrast, small open economies
may find it difficult to conduct fully independent monetary policy, forcing them to choose between a peg or
a f loat that must be combined with CFMs (Rey, 2015). Large economies will typically have the requisite
technical and organizational capacity to implement a f lexible exchange rate arrangement and the
associated independent monetary policy, as well as effective financial regulation and supervision. In
addition, the size of an economy is often related to other f eatures (such as a lower degree of openness)
discussed below. Large economies tend to be less open, which argues for a flexible exchange rate
arrangement. They are also often more economically diversified, which tends to mitigate potential
6
See the chapter onTransition to Greater Exchange Rate Flexibility.”
7
The strength and duratio n o f these adverse effects remains an unsettled empirical question.
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 12
adverse effects of exchange rate fluctuations. In fact, among the world's largest economies, most have a
f reely f loating exchange rate (Euro Area, Japan, Russia, United Kingdom, United States), while other
large countries combine a float with varying degrees of FXI (Brazil, India, Indonesia). Small economies
of ten feature exchange rate pegs.
Openness. The role of openness in the choice of the exchange rate arrangements is not straightforward.
In f act, small economies with high trade openness face a complicated trade-off. On the one hand, a fixed
exchange rate would involve significant benefits through reduced trading and transactions cost, which are
typically high for this type of economies given their high share of transactions with the rest of the world. In
open economies, frequent exchange rate adjustments or large exchange rate fluctuations can be
disruptive to international trade and financial flows, with adverse effects on domestic activity and prices.
Of ten, a country therefore might peg its currency to its largest trading partner (e.g., Denmark has a peg to
the euro), and in f act, this was one of the main economic reasons behind the creation of the euro. Highly
open economies will often also be more vulnerable to external shocks. Singapore, one of the most open
economies in the world as measured by the share of trade in GDP, provides an interesting example of a
successful heavily managed intermediate arrangement, which has in recent years empirically resembled
a crawling peg or even a fixed peg. For some small open economies, the benefits associated with
reducing trading and transactions costs therefore outweigh the costs. On the other hand, more advanced
small open economies that benefit from more developed hedging markets may assign a higher value on
the exchange rate flexibility that would allow them to cushion external shocks and provide monetary
independence. Indeed, several of such countries (e.g., Canada, New Zealand, Sweden) have been
trailblazers in the transition to more flexible exchange rate regimes.
Diversification of exports and output makes a country less vulnerable to terms-of-trade shocks,
reducing (all things equal) the need for exchange rate flexibility. However, the relationship between the
exchange rate arrangement and economic development and diversification is complex. A fixed exchange
rate can disincentivize financial risk management and impede the development of deep and liquid
f inancial markets, which in turn can be a drag on economic development and diversification. On the other
hand, particularly in commodity-exporting countries, exchange rate movements that are too large can give
rise to f urther complicated trade-offs (see also below).
Trade and political integration. The higher the extent of trade and political integration with partner
countries, the stronger the case for a peg or even a common currency. These issues have been
extensively debated in the literature on OCAs. However, as the experience of the euro area since 1999
has shown, despite the existence of a common market in goods and services, significant tensions can
emerge under a single currency owing to divergences in fiscal policy and external competitiveness in
member countries. Such tensions may also exacerbate risks to financial and price stability.
Flexibility of labor markets. Since domestic and external adjustment can, to some extent, substitute for
each other in the response to shocks, the less flexible the labor market, the stronger the case for more
f lexible exchange rates. The mechanisms are complex and have been discussed extensively in the
economic literature. Among the most important is that without exchange rate flexibility, the correction of
severe misalignments in the real exchange rate could require infeasible reductions in nominal wages.
Mobility of capital. In general, a higher capital mobility supports the adoption of a flexible exchange rate
regime. In f act, according to the impossible trinity, a f ully open capital account together with a fixed
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 13
exchange rate implies the loss of monetary policy independence. As a result, the country will face a
reduction in its capacity to respond to adverse shocks and maintain macroeconomic stability, especially if
the domestic economic and financial cycles are not aligned with those of the country issuing the currency
to which the exchange rate is pegged. By contrast, a flexible exchange rate would work as a shock
absorber against external shocks (see Carriere-Swallow and others, 2021; Ben-Zeev, 2019) and provide
room to maneuver to the central bank to further counteract this type of shocks. In this respect, empirical
f indings suggest that the transmission of a monetary policy shock to output and prices becomes stronger
in the presence of a f lexible exchange rate thanks to the amplification mechanism through exchange
rates (Brandao-Marques and others, 2020).
8
Dollarization. Another factor in the choice of an exchange rate arrangement is the degree of dollarization
in the economy (related to the issue of financial vulnerabilities discussed earlier). The term dollarization
includes not just the domestic use of the US dollar, but of any foreign currency. Dollarization can take a
variety of forms. In the banking system, for example, deposits or loans can be dollarized to different
degrees, with shares above 30 or 40 percent usually considered as high dollarization.
9
Dollarization may
af f ect all three classical functions of money, namely as a means of transaction, store of value, and unit of
account. High dollarization may be an impediment to the adoption of greater exchange rate flexibility, as it
can increase the vulnerability to exchange rate risk in the financial system and other sectors of the
economy and hamper the transmission and traction of monetary policy.
10
Durably reducing dollarization
requires a credible policy of low inflation, supported by various regulatory measures that reduce
incentives for the use of foreign currency.
11
Financial system development. The depth of FX and hedging markets is an important factor in
determining the optimal exchange rate regime. While markets could be developed, the choice of the
exchange rate arrangement can play an important role in incentivizing (or disincentivizing) such
development. Fixed exchange rates help shelter mismatched balance sheets from exchange rate
changes in the short term, weakening the incentives for the private sector to hedge their FX positions.
Similarly, frequent FX interventions by the central bank would reduce the room for other actors to engage
in bilateral transactions that do not involve the central bank. The resulting underdeveloped markets
amplify negative shocks and cause larger problems if the peg has to be abandoned at a later stage. For
8
Although a flexible exchange rate typically works as a sh o ck absorber, the literature and central bankers have also
identified several circumstances in which a flexible exchange rate may amplify some shocks rather than mitigate
them. These considerations especially apply for emerging markets and developing economies, where the link
between exchange rates and domestic macro-financial conditions may create a difficult trade-off between inflation
and output stabilization that typically does not arise in advanced economies. In this environment, several policy
responses may be needed to effectively d eal with large and volatile international capital flows, including FXI, financial
regulation and supervision, and CFMs.
9
Ize and Levy Yeyati (2003) see financial dollarization primarily as a rational response to macroeconomic instability.
However, dollarization may be a cause and not just a consequence of macroeconomic and financial instability and
vulnerability. Relatedly, dollarization may be high under both fixed (e.g., "official dollarization") and more flexible
exchange rate arrangements.
10
For a treatment of th e challenges that dollarization poses to the conduct of monetary and exchange rate policy, see
Baliño and others (1999). Brandao-Marques and others (2020), however, fin d that interest transmission can still be
effective in economies with a high degree of dollarization.
11
De-dollarization policies are reviewed in Kokenyne and others (2010).
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 14
this reason, these vulnerabilities should normally be addressed whenever possible to ensure an ordered
transition from a peg to a float.
D. TYPES OF SHOCKS TO THE ECONOMY
The choice of exchange rate arrangement is also affected by the size and types of shocks
affecting a country's economy. Shocks may be of external or domestic origin and may be nominal or
real. External shocks are generally seen as exogenous, with a large unpredictable component, and may
be short lived or longer lasting.
External shocks are usually most directly relevant to the choice of the exchange rate
arrangement. This is because the exchange rate is the key relative price linking the domestic and foreign
economies. Among the most important (real) external shocks are fluctuations in global commodity prices,
which directly affect a country's terms of trade (relative prices of exports and imports). Other important
external shocks include changes in the volume and composition of international capital flows, or in
nominal interest rates in major countries.
All else equal, larger and more frequent foreign shocks argue for greater exchange rate flexibility.
For example, the impact of an adverse terms-of-trade shock (say an increase in prices for important
imported factors of production such as energy or machinery) would be offset by exchange rate
depreciation that helps to maintain the international competitiveness of domestic industry (see Broda
2001 f or an empirical assessment).
12
Similarly, as also noted in the earlier discussion of policy responses
to capital mobility, financial shocks such as a capital inflow surge can also be dampened by appreciation
of the exchange rate. This makes domestic assets more expensive and less attractive to foreign
investors, especially if those investors expect that the exchange rate will depreciate again. And finally,
whereas under a pegged exchange rate, an increase in interest rates in the anchor currency country will
need to be broadly matched by an increase in domestic interest rates, a flexible exchange rate offers
greater scope for an independent domestic interest rate (or monetary) policy.
E. SPECIAL CONSIDERATIONS FOR COMMODITY EXPORTERS
The choice of exchange rate regime poses a particular problem for commodity exporters.
Commodity exporters often have a combination of characteristics, some of which may favor a f ixed
exchange rate, while others favor a flexible exchange rate. Features that argue for a peg include (often)
small size, openness to trade, and in many cases relatively undeveloped financial markets. On the other
hand, important features favoring a f lexible exchange rate include typically relatively undiversified output
and the susceptibility to large and frequent terms-of-trade shocks.
The literature has proposed several alternative arrangements for commodity exporting countries.
One proposal is to target the real exchange rate. However, the broad consensus in the literature is that a
real peg is inconsistent with maintaining price stability over the long run, and thus does not provide the
12
The traditional literature following Poole (1970) emphasized the distin ction between domestic money demand
shocks and real shocks. If the former prevails, a fixed exchange rate regime is advantageous since it automatically
stabilizes output (the change in money demand is met so as to sustain the peg). By contrast, the prevalence of real
shocks arg ues for flexible exchange rates.
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 15
needed monetary policy anchor (e.g., Uribe, 2003). Another proposal, introduced in Frankel (2003, 2005),
is to “peg the export price” by fixing the price of the main export commodities in terms of domestic
currencyno country has so far, however, adopted this proposal.
Commodity exporters considering a peg need to be aware that this choice may deliver price
stability in the medium and long run, but inflation will likely remain volatile in the short run.
Exchange rate anchors allow a country to import the monetary policy and credibility of foreign central
banks, along with their price stability. At the same time, an exchange rate anchor limits the domestic
monetary policy response to short-term shocks, generating more volatile price dynamics. Although this
consideration holds especially for hard pegs, all policy frameworks that aim at stabilizing the exchange
rate may suffer from this drawback. While this issue is not exclusive to commodity exporters, these
countries may observe particularly large swings in short-run inflation owing to frequent large shocks in
commodity export prices. Moreover, the associated real exchange over- and undervaluation will tend to
hamper the allocation of resources in the economy and dampen growth.
There are also specific challenges associated with choosing a more flexible exchange rate
arrangement in resource-rich countries. While more exchange rate flexibility can in principle be
desirable in many such countries, central bank capacity constraints or political economy considerations
may raise obstacles to their adoption. Resource-rich countries may indeed suffer from "Dutch disease,"
where an increase in global commodity prices translates into an appreciation of the real exchange rate
that adversely affects the viability of other export industries and economic diversification. A fiscal rule
along with effective sovereign wealth management will often be desirable to prevent excessive real
exchange rate appreciation during commodity price booms. However, such a rule can also dampen real
exchange rate depreciation during a commodity price bust, which could impede economic development
and diversification, owing, inter alia, to large increases in the domestic currency cost of imported
investment goods.
All in all, there is no consensus on the optimal choice of framework in resource-rich countries,
and trade-offs need to be considered on a case-by-case basis. Theoretical considerations need to be
complemented by in-depth analysis of country-specific circumstances when giving advice on the choice of
an exchange rate arrangement in commodity exporters.
F. INTERMEDIATE EXCHANGE RATE ARRANGEMENTS
About four-fifths of IMF member countries have adopted either a market-determined exchange
rate (float or free float) or a hard peg (Figure 1). The criteria discussed in this chapter will usually
suffice to support analyses on whether a f lexible or fixed exchange rate is appropriate. However, for some
countries an intermediate arrangement could be an appropriate choice. An intermediate arrangement
could be considered if country characteristics do not clearly support the choice of either a float or a peg.
The two main types of intermediate arrangements in contemporary practice are crawls and so-
called "other managed" arrangements. Crawls are subdivided by IMF staff into de jure crawling pegs
and "crawl-like" arrangements. Other managed arrangements are a residual that does not fit into any
other category, and usually exhibit a moderate but varying amount of exchange rate flexibility, but without
the exchange rate being fully market-determined.
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 16
Crawling pegs and crawl-like arrangements are often used by smaller and lower to middle income
countries without highly developed financial systems. The 2020 Annual Report on Exchange
Arrangements and Exchange Restriction (AREAER) documents that 26 IMF member countries use
various kinds of crawls (IMF 2020). Three countries have de jure crawling pegs (Botswana, Honduras,
Nicaragua) and have maintained these for many years. Some other countries have maintained crawl-like
arrangements for long periods, notably Ethiopia, Haiti, Laos, Rwanda, Tunisia, and Uzbekistan. For all
these countries, a f ormal or informal crawl combines the operational simplicity of an exchange rate
anchor, while providing greater room to maneuver for domestic monetary and fiscal policies. In terms of
the criteria f or the choice of an arrangement, many of these countries have some, but not all, of the
characteristics that would favor either a fixed or floating exchange rate.
Figure 1. Evolution of de Facto Exchange Rate Arrangements
(As of April 30
th
of AREAER publication year; in percent of total countries)
Source (IMF, 2020)
The 15 countries in the "other managed" category are also mainly smaller and lower to middle
income countries, although there are important exceptions. Indeed, a few large economies
(Argentina, China, Pakistan) exhibit this type of heavily managed arrangement, and some significant
commodity exporters (Angola, Kuwait) do as well. The reasons for the adoption of these kinds of
arrangements are diverse and country-specific, and often cannot be explained by a straightforward
application of the criteria set out in this chapter. More in-depth analysis of these arrangements and their
performance is needed. IMF country staff reports are a good starting point for information on these
issues.
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 17
IV. Additional Considerations
A. ELEMENTS OF THE POLICY FRAMEWORK
The choice of an exchange rate arrangement cannot be separated from the broader policy
framework. This section sets out the standard elements of the monetary and exchange rate policy
f ramework and discusses the consistency of policy frameworks.
The specification of a monetary and exchange rate policy framework should normally include
certain standard elements. These are (i) the main objectives of policy, (ii) the intermediate targets,
(iii) the operational targets, and (iv) the instruments used to implement policy. Table 2 provides a stylized
representation of various policy frameworks using these standard elements. Importantly, while the set of
potential instruments used in monetary and FX operations can be broadly similar under many policy
f rameworks, their relative roles and the way in which they are used will be very different.
Monetary and exchange rate policy frameworks should always provide a clear nominal anchor.
Without a nominal anchor, the price level in the economy is typically neither well defined nor determinate.
In addition to undermining price stability, the lack of a nominal anchor can also make monetary policy less
ef f ective in counteracting transitory shocks to the economy.
Table 2. Selected Monetary and Exchange Rate Policy Frameworks
Framework Objective Intermediate
Targets
Operational
Targets
Instruments
Exchange rate
anchor
1/
Stability of the currency
(indirectly providing price
stability)
Exchange rate Exchange rate,
interest rate
FXI, Open Market
Operations (OMOs),
standing facilities,
reserve
requirements
Monetary
targeting
Inflation (implicit) Broad money Interest rate,
various options for
reserves
OMOs, standing
facilities, reserve
requirements
Inflation targeting Inflation (explicit) Inflation forecast Interest rate OMOs, standing
facilities, reserve
requirements
1/
Examples of these frameworks include hard pegs, but also flexible exchange rate an chors, such as crawling pegs
and pegs to currency baskets.
Actual policy frameworks will often be more complex than this simple typology suggests. For
example, there are many variants of inflation targeting, and FXI may play an important role under many of
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 18
these.
13
There are also many variants of monetary targeting, ranging from monetary programming to
f lexible broad money targeting to the use of money as an indicative target (IMF, 2015c; Laurens and
others, 2015).
Exchange rate arrangements and monetary policy frameworks should be consistently defined.
The terminology used in CD should follow standard IMF practice, as discussed in Appendix 2.
B. CONSISTENCY AND INTEGRATION OF POLICY FRAMEWORKS
The exchange rate arrangement, the monetary policy framework, and other economic policies
need to be clearly defined and consistent.
Regarding macroeconomic consistency, an implication of a large class of models is the
"impossible trinity", which states that only two of the three following characteristics of a monetary
and exchange rate policy framework can be achieved at the same time: a fixed exchange rate,
f ree capital movements, and an independent monetary policy.
14
Some authors, notably Rey
(2015), argue that the constraints imposed by the global financial cycle reduce the impossible
trinity to an "impossible duality," so that independent monetary policy requires the implementation
of CFMs.
15
Each pillar of the impossible trinity corresponds to a set of policy instruments, and there is thus
also a need f or instrument consistency. The instruments are usually grouped into (1) domestic
monetary operations, (2) FXI, and (3) exchange controls and CFMs. The ef fectiveness of each
category of instruments imposes a constraint on the ability to achieve different combinations
under the impossible trinity. For example, if exchange controls and CFMs can be easily
13
The case of Singapore is of particular interest in this connection, as it combines the objective of price stability with
a flexible crawling peg. The Monetary Authority of Singapore (MAS) describes its framework as follows: "In a small
and open economy such as Sin g ap ore, where gross exports and imports of goods and services are more than 300
percent of GDP and domestic expenditure has a high import content, the exchange rate has a much stronger
influence on inflation than the interest rate. Accordingly, MAS monetary policy framework is centered on managing
the Singapore dollar against a trade-weighted basket of currencies." While this type of framework could in theory be
beneficial to other co un tries, implementing it well requires a high standard of central bank analytical and operational
capacity.
14
A theoretical underpinning of the impossible trinity is the concept of (uncovered) interest rate parity, that is, that
expected movements in the nominal exchange rate are equal to the interest rate differential between two countries.
This implies that under a fixed exchange rate and with free capital movements, th e interest rate in the country
pegging to a foreign currency needs to set domestic interest rates (or allow them to form in the market) in a manner
consistent with the mainten an ce of a fixed exchange rate. Hence, with free capital movements, there is little or n o
scope for an independent in terest rate policy under a peg. As an empirical matter, interest rate parity does not hold
precisely, owing to various frictions and uncertainties that impede complete arbitrage. Indeed, under certain
conditions, carry trades can be destabilizing, see for example, Plan tin and Shin (2018).
15
As a practical matter, in o rder to be effective for more th an a relatively short time, CFMs n eed to be comprehensive
and strongly enforced. It is generally not possible to achieve monetary policy independence under a pegged
exchange rate using only a few targeted CFMs. The use of comprehensive and strongly enforced CFMs can,
however, also have sig n ificant negative side effects on financial market functioning and development.
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 19
circumvented, a country may have to choose between a fixed exchange rate and room to
maneuver on domestic monetary policy.
In recent years, there has been growing interest in integrated policy frameworks. In addition to
combining the three categories of instruments mentioned above, these frameworks also include other
policy areas, notably macroprudential policies and sometimes also fiscal policies. The objective is to
achieve full consistency and higher effectiveness in macroeconomic policy making by recognizing key
f rictions absent in traditional Mundell-Fleming-type models. These include shallow FX markets, FX
mismatches, and imperfect monetary policy credibility, and encompass a broad set of relevant policy
instruments. For example, given that financial vulnerabilities and instability can interfere with the
achievement of monetary and exchange rate policy goals, macroprudential measures (MPMs) will also
need to be deployed. Country authorities generally understand the potential benefits of integrating and
coordinating various policy areas and instruments within an overall framework. However, a fully worked
out and generally accepted paradigmand practical methodologyfor doing so had until recently, not
been available. The IMF has been making progress in filling this gap.
16
When examining how a given policy framework operates in practice, it is useful to consider where
it lies along several dimensions: (i) how much weight does the framework place on the exchange rate
versus other targets; (ii) how much does it operate based on rules rather than discretion; (iii) how much
disclosure, transparency, and communications are there; and (iv) to what extent are policy instruments
market-based rather than administrative? The f irst of these is essentially the choice of exchange rate
arrangement. The remaining three relate to how the framework is implemented. These f our dimensions
cannot be chosen independently but must be consistent with one another. For example, a peg requires
sustainable fiscal policy and sufficient reserves for intervention. Other frameworks have their specific
requirements as well, and only in rare cases, the optimum is reached at the extremes (e.g., complete
transparency, zero discretion). Especially in advising on the design of various kinds of intermediate or
hybrid policy frameworks, it is essential to carefully consider these issues in light of country-specific
circumstances, and to find a workable mix.
In practice, the classification and assignment of policy instruments can be complex. Some policy
instruments have strong effects in more than one domain, and there may be ambiguities and overlaps in
how they are classified and used. A discussion of these issues is provided in Appendix 3.
V. Approach and IMF Tools
A. ANALYTICAL INSTRUMENTS
The application of the considerations and criteria set out above will usually require additional
analytical work. The assessment of the different factors at play and the identification of the exchange
rate regime that best suits each country can be challenging. To effectively address this issue, central
16
IMF staff have been developing open-econo my macroecono mic models that examine the interactions of interest
rate policy, FXI, CFMs, and macroprudential policies that guide the IMFs emerging Integrated Policy
Framework (IPF). For further information, see https://www.imf.org/en/Topics/IPF-Integrated-Po licy-Framework.
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 20
banks and other country authorities may need to increase their capacity. CD could significantly contribute
to this goal, together with the analytical work that is routinely performed by area departments.
The IMF provides a range of tools that can help inform the choice of exchange rate arrangement. A
more in-depth discussion of the various tools related to external stability can be found in the 2015
Guidance Note on Article IV Surveillance under Article IV Consultations (IMF, 2015b). MCM staff and
experts involved in the provision of TA on exchange rate policy should familiarize themselves with these
tools, including newer iterations, and with the assessments that are produced using them.
External balance assessments (EBA). EBA (Cubeddu and others, 2019) and EBA-Lite (IMF,
2019b). The "lite" version of the methodology is more readily applicable in low-income and other
developing economies.
Nominal and real effective exchange rates. Data for many countries are published in
International Financial Statistics (IMF, 2019a), and additional confidential data on some countries
are maintained in an internal database accessible to staff.
Debt sustainability analysis. Different methods have been developed for low-income countries
(updated in 2017-18) and market access countries (update expected late 2020).
Reserve adequacy metrics. Key papers (notably IMF, 2014) can be found at the following link.
Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP). Links to country reports can be found here.
Detailed technical notes on stress testing are often confidential and not published.
MCM Technical Assistance Logical Frameworks. The logical frameworks ("logframes") most
relevant f or the purposes of this chapter cover inflation targeting; monetary policy
communications; FX policy and operations; monetary policy implementation; and central bank
governance.
B. IMF POLICIES
Any advice on the exchange rate arrangement should be consistent with applicable IMF policies.
The legal basis for IMF advice on exchange rates is provided by the Articles of Agreement and the 2012
Integrated Surveillance Decision. Article IV, Section 3(a) instructs the IMF to "oversee the international
monetary system,” while Section 3(b) mandates "firm surveillance of the exchange rate policies of
members". The 2012 Surveillance Decision does not prescribe what type of exchange rate arrangement a
member country should choose. Rather, it specifies that each member should adopt policies, including
exchange rate policies, that "promote its own balance of payments stability and domestic stability" and
that such policies should not give rise to disruptive exchange rate movements. Accordingly, the 2012
Surveillance Decision mandates that exchange rate policies will "always be the subject" of bilateral
surveillance, along with monetary, fiscal, and financial sector policies. In the multilateral context,
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 21
exchange rate and other policies should also be consistent with the "effective operation" of the
international monetary system.
17
The Guidance Note for Surveillance under Article IV Consultations (IMF, 2015b) defines issues
related to exchange rate policies in further detail. Article IV staff reports are expected to “assess the
adequacy of the de facto regime for maintaining stability” and “take into account the authorities’ views,
and their readiness and capacity to implement changes,” when discussing alternative regimes. The
consistency of the exchange rate arrangement with the policy mix (fiscal stance, monetary objectives, and
f inancial regulation) should be considered.
18
Exchange rate policies should not be addressed in isolation,
but as part of a broader analysis of "(i) current accounts, (ii) real exchange rates, (iii) capital flows and
policy measures, (iv) FXI and reserve levels, and (v) external balance sheets." The guidance note spells
out the methodologies and tools relevant to this analysis.
Although the IMF does not have a formal position on the choice of an exchange rate arrangement,
advice provided by staff has at times, raised concerns that should be borne in mind. The IMF's
Independent Evaluation Office (IEO) notes in 2017 that several Directors, representing a significant
number of member countries, expressed concern about the IMF recommending that members introduce
more flexibility in managing their exchange rate regimes, particularly in the context of programs, without
enough attention to country circumstances or to the capacity of the country to manage this shift. In the
provision of CD, these concerns need to be addressed by ensuring that advice to change the exchange
rate arrangement is given only on the basis of a thorough analysis of the country's specific circumstances,
that the necessary analytical and operational capacity in the central bank and other relevant official
agencies has been put in place, and that the chosen framework also enjoys sustainable buy-in from
relevant stakeholders.
17
The international monetary system is considered to be operating effectively when the areas it governs do not
exhibit symptoms of malfunction, such as persistent significant current account imbalances, an unstable system of
exchange rates including foreign exchange rate misalig n ment, volatile capital flows, the excessive build up or
depletion of reserves, or imbalances arising from excessive or insufficient global liquidity.
18
In small developing states, reports should also consider the desirability and feasibility of exchange rate adjustment,
among other measures, to improve competitiveness.
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 22
References
Baliño, Tomás, Adam Bennett, and Eduardo Borensztein (1999). Monetary Policy in Dollarized
Economies,IMF Occasional Paper 171, (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Ben-Zeev, Nadav, (2019), Global Credit Supply Shocks and Exchange Rate Regimes,Journal of
International Economics, vol.116, pp.1-32.
Blundell-Wignall, Adrian, and Caroline Roulet, (2016). "Evaluating Capital Flow Management Measures
Used as Macro-Prudential To ols." OECD Journal: Financial Market Trends, vol. 2015, no. 2,
pp. 7-27.
Brandao-Marques, Luis, Gaston Gelos, Thomas Harjes, Ratna Sahay, and Yi Xue, (2020), Monetary
Policy Transmission in Emerging Markets and Developing Economies,” IMF Working Paper 20/35
(Washington: International Monetary Fund)
Broda, Christian, (2001), "Coping with Terms-of-Trad e Shocks: Peg versus Floats." American Economic
Review, May 2001, vol. 91, no. 2.
Carrière-Swallow, Yan, Nicolás E. Magud, and Juan F. Yépez, (2021), Exchange Rate Flexibility, The
Real Exchange Rate, and Adjustment to Terms-of-Trade Shocks.” Review of International
Economics, vol. 29, no. 2, pp. 439483.
Cubeddu, Luis, Signe Krogstrup, Gustavo Adler, Pau Rabanal, Mai Chi Dao, Swarnali Ahmed Hannan,
Luciana Juvenal, Nan Li, Carolina Osorio Buitron, Cyril Rebillard, Daniel Garcia-Macia, Callum
Jones, Jair Rodriguez, Kyun Suk Chang, Deepali Gautam, and Zijiao Wang, (2019). "The
External Balance Assessment Methodology: 2018 Update." IMF Working Paper 19/65,
(Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Davis, J. Scott, Ippei Fujiwara, and Jiao Wang, (2018), “Dealing with Time Inconsistency: Inf lation
Targeting Versus Exchange Rate Targeting,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 50(7),
pp. 1369-1399.
Fischer, Stanley, (2008), Mundell-Fleming Lecture: Exchange Rate Systems, Surveillance, and
Advice,” IMF Staff Papers, v ol. 55(3), pp. 367-383.
______, (2001), “Exchange Rate Regimes: Is the Bipolar View Correct? Journal of Economic
Perspectives, v ol. 15(2), pp. 3-24.
Frankel, Jeffrey (2003), “A Proposed Monetary Regime for Small-Commodity Exporters: Peg the Export
Price (PEP”).International Finance, vol. 6, no. 1, pp. 6188.
_____, (2005), “Peg the Export Price Index: A Proposed Monetary Regime for Small Countries.Journal
of Policy Modeling, vol. 27, no. 4, p p. 495508.
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 23
_____, (2012), "Choosing an Exchange Rate Regime." in Handbook of Exchange Rates, ed. by Jessica
James, Ian W. Marsh, and Lucio Sarna, ch. 28, pp. 765782, (Wiley: Hoboken, New Jersey).
Friedman, Milton, (1953). “The Case for Flexible Exchange Rates.in Essays in Positive Economics, ed .
by Milton Friedman, pp. 157203, (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).
Ghosh, Atish R., Anne-Marie Gulde, Jonathan D. Ostry, and Holger C. Wolf, (1997), Does the Nominal
Exchange Rate Regime Matter?NBER Working Paper 5874, (Cambridge: National Bureau of
Economic Research)
Ghosh, Atish R., Anne-Marie Gulde, and Holger C. Wolf, (2003), Exchange Rate Regimes: Choices and
Consequence, (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).
Ghosh, Atish R., Jonathan D. Ostry, and Charalambos G. Tsangarides, (2010), Exchange Rate Regimes
and the Stability of the International Monetary System.” IMF Occasional Paper No. 229,
(Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Ghosh, Atish R., Jonathan D. Ostry, and Mahvash S. Qureshi, (2015), Exchange Rate Management and
Crisis Susceptibility: A Reassessment, IMF Economic Review, v ol. 63(1), pp. 238-276.
Habermeier, Karl, Annamaria Kokenyne, Romain Veyrune, and Harald Anderson, (2009), "Revised
System for the Classification of Exchange Rate Arrangements." IMF Working Paper 09/211,
(Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Hofman, David, Marcos Chamon, Pragyan Deb, Thomas Harjes, Umang Rawat, and Itaru Yamamoto,
(2020), "Intervention Under Inf lation TargetingWhen Could it Make Sense?" IMF Working
Paper 20/9, (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Independent Evaluation Office (IEO) of the International Monetary Fund, (2017). IMF Exchange Rate
Policy Advice: Evaluation Update. Washington, D.C.
_____, (2020), IMF Advice on Capital Flows: Evaluation Report, (Washington).
International Monetary Fund, (2008), "Classification of Exchange Rate Arrangements." IMF Board Paper
SM/08/90 (unpublished), Washington, D.C.
_____, (2012), “The Liberalization and Management of Capital FlowsAn Institutional View,IMF Policy
Paper, (Washington).
_____, (2014), "Assessing Reserve AdequacySpecific Proposals." IMF Staff Report, (Washington).
_____, (2015a), "Measures Which are Both Macroprudential and Capital Flow Management Measures:
IMF Approach." IMF Group of Twenty Note, (Washington).
_____, (2015b), “Guidance Note for Surveillance Under Article IV Consultations.IMF SM/15/71,
(Washington).
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 24
_____, (2015c), “Evolving Monetary Policy Frameworks in Low-Income and Other Developing Countries.
IMF Staf f Report, (Washington).
_____, (2019a), "The IMF Updates the Effective Exchange Rates Indices." IMF Press Release No. 16/93,
(Washington).
_____, (2019b). "The Revised EBA-Lite Methodology." IMF Policy Paper No. 19/026, (Washington).
_____, (2020a), "Central Bank Transparency Code," Staff Report, (Washington).
Ize, Alain, and Eduardo Levy Yeyati, (2003), “Financial Dollarization.Journal of International Economics,
vol. 59, no. 2, pp. 323347.
Kokenyne, Annamaria, Jeremy Ley, and Romain Veyrune, (2010), "Dedollarization." IMF Working
Paper 10/188, (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Laurens, Bernard, Kelly Eckhold, Darryl King, Nils Maehle, Abdul Naseer, and Alain Durré, (2015), "The
Journey to Inf lation Targeting: Easier Said than Done. The Case for Transitional Arrangements
along the Road," IMF Working Paper 15/136, (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Levy Yeyati, Eduardo, and Federico Sturzenegger, (2003), “To Float or to Fix: Evidence on the Impact of
Exchange Rate Regimes on Growth, American Economic Review, vol. 93(4), pp. 1173-1193.
_______, (2010), "Monetary and Exchange Rate Policies." in Handbook of Development Economics, ed.
by Dani Rodrik and Mark R. Rosenzweig, Vol. 5, pp. 42154281, (Amsterdam: Elsevier).
Levy Yeyati, Eduardo, Federico Sturzenegger, and Iliana Reggio, (2010), "On the Endogeneity of
Exchange Rate Regimes." European Economic Review, vol. 54, no. 5, pp. 659677.
Martin, Fernando E., (2016), Exchange Rate Regimes and Current Account Adjustment: An Empirical
Investigation, Journal of international Money and Finance, vol. 65, p p. 69-93.
Mussa, Michael, Paul Masson, Alexander Swoboda, Esteban Jadresic, Paolo M auro , Paolo, and Andrew
Berg, (2000), “Exchange Rate Regimes in an Increasingly Integrated World Economy.” IMF
Occasional Paper No. 197, (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Obstfeld, Maurice, Jonathan. D. Ostry, and Mavash S. Qureshi, (2019), A Tie that Binds: Revisiting the
Trilemma in Emerging Mark et Economies,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 101(2),
pp. 279-293.
Plantin, Guillaume, and Hyun Song Shin, (2018), “Exchange Rates and Monetary Spillovers.Theoretical
Economics, vol. 13, no. 2, p p. 637666.
Poole, William, (1970), Optimal Choice of Monetary Policy Instruments in a Simple Stochastic Macro
Model,The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 84, no. 2, pp. 197-216.
Reinhart, Carmen. M., and Kenneth. S. Rogoff, (2004), The Modern History of Exchange Rate
Arrangements: A Reinterpretation,The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 119, no. 1, pp. 1-48.
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 25
Rey, Hélène (2015). "Dilemma Not Trilemma: The Global Financial Cycle and Monetary Policy
Independence." NBER Working Paper No . 21162, (Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic
Research)
Rogoff, Kenneth S., Aasim M. Husain, Ashoka M ody , Ro bin Brooks, and Nienke Oomes, (2004),
Evolution and Performance of Exchange Rate Regimes,” IMF Occasional Paper No. 229,
(Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Uribe, Martín, (2003). "Real Exchange Rate Targeting and Macroeconomic Instability." Journal of
International Economics, vol. 59, no. 1, pp. 137159.
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 26
Appendix I. Empirical Literature on the Choice of an Exchange
Rate Arrangement
Empirical work has examined all three theories of the choice of an exchange rate arrangement
(OCA, financial view, political view). Using a de facto classification, Levy Yeyati and others (2010)
identify the main drivers of the choice of exchange rate arrangement, highlighting important differences
between emerging markets and developing economies (EMDEs) and advanced economies. While the
implications of the OCA theory seem to apply to all countries, financial integration tends to have different
ef f ects on the two groups of countries. Higher financial and trade integration promotes flexible regimes in
advanced economies, supporting the impossible trinity view. By contrast, financial integration seems to
f avor the adoption of pegs among EMDEs, possibly because of large foreign currency-denominated
external liabilities and the associated currency mismatches. Regarding the political view, pegs appear
more likely when the country lacks adequate institutional credibility and capacity, but less so if the
government seems unable or unwilling to commit. Similarly, Davis and others (2018) show that the
probability of adopting a f ixed exchange rate regime increases with trade openness and decreases with
the level of central bank credibility or independence.
A large strand of the literature studies the effects of choosing an exchange rate arrangement. This
work is complementary to studies of the drivers of the choice: consequences and drivers are essentially
f lip sides of the same coin. Over the past two decades, the IMF has produced three major analytical
studies on the effects of the choice of exchange rate regimes. These reviews were conducted in 1999,
2003, and 2009 and subsequently published as Mussa and others (2000); Rogoff and others (2004); and
Ghosh and others (2010). The reviews drew on the existing empirical literature both inside and outside
the IMF (Ghosh and others, 1997; Ghosh and others, 2002; Levy Yeyati and Sturzenegger, 2003; and
Reinhart and Rogoff, 2004).
The findings reflect the evolution of views on the optimal choice of the exchange rate
arrangement. Based on de jure arrangements, the 1999 study supports the so-called bipolar prescription
(or corner hypothesis) articulated by Fischer (2001), who argues that countries should adopt either hard
pegs or free floats, on the grounds that intermediate regimes do not provide the same benefits as corner
solutions and involve important shortcomings, such as being more prone to crisis. The 2003 review,
which used a de facto instead of a de jure classification, finds that pegs provide little benefit to EMDEs in
terms of either inflation or growth performance. Because such regimes are associated with a greater
likelihood of currency or financial crises, the review concludes that EMDEs should adopt freely floating
exchange rates once sufficient financial integration has been achieved.
The third IMF review of 2009 represents a turning point in several respects. First, the findings
suggest that both de jure and de facto regimes matter. For instance, by using both de jure and de facto
classifications, the study shows that the poor macroeconomic performance associated with pegs found by
previous reviews seems to be driven by de facto pegs without a de jure commitment. This type of regime
does not deliver the same benefits in terms of price stability, as it lacks the credibility of a formal
commitment by the central bank. Second, intermediate regimes, especially managed floats, deliver the
best macroeconomic performance, at least in terms of growth. By combining the benefits of still relatively
low exchange rate volatility with a competitive level of the real exchange, intermediate regimes capture
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 27
the benef its of both pegs and free floats. Finally, the findings underscore that the key trade-off is not
between inf lation and growth, but rather between performance along these dimensions, and the greater
risk of crisis and delayed external adjustment, on the other.
The 2009 review provides support for a more nuanced approach to the optimal choice of the
exchange rate arrangement and continues to inform IMF policy advice. Rather than one-size-fits all
prescriptions, the approach over the past decade has been to take into account country-specific
circumstances. Countries would therefore choose the arrangement best suited to its particular economic
conditions, based on an evaluation of trade-offs among different objectives, notably nominal stability,
economic growth, reduced crisis risk, external adjustment, and fostering integration.
A key finding in the past decade is that floats can work better when accompanied by FXI. The
relevant literature is large and continues to grow quickly. Interestingly, Fischer (2008) qualifies the bipolar
view by adding managed floats to the safe end of the spectrum, rather than to the class of risky
intermediate regimes. More recently, Martin (2016) and Obstfeld and others (2019) find that flexible
regimes, including managed floats, contribute to insulating the economy from global financial shocks and
promote a faster correction of current imbalances. According to Ghosh and others (2015), floats are the
least prone to economic and financial crises, while intermediate exchange rate regimes are the most
susceptible. Crucially, central bank intervention to prevent overvaluation appears to be the key to
avoiding crises.
In sum, there is by now considerable empirical support for the view that free floating is only one
path to greater exchange rate flexibility, and that other flexible arrangements may also perform
well. Using FXI to dampen excessive movements in the exchange rate can be the preferred approach for
a broad range of reasons. Hofman and others (2020) provide an up-to-date and comprehensive review of
the arguments and relevant literature.
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 28
Appendix 2. Describing Exchange Rate Arrangements and Monetary Policy Frameworks
In describing exchange rate arrangements, CD should use the terms defined in the IMF's Annual
Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions (AREAER). The classification
scheme is described in the introduction to the AREAER and is explained in detail in Habermeier and
others (2009).
1
The typology of arrangements is similar to that found in the academic literature: it ranges
f rom those that are less flexible (such as currency boards and fixed pegs) through intermediate
arrangements (such as crawling pegs or other managed arrangements) to market-determined flexible
exchange rates (floating and free floating). An important characteristic of the classification methodology is
its systematic distinction between the arrangement officially announced by the authorities (de jure), and
the classification based on the observed characteristics the arrangement (de facto). The classification
exercise is conducted on an ongoing basis by IMF staff as part of multilateral and bilateral surveillance.
The classification of individual countries is a staff classification and while endorsed by management, does
not necessarily reflect the views of the IMF's Executive Board.
The AREAER also provides a cross-classification of monetary policy frameworks with exchange
rate arrangements. The categories used are (1) exchange rate anchors (with subcategories for the US
dollar, the euro, a composite, and others); (2) monetary aggregate targets; (3) inflation targets; and
(4) others. These broad categories are useful for tracking developments in monetary policy frameworks in
IMF member countries. This said, monetary policy frameworks are substantially more varied and complex
than these categories suggest and need to be characterized in greater detail in the context of TA.
1
This reference is based o n an unpublished IMF Board paper (IMF, 2008).
Monetary Policy FrameworksChoice of Exchange Rate Arrangement
IMF | MCM Technical Assistance Handbook 29
Appendix 3. Classification and Assignment of Policy Instruments
The classification and assignment of policy instruments can be complex. Some policy instruments
have strong effects in more than one domain, and there may be ambiguities and overlaps in how they are
classified and used. In designing monetary and exchange rate policy frameworks, these cross-effects and
cross-classifications need to be considered. It is also necessary to take account of which agencies
beyond the central bank are involved in various areas of policy, and how their responsibilities and
instruments are defined. Finally, categories of instruments such as CFMs and MPMs include a broad
range of very different tools.
The roles of different instruments within the policy framework need to be clearly specified.
Instruments will typically have a greater effect on some objectives than on others and will therefore need
to be assigned first-order and lower-order roles. Doing so will strengthen the efficacy of a central bank's
internal decision-making process. A clear specification of the roles of different instruments also underpins
ef f ective communications that support policy transmission through an improved public understanding of
policy objectives and what the use of particular instruments is intended to achieve. In particular:
Interest rates and OMOs. These are usually considered to be a tool for domestic monetary
control (or monetary policy instrument). However, OMOs can also be used to provide or withdraw
f oreign currency liquidity, and in that case, can serve to affect the exchange rate, and thus also
be considered as FXI. Similarly, under an exchange rate anchor, policy interest rates need to be
set in a manner consistent with the level of the exchange rate, and under pegged arrangements,
interest rate adjustments are often an important form of "indirect" FXI.
Reserve requirements. These are also usually considered to be a monetary policy instrument.
However, they can be used as a prudential policy instrument (either microprudential or
macroprudential), as a CFM when differentiated by the residency of the account holder, and as
FXI when dif ferentiated by currency and serving to affect the exchange rate.
CFMs and MPMs. CFMs serve to influence capital flows, and MPMs to influence systemic
f inancial risk. In addition to their primary aims, both categories of instruments can serve other
purposes. Delineation can be difficult in practice: is a measure a CFM only, an MPM, or a
CFM/MPM? The classification is also affected by the different legal and conceptual frameworks
used by the IMF (IMF, 2015a) and the OECD (Blundell-Wignall and Roulet, 2016). In applying the
Institutional View in Article IV surveillance (IMF, 2012), these distinctions have at times led to
disagreements between IMF staff and country authorities (IEO, 2020).
FXI. There is no single definition of FXI endorsed by the IMF Executive Board. Staff consider FXI
to be any official action that serves to affect the exchange rate. Intervention most commonly
involves outright purchases/sales of FX or FX derivatives by the central bank, the ministry of
f inance, or others working on behalf of these or other governmental or public sector authorities or
agencies. Though distinct from intervention, other policies (whether foreign or domestic) that have
an equivalent effect on the exchange rate and that are conducted for this purpose, for example,
the use of FX regulations and monetary policy to influence the exchange rate, are sometimes
referred to as “indirect intervention” and are considered as tantamount to intervention for the
purpose of classifying exchange rate arrangements (IMF, 2008).