1
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
______
Non-Compete Clause Rule
Docket No. 2023-0007
COMMENT OF
THE ANTITRUST DIVISION OF THE
UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
Jonathan Kanter
Assistant Attorney General
Doha Mekki
Principal Deputy Assistant Attorney
General
Maggie Goodlander
Deputy Assistant Attorney General
David Lawrence
Policy Director
Jacobus van der Ven
Counsel to the Assistant Attorney General
Karina Lubell, Chief
Jennifer Dixton, Assistant Chief
Danielle Drory, Attorney Advisor
Sarah Scheinman, Attorney Advisor
Competition Policy & Advocacy Section
U.S. Department of Justice
950 Pennsylvania Ave., N.W.
Washington, D.C. 20530-0001
Dated: April 19, 2023
2
The Antitrust Division of the United States Department of Justice (“Antitrust
Division”) respectfully submits this comment in response to the Federal Trade
Commission’s (“FTC”) request for public comment on its notice of proposed rulemaking
on the non-compete clause rule, as described in its Federal Register Notice published on
January 19, 2023.
1
The Antitrust Division unequivocally supports the FTC’s full exercise of its
rulemaking authority to address the anticompetitive effects of non-compete clauses. It
offers this comment to identify where the Antitrust Division’s own experience and
expertise provide support, in addition to those reasons set forth by the FTC, for the FTC’s
proposal to restrict the pervasive use of non-compete clauses throughout the United
States. The Antitrust Division commends the FTC for its efforts to promote worker
mobility and increase labor market competition.
I. INTEREST OF THE ANTITRUST DIVISION
The Antitrust Division, along with the FTC, is entrusted with enforcing the
federal antitrust laws. These laws reflect a legislative judgment that “[t]he heart of our
national economic policy long has been faith in the value of competition.”
2
For this
reason, the federal antitrust laws seek to protect economic freedom and opportunity by
promoting free and fair competition in the marketplace. As the Supreme Court has
explained, antitrust law serves as “a comprehensive charter of economic liberty aimed at
preserving free and unfettered competition as the rule of trade.
3
Protecting workers is a central goal of antitrust. Antitrust law and the essential
value of competition – applies equally to labor markets as to markets for other services
and products.
4
The Supreme Court has made clear (in the context of discussing the
Sherman Act) that antitrust law does “not confine its protection to consumers, or to
purchasers, or to competitors, or to sellers” but that the law is instead “comprehensive in
its terms and coverage, protecting all who are made victims of the forbidden practices by
whomever they may be perpetrated.”
5
A focus on workers is longstanding. The English
common law that pre-dated U.S. law saw the “impoverishing of poor artificers” as one of
the core harms of monopoly power.
6
For that reason, since at least Dyer’s Case in 1414,
1
Non-Compete Clause Rule, 88 Fed. Reg. 3482 (Jan. 19, 2023).
2
Nat’l Soc’y of Pro. Eng’rs v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 695 (1978) (quoting Standard Oil Co. v. FTC,
340 U.S. 231, 248 (1951)).
3
N. Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 4 (1958).
4
See NCAA v. Alston, 141 S. Ct. 2141, 2154-60 (2021); Anderson v. Shipowners’ Ass’n of Pac. Coast, 272
U.S. 359, 363-64 (1926); United States v. Jindal, No. CV 4:20-CR-00358, 2021 WL 5578687 at *5 (E.D.
Tex. Nov. 29, 2021) (“The Supreme Court has made clear that the Sherman Act applies equally to all
industries and marketsto sellers and buyers, to goods and services, and consequently to buyers of
servicesotherwise known as employers in the labor market.”).
5
Mandeville Island Farms, Inc. v. Am. Crystal Sugar Co., 334 U.S. 219, 236 (1948).
6
Denver & N.O.R. Co. v. Atchison, T. & S.F.R. Co., 15 F. 650, 672 (C.C.D. Colo. 1883) (quoting The Case
of Monopolies/Darcy v. Allen, 11 Coke, 84).
3
the law has looked with skepticism on restraints on workers’ future employment.
7
In
labor markets today, antitrust protections promote competition among employers,
contributing to higher wages, benefits, and working conditions for employees.
The Antitrust Division, therefore, sees promoting competition and challenging
anticompetitive practices in labor markets as critical to its mission. For years, it has
challenged firms and individuals that use anticompetitive employment practices such as
no-poach agreements, wage-fixing conspiracies, unlawful information exchanges, and
non-compete clauses that harm competition.
8
The Antitrust Division has also challenged
horizontal agreements between employers not to hire each other’s workers as criminal
violations of the antitrust laws.
9
In addition, the Antitrust Division has filed amicus
briefs and statements of interest in cases addressing employment restraints.
10
Anticompetitive employment agreements result in a range of harms by depriving workers
of a competitive market for their services and by depriving employers of a robust pool of
7
Dyers Case, Y.B. Mich. 2 Hen. 5, f. 5, pl. 26 (C.P. 1414).
8
See, e.g., United States v. Am. Tobacco Co., 221 U.S. 106, 181-83 (1911) (finding tobacco companies
violated both Section 1 and Section 2 of the Sherman Act because of the collective effect of six of the
companies’ practices, one of which was the “constantly recurring” use of non-compete clauses); United
States v. Patel, et al., No. 3:21-cr-220,-VAB 2022 WL 17404509, at *8-10 (D. Conn. Dec. 2, 2022)
(alleging defendants agreed to “restrict the hiring and recruiting of engineers and other skilled-labor
employees between and among” competitors); United States v. Manahe, No. 2:22-cr-00013-JAW, 2022
WL 3161781, at *7 (D. Me. Aug. 8, 2022) (“The Court concludes that the indictment alleges a recognized
per se illegal form of market allocation among purchasers of labor.”); United States v. Hee, No. 2:21-cr-
00098-RFB-BNW (D. Nev. Mar. 30, 2021); United States v. Surgical Care Affiliates, LLC, No. 3:21-cr-
00011-L (N.D. Tex. July 8, 2021); United States v. Cargill Meat Solutions Corp. et al., No. 1:22-cv-01821-
ELH (D. Md. July 25, 2022) (resolving unlawful exchange of wage and benefit information among chicken
processing plants).
9
See United States v. DaVita Inc., No. 1:21-CR-00229-RBJ, 2022 WL 266759, at *3 (D. Colo. Jan. 28,
2022) (denying defendants’ motion to dismiss criminal claims on the basis that naked non-solicitation
agreements or no-hire agreements to allocate the market are per se unreasonable, as “anticompetitive
practices in the labor market are equally perniciousand are treated the sameas anticompetitive
practices in markets for goods and services.”); see also United States v. Patel, 2022 WL 17404509, at *10-
11 (holding agreement described in indictment was appropriately subject to per se treatment as it described
a horizontal agreement to allocate employees in a specific labor market).
10
See, e.g., Brief for the United States and Federal Trade Commission as Amici Curiae, Deslandes v.
McDonald’s USA, LLC, No. 22-2333, 22-2334 (7th Cir. Nov. 9, 2022); Brief of the United States as
Amicus Curiae, Aya Healthcare Servs., Inc. v. AMN Healthcare, Inc., No. 20-55679 (9th Cir. Nov. 19,
2020); Statement of Interest of the United States, Markson v. CRST Int’l, Inc., No. 5:17-cv-01261-SB (SPx)
(C.D. Cal. July 15, 2022); Statement of Interest of the United States, In re Outpatient Med. Ctr. Emp.
Antitrust Litig., No. 1:21-cv-00305 (N.D. Ill. Dec. 9, 2021); Statement of Interest of the United States at 22-
23, Seaman v. Duke University, No. 1:15-CV-462 (M.D.N.C. Mar. 7, 2019) (no-poach agreements between
competing employers serve to allocate employees within a labor market); Statement of Interest of the
United States at 4, In re Ry. Indus. Emp. No-Poach Antitrust Litig., No. 2:18-MC-00798 (W.D. Pa. Feb. 8,
2019) (“no-poach agreements among competing employers are per se unlawful unless they are reasonably
necessary to a separate legitimate business transaction or collaboration among the employers”); Statement
of Interest of the United States at 11, Beck et al. v. Pickert Medical Group, P.C., et al., No. CV-21-02092
(2d Jud. Dist. Nev. Feb. 25, 2022) (asserting that even if non-compete agreements were ancillary to a
broader collaboration, “several allegations suggest they would be unreasonable under a rule-of-reason
analysis”).
4
available employees. They can reduce wages, limit workers’ employment options,
foreclose employers’ ability to access talent, and stifle innovation.
Accordingly, the Antitrust Division has significant expertise with respect to
competition issues in labor markets. Based on that experience and expertise, the
Antitrust Division agrees with the FTC’s assertion that non-compete clauses harm
competition in labor markets in the United States. The Antitrust Division supports the
FTC’s rulemaking effort to promote labor market competition by restricting
anticompetitive non-compete clauses.
11
II. THE ANTITRUST DIVISION BELIEVES THAT NON-COMPETE
CLAUSES HARM LABOR MARKET COMPETITION BY INHIBITING
WORKER MOBILITY
A. Non-compete clauses limit competition in design and effect. The Antitrust
Division, through its experience as an enforcer of the antitrust laws, has witnessed the
aggregate potential of these agreements to restrict worker mobility and dampen
competition in labor markets. Non-competes that are broad in scope, duration, and
geography are particularly problematic. For those reasons, like the FTC, the Antitrust
Division is concerned by the proliferation of non-competes throughout the U.S.
economy.
12
In addition to the Antitrust Division’s labor market enforcement experience and
the support offered by the FTC for its proposed rule, the Antitrust Division’s review of
empirical research demonstrates that non-compete clauses are pervasive and have a
deleterious impact on labor market competition.
13
This research shows that workers and
employers alike bear the costs of the non-competes.
14
11
88 Fed. Reg. 3508 (Non-compete clauses obstruct competition in labor markets because they inhibit
optimal matches from being made between employers and workers across the labor force. The available
evidence indicates increased enforceability of non-compete clauses substantially reduces workers’ earnings,
on average, across the labor force generally and for specific types of workers.”).
12
Id. 3501 (“The proliferation of non-compete clauses is restraining competition in labor markets to such a
degree that it is materially impacting workersearningsboth across the labor force in general, and also
specifically for workers who are not subject to non-compete clauses.”); Statement of Interest of the United
States at 11, Beck et al. v. Pickert Medical Group, P.C., et al., No. CV-21-02092 (2d Jud. Dist. Nev. Feb.
25, 2022).
13
See generally id. 3484-93 (discussing empirical research examining the effects of non-compete clauses
on labor and product markets).
14
See Natarajan Balasubramanian et al., Locked In? The Enforceability of Non-Compete Clauses and the
Careers of High-Tech Workers, 57 J.
HUM. RES. S349, S377 (2022) (finding earnings of new hires
increased by roughly 4% when Hawaii stopped enforcing non-compete clauses for high-tech workers);
Evan Starr, Justin Frake & Rajshree Agarwal, Mobility Constraint Externalities, 30 O
RG. SCI. 961 (2019)
(finding increased enforceability of non-compete clauses in a certain state and industry combination
coincided with a 6% decrease in earnings for workers who work in that same state and industry but did not
have a non-compete clause); see also Evan Starr et al., Screening Spinouts? How Noncompete
5
As to workers, mounting evidence indicates that non-competes cover a broad
swath of workers
15
and reduce their earnings.
16
The harmful effects of non-competes
extend to workers regardless of income, skill, and geography.
17
At least one study
suggests that non-compete usage may even negatively impact wages for workers who do
not themselves have a non-compete clause in their employment contract.
18
In addition,
given the existing patchwork of state laws governing non-competes, workers can often be
confused about the enforceability of non-compete clauses. This confusion can have the
same deterrent effect as non-competes that employers can enforce through legal action.
19
Non-compete clauses can also harm businesses as employers. They prohibit
businesses from freely hiring workers to meet their workforce needs
20
and negatively
impact business formation by preventing workers from starting their own businesses.
21
Enforceability Affects the Creation, Growth, and Survival of New Firms, 64 MGMT. SCI. 552, 561 (2018)
(finding that non-compete clauses reduce intra-industry spinoff entrepreneurial activity).
15
See Evan P. Starr et al., Noncompete Agreements in the U.S. Labor Force, 64 J. L. & ECON. 53, 60
(2021)
(finding that 38% of respondents have worked under a non-compete agreement at some point in
their lives); see also Natarajan Balasubramanian et al., Employment Restrictions on Resource
Transferability and Value Appropriation from Employees (Feb. 1, 2023),
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3814403 (finding 22.1% of survey respondents
currently work under a non-compete and noting this figure is consistent with results in prior studies);
Alexander J.S. Colvin & Heidi Shierholz, Noncompete Agreements, E
CON. POLY INST. (Dec. 10, 2019),
https://www.epi.org/publication/noncompete-agreements/ (finding that roughly half (49.4%) of survey
respondents of private-sector American business establishments indicated that at least some employees in
their establishment were required to enter into a noncompete agreement, regardless of pay or job duties).
16
See, e.g., Matthew S. Johnson, Kurt Lavetti & Michael Lipsitz, The Labor Market Effects of Legal
Restrictions on Worker Mobility 2 (2021), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3455381
(increasing non-compete enforceability by a certain metric would decrease workers’ earnings by 3-4%).
17
See Kurt Lavetti, Carol Simon & William D. White, The Impacts of Restricting Mobility of Skilled
Service Workers: Evidence from Physicians, 55 J.
HUM. RES. 1025, 1042 (2020) (reporting that 45% of
physicians worked under a non-compete clause in 2007); Matt Marx, The Firm Strikes Back: Non-Compete
Agreements and the Mobility of Technical Professionals, 76 A
M. SOCIO. REV. 695, 702 (2011) (finding
43% of electrical and electronic engineers signed a non-compete clause); Matthew S. Johnson & Michael
Lipsitz, Why Are Low-Wage Workers Signing Noncompete Agreements?, 57 J.
HUM. RES. 689, 700 (2022)
(finding 30% of hair stylists worked under a non-compete clause in 2015).
18
See Evan Starr et al., Mobility Constraint Externalities supra note 14.
19
See THE STATE OF LABOR MARKET COMPETITION 17, U. S. DEPT TREASURY (Mar. 7, 2022) (“While
guaranteed enforcement would strengthen their effects, uncertainty over enforcement can nonetheless affect
behavior (‘in terrorem’ effects). This is true even if the actual probability of a contract being enforced is
zero. So long as the perceived probability of an employer attempting to enforce the contract is non-zero,
restrictive employment agreements can create frictions.”); see also J.J. Prescott, Norman D. Bishara, &
Evan Starr, Understanding Noncompetition Agreements: The 2014 Noncompete Survey Project, 2016
M
ICH. ST. L. REV. 369, 377 (2016) (finding that the incidence of non-compete clauses in employment
contracts is not strongly correlated with their enforceability, suggesting employers include these clauses
even when they expect them to be unenforceable).
20
See Liyan Shi, Optimal Regulation of Noncompete Contracts, 92 ECONOMETRICA 425, 440 (2023)
(finding that firms must make inefficiently high payments to buy workers out of non-compete clauses with
former employers).
21
See, e.g., Sampsa Samila and Olav Sorenson, Noncompete Covenants: Incentives to Innovate or
Impediments to Growth, 57 M
GMT. SCI. 425, 432 (2011) (finding that an increase in capital funding
6
Talented employees are forced to sit out of labor markets covered by non-competes,
preventing businesses from employing key people that could spur the businesses’
success.
B. Although some employers – especially those of specialized and executive-
level employees assert interests in the post-employment conduct of certain employees,
the Antitrust Division does not believe that these interests justify the broad harms of non-
compete clauses on labor market competition.
Employers, for instance, may assert a need to prevent the disclosure of sensitive
business information from certain workers with specialized knowledge (although this
concern is not salient for most low-wage workers). But there already exists a large body
of federal law, state law, and contractual mechanisms targeted at this precise concern.
For instance, the FTC’s non-compete rulemaking does not circumvent the existing federal
and state laws on trade secrets or other protections on the disclosure of proprietary
information.
22
In addition, as the FTC observes in its rulemaking, less restrictive
covenants in employment agreements namely non-disclosure agreements are aimed at
protecting against the outflow of trade secrets and other valuable, confidential, or
sensitive business information that could threaten the firm if disclosed.
23
These
covenants, which are common and currently exist in many employment contracts,
24
mitigate employer concerns that departing employees will improperly disclose trade
secrets or business information. Unlike appropriately tailored non-disclosure agreements
and trade secret law, non-compete clauses are a blunt tool to address the targeted concern
of sharing sensitive information.
III. COMPETITIVELY HARMFUL NON-COMPETE CLAUSES ARE TOO
PERVASIVE FOR CASE-BY-CASE ADJUDICATION TO ADDRESS
FULLY
Case-by-case adjudication of anticompetitive non-compete clauses is an important
enforcement tool. But – in addition to the reasons set forth in the preamble to the
proposed rule
25
the Antitrust Division’s experience suggests that case-by-case
adjudication is not well suited to remedy the aggregate anticompetitive effects of
pervasive non-compete clauses by itself.
increased the number of new firms by nearly three times the amount when non-competes were not
enforceable as compared to when they were enforceable).
22
See 88 Fed. Reg. 3505-08; Defend Trade Secrets Act of 2016, Pub. L. No. 114-153, § 2(a), 130 Stat. 376,
376-80 (codified at 18 U.S.C. § 1836(b)). Trade secret protection also derives from state law. See
generally Kewanee Oil Co. v. Bicron Corp., 416 U.S. 470 (1974); see also Defend Trade Secrets Act § 2(f)
(“Nothing in the amendments made by this section shall be construed . . . to preempt any other provision of
law.”).
23
88 Fed. Reg. 3487 (citing Natarajan Balasubramanian et al., supra note 14).
24
Id.
25
See id. 3538.
7
As the FTC’s proposed rule explains, approximately one in five American
workers, which amounts to approximately 30 million people, are restricted by non-
compete clauses.
26
The impact of these clauses is cumulative. A high frequency of non-
competes has the ability to affect the opportunities of all workers in that market.
27
But
while the cumulative effects of pervasive non-compete clauses are significant, the effects
of individual non-compete clauses tend to be small relative to the cost of litigation. Even
firm-wide cases have limited impact with respect to a widely prevalent practice with
cumulative effects. That reality has contributed to the pervasiveness of anticompetitive
non-competes throughout the U.S economy in ways that case-by-case adjudication has
been, and will likely continue to be, unable to address fully.
Administrability challenges are also significant for case-by-case adjudication at
the state level. The existing patchwork of state laws governing non-competes may leave
the same worker free to move from job to job in one jurisdiction but subject to a non-
compete in the next, resulting in “considerable uncertainty” for both firms and workers as
to whether a particular non-compete could be enforced.
28
IV. CONCLUSION
The Antitrust Division shares the FTC’s concern that many Americans across the
country are unnecessarily burdened by non-compete clauses. In addition to the reasons
detailed in the preamble to the notice of proposed rulemaking, the Antitrust Division’s
experience and expertise supports the FTC’s view that these restraints harm workers and
businesses alike, restricting mobility for workers and access to workers for businesses. In
the Antitrust Division’s view, the aggregate impact of these clauses leads to reduced
labor market competition to the detriment of our economy, often resulting in lower wages
and a potential reduction in innovation. Case-by-case adjudication has struggled to
address fully this aggregate harm. The Antitrust Division commends the FTC for its
efforts to promote worker mobility and labor market competition and vigorously supports
the FTC’s full exercise of its rulemaking authority to address the anticompetitive effects
of non-compete clauses.
Respectfully Submitted,
/s/ Jonathan Kanter
_______________________________________________
Jonathan Kanter
Assistant Attorney General
Antitrust Division
26
See id. 3482.
27
See id. 3501.
28
See id. 3495-96 (noting “significant variation” in courts’ application of choice of law rules in disputes
over non-compete clauses, along with potential changes to state non-compete law, leads to “considerable
uncertainty” as to whether a non-compete clause is enforceable); see also Evan P. Starr et al., Noncompete
Agreements in the U.S. Labor Force, supra note 15, at
60 (finding that nearly 30 percent of employees
themselves do not know if they have signed a non-compete agreement).