1
“Land of Hope and Dreams: Rock and Roll, Economics and Rebuilding the Middle Class”
Alan B. Krueger, Chairman, Council of Economic Advisers
June 12, 2013
Cleveland, OH
Remarks as prepared for delivery
Introduction
Thank you very much for your kind introduction. I have always felt that this is a magnificent
museum, one of the few in the world that brings people of all backgrounds together, young and
old, rich and poor – there is something here for everyone to marvel at. Particularly at a time
when economic forces have been chipping away at the middle class for decades, I think it is
essential to have institutions like the Rock and Roll Hall of Fame that can bring people together,
and remind us that we are one nation, united by our hopes and dreams.
I gave this talk the title, “Land of Hope and Dreams: Rock and Roll, Economics and Rebuilding
the Middle Class” because many of the forces that are buffeting the U.S. economy can be
understood in the context of the music industry. I have also learned from 25 years of teaching
that the best way to explain economics is through the example of the rock ‘n roll industry.
The music industry is a microcosm of what is happening in the U.S. economy at large. We are
increasingly becoming a “winner-take-all economy,” a phenomenon that the music industry has
long experienced. Over recent decades, technological change, globalization and an erosion of
the institutions and practices that support shared prosperity in the U.S. have put the middle class
under increasing stress. The lucky and the talented – and it is often hard to tell the difference –
have been doing better and better, while the vast majority has struggled to keep up.
These same forces are affecting the music industry. Indeed, the music industry is an extreme
example of a “super star economy,” in which a small number of artists take home the lion’s share
of income.
The music industry has undergone a profound shift over the last 30 years. The price of the
average concert ticket increased by nearly 400% from 1981 to 2012, much faster than the 150%
rise in overall consumer price inflation (slide 1). And prices for the best seats for the best
performers have increased even faster.
At the same time, the share of concert revenue taken home by the top 1% of performers has more
than doubled, rising from 26 percent in 1982 to 56 percent in 2003 (slide 2). The top 5 percent
take home almost 90 percent of all concert revenues.
This is an extreme version of what has happened to the U.S. income distribution as a whole. The
top 1% of families doubled their share of income from 1979 to 2011 (slide 3). In 1979, the top
1% took home 10 percent of national income, and in 2011 they took home 20%. By this
2
measure, incomes in the entire U.S. economy today are almost as skewed as they were in the
rock ‘n roll industry when Bruce Springsteen cut “Born in the U.S.A.”
In my talk, I will focus on why these dramatic changes are taking place and explore their
consequences. I will also describe President Obama’s vision for providing more opportunities
for middle class families and those struggling to get into the middle class.
I should be clear about my overall theme: while the U.S. economy is recovering from the worst
financial and economic crisis since the Great Depression, we must also take steps to strengthen
the middle class and provide more opportunities for those born to less fortunate circumstances.
If we don’t, we will fail to live up to our promise as a Nation and be susceptible to the kinds of
forces that created economic instability in the past. To rebuild the economy from the middle out,
the private sector will have to step up and reinvigorate the norms and institutions that have
supported inclusive growth in the past. The government has an important role to play as well, but
with severe budget constraints and limited political will, the government can only set the
conditions for the private sector to grow, and provide more jobs and opportunities for middle
class families. It is, to a considerable extent, up to private sector businesses, organizations and
communities to ensure that economic growth leads to widely shared prosperity and a decent
living for the vast majority of our people.
Let me start with the economics of the music industry, and then turn to the economy at large.
Rockonomics
I want to highlight four factors that are important in generating a superstar economy. These are
technology, scale, luck and an erosion of social norms that compress prices and incomes. All of
these factors are affecting the music industry.
The idea of a “super star economy” is very old. It goes back to Alfred Marshall, the father of
modern microeconomics.
1
In the late 1800s, Marshall was trying to explain why some
exceptional businessmen amassed great fortunes while the incomes of ordinary artisans and
others fell. He concluded that changes in communications technology allowed “a man
exceptionally favored by genius and good luck” to command “undertakings vaster, and
extending over a wider area, than ever before.”
Ironically, his example of a profession where the best performers were unable to achieve such
super star status was music. Marshall wrote, “so long as the number of persons who can be
reached by a human voice is strictly limited, it is not very likely that any singer will make an
advance on the £10,000 said to have been earned in a season by Mrs. Billington at the beginning
of the last century, nearly as great [an increase] as that which the business leaders of the present
generation have made on those of the last.”

1
Alfred Marshall, Principles of Economics, MacMillan, 1890, p. 728.
3
Elizabeth Billington reputedly was a great soprano with a strong voice, but she did not have
access to a microphone or amplifier in 1798, let alone to MTV, CDs, iTunes, and Pandora. She
could only reach a small audience. This limited her ability to dominate the market.
Modern economists have elaborated on Alfred Marshall’s insights. The economist Sherwin
Rosen developed a theoretical model in which super star effects are driven by “imperfect
substitution” and “scale” in production.
2
Simply put, imperfect substitution means that you
would rather listen to one song by your favorite singer than a song and a half by someone else.
Or, in another context, it means that if you need to have heart surgery, you would rather have the
best surgeon in Cleveland perform it rather than the second and third best together.
Scale means that one performer can reach a large audience.
Technological changes through the centuries have long made the music industry a super star
industry. Advances over time including amplification, radio, records, 8-tracks, music videos,
CDs, iPods, etc., have made it possible for the best performers to reach an ever wider audience
with high fidelity.
And the increasing globalization of the world economy has vastly increased the reach and
notoriety of the most popular performers. They literally can be heard on a worldwide stage.
But advances in technology have also had an unexpected effect. Recorded music has become
cheap to replicate and distribute, and it is difficult to police unauthorized reproductions. This has
cut into the revenue stream of the best performers, and caused them to raise their prices for live
performances.
My research suggests that this is the primary reason why concert prices have risen so much since
the late 1990s.
3
In this spirit, David Bowie once predicted that “music itself is going to become
like running water or electricity,” and, that as a result, artists should “be prepared for doing a lot
of touring because that’s really the only unique situation that’s going to be left.”
4
While concerts
used to be a loss leader to sell albums, today concerts are a profit center.
But there are limits to how much artists can charge their fans for concert tickets because of social
pressures. Most people do not want to think of their favorite singer as greedy. There are a lot of
great singers to choose from. Would you rather listen to a singer who is committed to social
causes you identify with, or one who is only in it for the money? Part of what you are buying
when you buy a recording or concert ticket is the image of the performers. The image and the
music are intrinsically linked.
Some of our greatest artists have also been great champions of important social and economic
causes, including George Harrison, Joan Baez and Bono.

2
Sherwin Rosen, “The Economics of Superstars,” The American Economic Review, 1981, Vol. 71, Issue 5: 845-858.
3
Alan Krueger, “The Economics of Real Superstars: The Market for Rock Concerts in the Material World,” Journal
of Labor Economics, 2005, Vol. 23, No. 1: 1-30.
4
“David Bowie, 21st-Century Entrepreneur,” New York Times, June 9, 2002.
4
If artists charge too much for their tickets, they risk losing their appeal. In this sense, the market
for rock ‘n roll music is different from the market for commodities, or stocks and bonds.
Considerations of fair treatment exert pressure on how much musicians can charge, even
superstars.
Along these lines, one of my favorite performers, Tom Petty, once said, “I don’t see how carving
out the best seats and charging a lot more for them has anything to do with rock & roll.”
5
And artists like Garth Brooks and, more recently, Kid Rock have made a point of charging a low
price for all of the seats in the house when they perform.
6
In fact, the best seats for the hottest concerts have historically been underpriced.
7
This is a major
reason why there is a market for scalped tickets.
But many artists have been reluctant to raise prices to what the market will bear for fear of
garnering a reputation of gouging their fans.
They also protest when tickets sell for a higher price on the secondary market, and often try to
prevent the secondary market entirely. And it is considered scandalous when performers sell
tickets on the secondary market themselves.
This behavior can only be explained in light of fairness considerations. Singers want to be
viewed as treating their fans fairly, rather than charging them what supply and demand dictate.
Indeed, you can think of market demand as depending on the perception of fairness.
In many respects, concerts could be thought of as a giant block party instead of a traditional
market. While it is socially appropriate to charge neighbors some fee for coming to a block party
to pay for the provisions, it is inappropriate to charge them enough to make a hefty profit. There
is a compact that fans come and bring their enthusiasm and support for the band, and the band
charges a reasonable price and puts on a good show.
Now, as inequality has increased in society in general, norms of fairness have been under
pressure and have evolved.
Prices have risen for the best seats at the hottest shows – and made it possible for the best artists
to make over $100 million for one tour – but this has come with a backlash from many fans who
feel that rock ‘n roll is straying from its roots. And this is a risk to the entire industry.
Let me next turn to the role of luck. I said “best artists,” but I also could have added luckiest
artists. Luck plays a major role in the rock ‘n roll industry. Success is hard to judge ahead of

5
“The Ten Things That Piss off Tom Petty,” Rolling Stone Magazine, November 14, 2002.
6
“Kid Rock’s Plan to Change the Economics of Touring,” The Wall Street Journal, June 7, 2013.
7
See Marie Connolly and Alan Kruger, “Rockonomics: The Economics of Popular Music,” Handbook of the
Economics of Art and Culture, 2006; and Marie Connolly and Alan Krueger, “Evidence on the Secondary Market
for Concert Tickets,” unpublished, 2008.
5
time, and definitely not guaranteed, even for the best performers. Tastes are fickle, and herd
behavior often takes over.
Even the experts, with much at stake, have difficulty picking winners. Columbia Records turned
down Elvis Presley in 1955 and the Beatles in 1963. They turned down Bob Dylan in 1963, and
almost rejected “Like a Rolling Stone” in 1965, which was later named the greatest rock ‘n roll
song ever by Rolling Stone magazine.
8
Or consider Sixto Rodriguez, the subject of the documentary movie Searching for Sugar Man.
Rodriguez recorded two-and-a-half albums from 1970 to 1975, which were commercial flops.
But he was a huge success in South Africa, and his music became the battle hymn of the anti-
Apartheid movement. And – amazingly – he was unaware of his fame and influence.
Both good and bad luck play a huge role in the rock ‘n roll industry. And the impact of luck is
amplified in a superstar economy.
This was clearly demonstrated in a fascinating experiment conducted by the sociologists Matt
Salganik and Duncan Watts.
9
With the musicians’ permission, the researchers posted 48 songs
in an online music library. Subjects were invited to log on to the library and sample the songs,
with the opportunity to download the songs for free (slide 4). Participants could see the list of
songs, ranked by the number of times each one had been downloaded up to that point. They
could also see the exact download counts, so they were aware of the popularity of each song
based on the collective opinions of other participants (slide 5). From there, the subjects could
click on a song to play it, and then were given the option to download the song for free (slide 6).
For the first 750 participants, the researchers faithfully tallied and displayed the number of
downloads. However, the subsequent 6,000 participants were randomly – and unknowingly –
assigned to one of two alternative universes. In one universe, they continued to see the true
download counts (slide 7).
For the other participants, the researchers deviously created an alternative universe where the
download counts had been flipped, so that the 48
th
song was listed as the most popular song, the
47
th
song was listed as the number two song, and so on.
10
After this one-time inversion in the
ranking, the researchers let the download tallies grow on their own. They wanted to see if the
cream would rise to the top, or if the boost in ranking that the worst song received would lead it
to become popular.
Here’s what happened in the world where the download counts were presented accurately (slide
8). By the end of the experiment, the top song (“She Said” by Parker Theory) had been
downloaded over 500 times, while the least popular song (“Florence” by Post Break Tragedy)

8
“The Hit We Almost Missed,” The New York Times, December 3, 2004.
9
See Matthew Salganik and Duncan Watts, “Leading the Herd Astray: An Experimental Study of Self-Fulfilling
Prophecies in an Artificial Cultural Market,” Social Psychology Quarterly, 2008, Vol. 71, No. 4: 338-355. My
description of their work combines two of their alternative universes to provide a simplified overview of their
experiment, but is faithful to their main findings.
10
All participants provided informed consent before taking part in the experiment.
6
had been downloaded just 29 times – so the natural outcome of the experiment was that the most
popular song was nearly 20 times more popular than the least popular song.
Now let’s see what happened when the download counts were flipped, so that the new
participants thought the least popular song was actually the most popular. As you can see, the
download count for the least popular song grew much more quickly when it was artificially
placed at the top of the list. And the download count for the most popular song grew much more
slowly when it was artificially placed at the bottom of the list.
In the alternative world that began with the true rankings reversed, the least popular song did
surprisingly well, and, in fact, held onto its artificially bestowed top ranking. The most popular
song rose in the rankings, so fundamental quality did have some effect. But, overall – across all
48 songs – the final ranking from the experiment that began with the reversed popularity
ordering bore absolutely no relationship to the final ranking from the experiment that began with
the true ordering. This demonstrates that the belief that a song is popular has a profound effect
on its popularity, even if it wasn’t truly popular to start with.
A more general lesson is that, in addition to talent, arbitrary factors can lead to success or failure,
like whether another band happens to release a more popular song than your band at the same
time. The difference between a Sugar Man, a Dylan and a Post Break Tragedy depends a lot
more on luck than is commonly acknowledged.
Decent Wages
Let me next turn to the economy more generally. The same forces of technology, scale, luck and
the erosion of social pressures for fairness that are making rock ‘n roll more of a superstar
industry also are causing the U.S. economy to become more of a winner-take-all affair.
The effects of technological change and globalization on inequality have been well documented
in the past.
It is abundantly clear that computer and information technology has revolutionized the way work
is done in the U.S. In 1984, less than a quarter of workers directly used a computer on their
job.
11
Today, nearly two thirds of workers directly touch a keyboard at work, and millions of
others have had their jobs altered by embedded computers and information technology.
12
Computer and information technology has reduced the demand for jobs that can be routinized,
and increased the demand for highly educated workers who can use the technology to increase
their productivity.
13

11
Alan Krueger, “How Computers Have Changed The Wage Structure: Evidence From Microdata, 1984-1989,” The
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1989, Vol. 108, No. 1: 33-60.
12
Census Bureau. Computer and Internet Use in The United States: 2010; Bureau of Labor Statistics; CEA
calculations.
13
See, for examples, George Johnson, “Changes in Earnings Inequality: The Role of Demand Shifts,” Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 1997, 11(2): 41-54; and David Autor, Lawrence Katz and Alan Krueger, “Computing
Inequality: Have Computers Changed the Labor Market?” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1998, Vol. 113. No.
4: 1169-1214.
7
The U.S. economy has also become much more integrated with the world economy in recent
decades. While exports and imports made up only 11 percent of GDP in 1970, they made up 31
percent last year.
14
You see signs of globalization everywhere: for example, American bands
tour much more internationally today than they used to. A more globally connected economy
increases the reach of successful entrepreneurs and artists, but also brings many more low-wage
workers into competition with our workforce.
These developments have contributed to some of the momentous changes we have seen in the
U.S. economy. This chart shows the share of total income going to the top 1% of families
starting in 1920 (slide 9).
15
During the Roaring ‘20s inequality was very high, with the top 1%
taking in nearly 20% of total income. This remained the case until World War II. Price and
wage controls and the patriotic spirit that “we’re all in it together” during World War II caused
inequality to fall. Interestingly, the compression in income gaps brought about by World War II
persisted through the 1950s, 1960s and 1970s. Beginning in the 1980s, however, inequality rose
significantly in the U.S., with the share of income accruing to the top 1% rising to heights last
seen in the Roaring ‘20s.
After World War II, a social compact ensured that workers received a fair share of the gains of
economic growth. This was enforced by labor unions, progressive taxation, a minimum wage
that increased in value, anti-discrimination legislation and expanding educational opportunities.
This social compact was good for business and good for the economy. But the social compact
began to fray in the 1980s.
16
You can see from the following chart that wages of production and
nonsupervisory workers moved pretty much in lockstep with productivity until the late 1970s
(slide 10).
17
Since the 1980s, however, labor compensation has failed to keep pace with
productivity growth, and this has put stress on middle class workers.
The next two charts show what has happened to income growth in other parts of the distribution.
The charts show average annual income growth for families broken down to whether they are in
the poorest fifth, second poorest fifth, and so on.
First look at the post-war period through 1979 (slide 11). All segments grew together. But since
1979, the top has done better than the middle – which has barely grown over three decades – and
those in the bottom have done even worse, with real income declining (slide 12).

14
Census Bureau. 2013. U.S. Trade in Goods and Services-Balance of Payments (BOP) Basis.
15
To allow for international comparisons in subsequent slides, capital gains are excluded from the data in this chart.
The top 1% income share in the U.S. doubled from 1979 to 2011 irrespective of whether capital gains are included.
16
Emanuel Saez and Thomas Piketty attribute the post-1980 rise in inequality, in part, to a “retreat of institutions
developed during the New Deal and World War II – such as progressive tax policies, powerful unions, corporate
provision of health and retirement benefits, and changing social norms regarding pay inequality.” Thomas Piketty
and Emmanuel Saez, “Inequality in the United States, 1913-1998,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2003, Vol.
118, No. 1: 1-38.
17
Note that output and wages were both deflated by the nonfarm business output deflator. Deflating wages by the
Consumer Price Index would expand the gap between output and compensation.
8
An astonishing 84 percent of total income growth from 1979 to 2011 went to the top 1 percent of
families, and more than 100 percent of it from 2000 to 2007 went to the top 1 percent.
These trends are driven by a pulling apart of wages, with much faster wage growth for the
highest income earners over the last three decades, and wages barely keeping pace with inflation
or falling behind for everyone else.
Now the forces that brought about these changes were not unique to the U.S., but they have had a
more dramatic effect in the U.S. Consider the following chart again with other countries added
(slide 13). Inequality has followed a broadly similar trend in the U.K., France and Sweden, for
example. But notice that the level of inequality varies considerably across these countries, and
the rise in the share going to the top 1% varies considerably as well. In Sweden, for example, the
share of income brought home by the top 1% rose just 3 percentage points, from 4% in 1980 to
7% in 2011, while in the U.S. it doubled from 10% to 20%.
18
The widely differing responses to globalization and technological change suggest that other
factors mediate these forces.
This brings me to discuss the role of luck, education and institutions that ensure that prosperity is
broadly shared.
Globalization and technological change have increased the payoff to completing more education.
Countries that have expanded access to education have weathered the polarizing effects of
technological change and globalization to a better extent.
19
To demonstrate the economic benefit of education, I’ll describe a study that a colleague and I
conducted not very far from here, in Twinsburg, OH.
20
For four summers in a row in the 1990s,
we went to the Twins Days Festival in Twinsburg. We interviewed identical twins about their
education and their incomes. We were particularly interested in knowing whether a twin who
had more education than his sibling also had higher income.
The following graph shows the difference in wage rates and years of education between pairs of
twins. You can see that, on average, twins with higher education tend to earn more than their
other half with less education (slide 14).
On average, we find that completing four more years of education is associated with 60 percent
higher wages. This and other studies demonstrate that education has a high payoff, on average.
But, as we saw in the rock ‘n roll industry, luck also matters. Consider identical twins with the
same level of education. They were raised by the same family, under the same roof, and
typically were dressed alike and went to the same school. They are as alike as two peas in a pod
(slide). Yet in most cases they have very different economic outcomes as adults. Earnings

18
The figures cited for the U.S. here include capital gains. If capital gains are excluded, it rose from 8 to 17 percent.
19
OECD. 2001. The Well-being of Nations: The Role of Human and Social Capital. OECD Publishing.
20
Orley Ashenfelter and Alan Krueger, “Estimates of the Economic Return to Schooling from a New Sample of
Twins,” The American Economic Review, 1994,Volume 84, Issue 5: 1157-1183.
9
differed by 25% or more for pairs of identical twins in half of our sample. And earnings differed
by more than 50% in a quarter of identical twins with identical school levels.
These discrepancies for such similar workers suggest that luck is an important factor in the labor
market, as well as in the music industry.
As in the music industry, the effect of luck is amplified in a winner-take-all economy. Consider
the pay of CEO’s.
The pay of top executives relative to their workers has soared since the 1980s. In 1965 the
average CEO earned about 18 times as much as the average worker; now the average CEO earns
over 200 times as much (slide 15). As in Alfred Marshall’s time, successful executives can now
command undertakings on a much vaster scale. This undoubtedly has played a role.
But luck and an erosion of norms of fairness have also boosted CEO pay in many cases.
For example, Marianne Bertrand and Sendhil Mullainathan show that the compensation paid to
CEO’s of oil companies jumps when the price of oil rises.
21
Since the price of oil is set on a
world market, with gyrations caused by geopolitical forces well beyond the control of CEO’s,
movements in the price of oil have nothing to do with their job performance. Yet they benefit
when the price of oil rises.
Next, let me consider the role that fairness plays in the economy. We already saw that social
pressures for fairness affect the concert industry.
Workers, like music fans, expect to be treated fairly, and if they perceive they are paid unfairly
their morale and productivity suffer.
To examine the role of fairness at the workplace, in a recent experiment Ernst Fehr and
coauthors randomly varied the pay of members of pairs of workers who were hired to sell
membership cards to discotheques in Germany.
22
Obviously, it is not fair if, by luck of the draw,
your pay is lower than that of your co-worker who was hired to do the exact same job. They
found that increasing the disparity in pay between pairs of workers decreased the productivity of
the two workers combined. Their findings suggest that a more equal distribution of wages would
be good for business because it would raise morale and productivity.
This conclusion is reinforced by fascinating new research by Alex Edmans of Wharton. Edmans
finds that when a company makes the list of the “100 Best Companies to Work for in America”
its stock market value subsequently rises by 2 to 4 percent per year.
23
Because employee morale

21
Marianne Bertrand and Sendhil Mullainathan, “Are CEOs Rewarded for Luck? The Ones Without Principals
Are,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2001, Vol. 116. No. 3: 901-932-1214.
22
Alain Cohn, Ernst Fehr, Benedikt Herrmann, and Frederic Schneider, “Social Comparison in the Workplace:
Evidence from a Field Experiment,” IZA Working Paper 5550, March 2011.
23
Alex Edmans, “The Link Between Job Satisfaction and Firm Value, With Implications for Corporate Social
Responsibility,” Academy of Management Perspectives, 2012, 26: 1-19.
10
and compensation are key factors in determining whether a company makes the list, this result
suggests that treating workers fairly is in shareholders’ interests. Unfortunately, too many
executives have strayed from this ethic, to the detriment of their shareholders and the economy.
The notion that profitable companies should share some of their success with their workforce
used to be ingrained in U.S. companies. Earlier studies have found that companies and industries
that are profitable tend to pay all of their workers relatively well, the managers as well as the
janitors.
24
In economics we call this “rent sharing”. While this is still the case, the practice has
been eroded. The following chart shows the relationship between the average pay of managers
and janitors across industries in the 2000s (slide 16). The correlation is 0.7, indicating that pay is
higher for janitors in industries where managers are relatively well paid. If the same analysis is
done using data for 1980s, however, the correlation is higher (0.8), indicating that there used to
be a stronger tendency for janitors’ pay to move together with that of managers in their industry.
This suggests that companies are less likely to share their profits with all workers.
It is not hard to find reasons why the institutions and practices that long enforced norms of
fairness in the labor market have been eroded. At a time when market forces were pushing an
increasing share of before-tax income toward the wealthiest Americans, the previous
administration cut taxes disproportionately for the well off.
Even earlier, in the 1980s when inequality was starting to take off, the nominal value of the
minimum wage was left unchanged from 1981 to 1989, causing it to decline in the value by 27
percent after accounting for inflation. The minimum wage serves as an important anchor for
other wages, and the whole wage scale was brought down by the decline in the minimum wage.
25
A lower minimum wage and regressive tax changes sent a clear signal that maintaining fairness
was not a priority.
And policies and tactics that undermined the ability of workers’ to join unions and exercise their
right to collectively bargain weakened a critical institution that has long fought for fairness in the
labor market, and served to strengthen the middle class, both for union members and
nonmembers.

24
See Sumner Slichter, “Notes on the Structure of Wages,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 1950; John T.
Dunlop, “The Task of Contemporary Wage Theory,” in The Theory of Wage Determination, John Dunlop, ed.
London: Macmillan, 1957, pp. 3-27; Erica Groshen, “Sources of Wage Dispersion: The Contribution of
Interemployer Differentials within Industry,” Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, 1988; William Dickens and
Lawrence Katz, “Inter-Industry Wage Differences and Industry Characteristics,” in K. Lang and J. Leonard,
Unemployment & the Structure of Labor Markets, Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1987; and Alan Krueger and Lawrence
Summers, “Reflections on the Inter-Industry Wage Structure,” in the Lang and Leonard volume.
25
See, for examples, David Card and Alan Krueger, Myth and Measurement: The New Economics of the Minimum
Wage, Princeton University Press, 1995, Chapter 5; and David Lee, “Wage Inequality in the United States During
the 1980s: Rising Dispersion or Falling Minimum Wage?” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1999.
11
Consequences
While we rightly celebrate the achievements of those who have been able to scale new heights of
success in our economy, the shift toward becoming more of a winner-take-all economy has also
had a number of adverse consequences for the U.S. economy that merit great concern.
I’ll highlight three.
First, the three-decades’ long stagnation in real income for the bottom half of families threatens
our long cherished goal of equality of opportunity. In a winner-take-all society, children born to
disadvantaged circumstances have much longer odds of climbing the economic ladder of
success. Indeed, research has found that countries that have a high degree of inequality also tend
to have less economic mobility across generations.
This is shown in the next chart, which displays a plot of the degree of income mobility across
generations in a country on the Y-axis (the intergenerational income elasticity) against a measure
of the extent of inequality in that country in the mid-1980s (the Gini coefficient for after-tax
income) on the X-axis (slide 17).
26
A little over a year ago, I called this relationship “the Great
Gatsby curve,” because F. Scott Fitzgerald’s novel highlighted the inequality of the Roaring ‘20s
and class distinctions – I had no idea they would remake the movie as a result!
Each point in the graph represents a country. Higher values along the X-axis reflect greater
inequality in family resources roughly around the time that the children were growing up.
Higher values on the Y-axis indicate a lower degree of economic mobility across generations.
The points cluster around an upward sloping line, indicating that countries that had more
inequality across households also had more persistence in income from one generation to the
next. Note that the U.S. is on the upper right of the line, indicating that we have both high
inequality and low mobility.
The rise in inequality since the 1980s is likely to move us further out on the Great Gatsby Curve
(slide 18). Quantitatively, the persistence in the advantages and disadvantages of income passed
from parents to children is predicted to rise by about one quarter for the next generation as a
result of the rise in inequality that the U.S. has experienced over the last 25 years.
We are already seeing a growing gap in the enrichment activities provided to children born to
higher and lower income families.
This next chart shows that since the 1970s expenditures on educated-related activities –
including music and art lessons, books and tutoring – have been growing for children in families

26
See Alan Krueger, “The Rise and Consequences of Inequality in the United States,” Remarks at the Center for
American Progress, January 2012; and Miles Corak, “Inequality from Generation to Generation: The United States
in Comparison,” in Robert Rycroft (editor), The Economics of Inequality, Poverty, and Discrimination in the 21st
Century, ABC-CLIO, 2013.
12
in the top 20 percent of income earners, but stagnant for children in the bottom 20 percent (slide
19).
27
And the following chart shows that there is a growing gap between the top and bottom in
participation in extracurricular activities at school (slide 20).
28
And there is also a widening gap
in participation in music, dance and art outside of school (slide 21).
Children of wealthy parents already have much more access to opportunities to succeed than do
children of poor parents, and this is likely to be increasingly the case in the future unless we
ensure that all children have access to quality education, health care, a safe environment and
other opportunities that are necessary to have a fair shot at economic success.
There is a significant cost to the economy and society if children from low-income families do
not have anything close to the opportunities to develop and apply their talents as their more-
fortunate counterparts from better-off families, who can attend better schools, receive college
prep tutoring, and draw on a network of family connections in the job market.
Diverse observers from Raghuram Rajan of the University of Chicago to Robert Reich of
Berkeley have suggested a second way in which rising inequality and slow income growth for
the vast middle class have harmed the U.S. economy – namely, by encouraging families to
borrow to try to maintain consumption, a practice which cannot go on forever, and by reducing
aggregate consumption.
29
As a result of the rise in inequality, the amount of income going to the
top 1 percent of American families has increased by about $1 trillion on an annual basis.
Because the middle class has a higher propensity to spend their income than the top 1 percent,
this curbs consumption. An increasingly top-heavy distribution of income is a drag on aggregate
demand and economic growth, and a contributing factor to credit bubbles.
President Obama made this point very clearly in a speech in Osawatomie, Kansas: “When
middle class families can no longer afford to buy the goods and services that businesses are
selling, it drags down the entire economy, from top to bottom.”
Third, an active line of research examines the connection between inequality and longer term
economic growth. In a seminal study, Torsten Persson and Guido Tabellini found that in a
society where income inequality is greater, political decisions are likely to result in policies that
lead to less growth.
30

27
Greg Duncan and Richard Murnane, Wither Opportunity? Rising Inequality, Schools and Children’s Life
Chances, New York, NY: Russell Sage Foundation, 2011.
28
This slide and the next is from Robert Putnam, “Requiem for the American Dream? Unequal Opportunity in
America,” presentation at the Aspen Institute Ideas Festival, July 29, 2012.
29
Raghuram Rajan, Fault Lines: How Hidden Fractures Still Threaten the World Economy, Princeton University
Press, 2010; Reich, Robert B., Aftershock: The Next Economy and America’s Future, Random House, 2010.
30
Torsten Persson and Guido Tabellini, “Is Inequality Harmful for Growth?” American Economic Review, 1994,
Vol. 84, No. 3: 600-621.
13
A recent IMF paper also finds that more equality in the income distribution is associated with
more stable economic growth.
31
Historically, a growing middle class has led to new markets, supported economic growth and
built stronger communities.
Growing the Economy from the Middle Out
In this year’s State of the Union Address, President Obama said, “We can either settle for a
country where a shrinking number of people do really well, while a growing number of
Americans barely get by, or we can restore an economy where everyone gets a fair shot, and
everyone does their fair share, and everyone plays by the same set of rules.”
He went on to outline a robust set of proposals to grow the economy from the middle out, by
creating more middle class jobs and opportunities for those who are struggling to make it to the
middle class.
I’ll conclude by explaining why the President’s agenda makes so much sense for our economy.
This slide summarizes key elements of the President’s proposals to rebuild the middle class
(slide 22).
First, we need to provide ladders of opportunity so we can fully utilize and develop the talents of
everyone in our country. One example of such a policy is pre-school education. Much research
has found that high quality pre-school pays for itself many times over down the road.
32
All
children should have access to a safe learning environment.
Second, the only force stronger than globalization is the strength of community. There are
synergies within local areas. There is the reason why tech companies agglomerate in Silicon
Valley or movie producers in Hollywood. And it is why Motown produced so much great music.
There can be positive spillovers within communities.
Research by the economist Enrico Moretti, for example, shows that high school graduates benefit
when the number of college graduates rise in an area (slide 23).
33
The Obama Administration is
committed to revitalizing distressed communities. The President’s Budget proposed to designate
20 of the communities hardest hit by the recession as “Promise Zones”. These “Promise Zones”
will benefit from coordinated federal support to reduce crime, build more affordable housing,
revamp schools, and attract private investment.

31
Andrew Berg and Jonathan Ostry, “Inequality and Unsustainable Growth: Two Sides of the Same Coin?
International Monetary Fund Staff Discussion Note, April 2011.
32
See, for example, Steven Barnett, “Effectiveness of early educational intervention,” Science, 2011, 333, 975-978.
33
Enrico Moretti, The New Geography of Jobs, Houghton Mifflin Harcourt, 2012, p. 98.
14
Third, the landmark Affordable Care Act expands access to health insurance coverage by
providing subsidies for low- and moderate-income families, creates more competition and
transparency in the insurance market, and gives providers and insurers new incentives to keep
costs down.
Fourth, to restore fairness to our economy, President Obama has proposed raising the minimum
wage to $9 an hour and indexing it so it rises with inflation. This would bring the real value of
the minimum wage back to where it was in 1981.
Government actions and the use of the bully pulpit can also strengthen norms of fairness when it
comes to private sector pay.
As part of the Wall Street Reform Act, for example, the President signed legislation that requires
a nonbinding shareholder vote on the pay of top executives at public companies, called “Say-on-
Pay”. About 3 percent of companies had shareholders vote against executive pay packages in
Say-on-Pay votes in 2012. Although this may seem small, there were some very consequential
and newsworthy negative votes, including at Citigroup and Hewlett-Packard. About one in four
of the companies that lost Say-on-Pay votes in 2011 subsequently replaced their CEO.
34
Moreover, the fact that pay packages must now be aired in front of shareholders should cause at
least some compensation committees to moderate their proposals.
President Obama has also proposed limiting the pay of federal contractors to the same salary
received by the President himself, which was $400,000 this year (before he voluntarily returned
5% of his salary to the Treasury out of sympathy for federal workers who were forced to take
pay cuts due to furloughs under the budget sequester). The current rules governing pay for
federal contractors permits top managers at these firms to be reimbursed in line with the pay of
top private sector CEOs. The contractor reimbursement level has skyrocketed by more than 300
percent since the mid-1990s, and the top rate is slated to rise from $763,000 to $950,000 this
year if action is not taken. This proposal not only reduces waste and inefficiency in government,
but also represents another step towards strengthening norms of fairness in pay setting.
In addition, the American Taxpayer Relief Act, which passed at the beginning of this year and
allows tax rates on the top 2% of income earners to return to where they were in the Clinton
years, restores more fairness to our tax code, while maintaining tax breaks for middle class
families.
The manufacturing and construction industries were hit particularly hard by the Great Recession,
and manufacturing languished before the recession. These industries provide relatively many
middle class jobs, especially for workers with less than a college degree. To revitalize
manufacturing, the President has proposed to create Institutes of Manufacturing Innovation, and
one has already been launched in Youngstown, Ohio. He has also proposed investing more in
our infrastructure. It makes tremendous economic sense to repair and rebuild our roads and
highways, ports and airports, when unemployment is high in the construction sector and interest
rates are low. This would put more people back to work today and improve our competitiveness
tomorrow.

34
“‘Say on Pay’ Changes Ways.” Wall Street Journal. February 21, 2012.
15
Finally, all of these President’s proposals were made in the context of a sustainable federal
budget. The budget is a means to an end, not an end in itself. President Obama has insisted on a
balanced approach to deficit reduction that closes loopholes for the well-off and well-connected
and addresses our long-run entitlement problems, while protecting the middle class and making
key investments in infrastructure and research and development, which will raise our living
standards in the future.
We should not expect problems that have built up over decades to be solved overnight, but the
President’s proposal would put us on a path to rebuild the middle class.
Conclusion
One of my predecessors as Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers, Arthur Okun, wrote
an influential book called, Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff. Okun argued that policies
that increase equality often reduce efficiency.
35
But given the dramatic rise in inequality in the U.S. over the past three decades, we have reached
the point where inequality is hurting the economy. Today, a reduction in inequality would be
good for efficiency, economic growth and stability.
Growing the economy from the middle out is not only an economic necessity; it is also a national
imperative. Our system of government as well as our economy work better when we have a
rising, thriving middle class, with broad common interests.
The expanding middle class in the post-war period was a defining experience for our country.
Just like music, this shared growth and prosperity helped bring the nation together.
President Obama captured the changes sweeping our economy well when he said, “The world is
faster and the playing field is larger and the challenges are more complex. But what hasn’t
changed – what can never change – are the values that got us this far. We still have a stake in
each other’s success. We still believe that this should be a place where you can make it if you
try. And we still believe, in the words of … [Theodore Roosevelt that] ‘The fundamental rule of
our national life, the rule which underlies all others – is that, on the whole, and in the long run,
we shall go up or down together.’” And I agree with the President that America is still on the
way up.

35
He also noted some glaring exceptions. For example, he observed that civil rights legislation that outlawed
discrimination on the basis of race, sex and ethnicity increased equality as well as efficiency.
Concert Ticket Prices Have Risen Much Faster Than
Overall Consumer Price Inflation
June 12, 2013 1
Note: Data for 2003-2012 provided by Pollstar for top 100 North America tours by revenue. Earlier data from Krueger (2005). The average ticket
price after 2003 is assumed to grow at the same rate as the average for the top 100 tours.
Source: Pollstar; Krueger (2005); Bureau of Labor Statistics; CEA calculations.
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004 2008 2012
Growth in Concert Ticket Prices, 1981-2012
Index, 1981=100
Average Ticket
Price
Consumer
Price Index
The Top Artists are Getting a Larger Share
of Total Ticket Revenue…
June 12, 2013 2
Source: Krueger (2005).
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003
Percent
Shares of Concert Ticket Revenue, 1982-2003
Everybody Else
26%
56%
Top 1 Percent
Top 2-5 Percent
…As the Top Earners are Getting a Larger Share
of National Income
June 12, 2013 3
Note: Includes capital gains and measured before taxes.
Source: Piketty and Saez (2003, 2013 data update).
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
1979 1983 1987 1991 1995 1999 2003 2007 2011
Percent
Shares of National Income, 1970-2011
Everybody Else
10%
20%
Top 1 Percent
Top 2-5 Percent
Role of Luck in Popular Music:
Design of Music Market Experiment
June 12, 2013 4
Source: Salganik and Watts (2008).
Role of Luck in Popular Music:
Subjects Can See Download Counts and Rank
June 12, 2013 5
Source: Salganik and Watts (2008).
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
Role of Luck in Popular Music:
Can Listen To and Download Songs
June 12, 2013 6
Source: Salganik and Watts (2008).
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
Role of Luck in Popular Music:
“Alternative Universe” With Flipped Rankings
June 12, 2013 7
Source: Salganik and Watts (2008).
The Belief that a Song is Popular has a Profound Effect on
its Popularity, Even if it Wasn’t Truly Popular to Begin With
June 12, 2013 8
Note: The experiment included two “inverted” worlds with approximately 2,000 subjects in each. The download counts from the two alternative worlds are
averaged here.
Source: Salganik and Watts (2008).
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500
Downloads
Music Downloads in Two Alternative Universes
Subjects
Song 1
Song 48
Song 1
Song 48
2
6
10
14
18
22
1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
Percent
Share of National Income Earned by Top 1 Percent, 1920-2011
In the U.S., the Share of Income Earned by the Top 1
Percent Has Doubled Since 1979
June 12, 2013 9
Note: Incomes exclude capital gains and are measured before taxes.
Source: Alvaredo, Atkinson, Piketty, and Saez (The World Top Incomes Database).
United
States
Beginning in the 1980s, Compensation for Production and Non-
Supervisory Workers Failed to Keep Pace With Productivity
June 12, 2013 10
Note: Compensation series based on average hourly wage for production and non-supervisory workers in goods-producing industries (pre-1964)
and all private sector industries (1964-present). Series is adjusted to account for growth of non-wage compensation using the wage-and-salary
share of employee compensation as measured in the National Income and Product Accounts. Both series shown are deflated by price index for
output in the nonfarm business sector.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Bureau of Economic Analysis; CEA calculations.
0
50
100
150
200
250
300
350
400
450
'47'52'57'62'67'72'77'82'87'92'97'02'07'12
Labor Productivity and Compensation
Index, 1947:Q1=100
Real Output per Hour
2013:Q1
Real Compensation per Hour
for Production and
Nonsuperv isory Workers
All Income Groups Grew Together in the
Post-War Period Through 1979
June 12, 2013 11
Note: Adjusted for inflation.
Source: Census Bureau.
2.5%
2.2%
2.4%
2.4%
2.2%
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
Lowest fifth Second fifth Mid Fifth Fourth fifth Highest fifth
Annual Growth of Family Income, 1947-1979
Percent
Since 1979, the Top has Done Better
than the Middle
June 12, 2013 12
Note: Adjusted for inflation.
Source: Census Bureau.
-0.4%
0.0%
0.2%
0.6%
1.2%
Lowest fifth Second fifth Mid Fifth Fourth fifth Highest fifth
-0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
Annual Growth of Family Income, 1979-2011
Percent
2
6
10
14
18
22
1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
Percent
Share of National Income Earned by Top 1 Percent, 1920-2011
Top Income Shares Vary Across Countries
June 12, 2013 13
Note: Incomes exclude capital gains and are measured before taxes.
Source: Alvaredo, Atkinson, Piketty, and Saez (The World Top Incomes Database).
United
States
Sweden
United
Kingdom
France
-80
-60
-40
-20
0
20
40
60
-8 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 8
Difference in Years of Education
Difference in Hourly Wage, Dollars
Difference in Education and Wages
Between Identical Twins
Twins With Higher Education Tend to Earn More
Than Their Other Half With Less Education
June 12, 2013 14
Source: Ashenfelter and Krueger (1994).
A Typical CEO Made 18 Times the Average Worker in 1965,
but Today CEOs Make Over 200 Times the Average Worker
June 12, 2013 15
Note: Includes stock options granted.
Source: Economic Policy Institute, The State of Working America, 12
th
Edition and Issue Brief #331 (May 2012).
0
50
100
150
200
250
300
350
400
450
'65 '70 '75 '80 '85 '90 '95 '00 '05 '10
Ratio of CEO-to-Worker Compensation, 1965-2011
Ratio
1965: 18-to-1
2011: 209-to-1
In Industries Where Managers are Well-Paid, Janitors are also
Paid Better, Showing that to Some Extent Profits are Shared
June 12, 2013 16
Note: Data covers 2003-2012. Wages in 2012 dollars.
Source: Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
$10.00
$20.00
$30.00
$40.00
$50.00
$8.00 $12.00 $16.00 $20.00
Average Wage of Managers
Hourly Wage of Managers and Janitors by Industry
Average Wage of Janitors
r=0.72
Higher Income Inequality Associated with Lower
Intergenerational Mobility
June 12, 2013 17
Denmark
Finland
France
Germany
Japan
New Zealand
Norway
Sweden
United Kingdom
United States
y = 2.2x - 0.27
R² = 0.76
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35 0.40
Inequality
(1985 Gini Coefficient)
Intergenerational earnings elasticity
The Great Gatsby Curve
y = 2.2x - 0.27
R² = 0.76
.
Source: Corak (2011), OECD, CEA estimates
g
Higher Income Inequality Associated with Lower
Intergenerational Mobility
June 12, 2013 18
Denmark
Finland
France
Germany
Japan
New Zealand
Norway
Sweden
United Kingdom
United States
y = 2.2x - 0.27
R² = 0.76
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35 0.40
Inequality
(1985 Gini Coefficient)
Intergenerational earnings elasticity
The Great Gatsby Curve
United States
(2010)
y = 2.2x - 0.27
R² = 0.76
United States
(2010 Gini)
.
Source: Corak (2011), OECD, CEA estimates
g
The Gap in Spending on Child Enrichment
Has Widened
June 12, 2013 19
Note: Child enrichment expenditures defined as education-related items and activities such as music and art lessons, children’s books and toys, sports
equipment and classes, and tutoring.
Source: Duncan and Murnane (2011).
$835
$1,264
$1,173
$1,315
$3,536
$5,650
$6,975
$8,872
0
2,500
5,000
7,500
10,000
1972-73 1983-84 1994-95 2005-06
2008 Dollars
Family Expenditures on Child Enrichment
Top Income
Quintile
Bottom Income Quintile
The Gap in Participation in
Extracurricular Activities Has Widened
June 12, 2013 20
Note: Households assigned to socioeconomic status quartiles based on an index of income, parents’ education, and parents’ occupation.
Source: Putnam (2012).
50
55
60
65
70
75
80
1972 1982 1992 2004
Percent
Top Socioeconomic
Status Quartile
Bottom Socioeconomic
Status Quartile
Participation in Extracurricular Activities, 12th Grade
The Gap in Participation in Music, Dance and
Art Outside of School Has Widened
June 12, 2013 21
Note: Households assigned to socioeconomic status quartiles based on an index of income, parents’ education, and parents’ occupation.
Source: Putnam (2012).
15
20
25
30
35
40
1990 2002
Percent
Top Socioeconomic
Status Quartile
Bottom Socioeconomic
Status Quartile
Participation in Music, Dance or Art
Outside School, 10th Grade
Obama Administration Policies for Growing and
Strengthening the Middle Class
June 12, 2013 22
Ladders of Opportunity: E.g., Pre-school for all
Promise Zones: Revitalizing hard-hit communities
Affordable Care Act: Affordable, high quality health care
Raise the minimum wage
Restore fairness to the tax code with ATRA and by
closing loopholes
Support a renaissance in U.S. manufacturing
Invest in 21
st
Century Infrastructure
Balanced Deficit Reduction
Education Has Spillover Effects: High School Grads Benefit
from Living in a City with More College Grads
June 12, 2013 23
Note: The red dot represents Cleveland, OH.
Source: American Community Survey, CEA calculations.
$15,000
$20,000
$25,000
$30,000
$35,000
$40,000
$45,000
$50,000
$55,000
0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50%
Average Annual Earnings for High School Graduates
Percent of College Graduates
Average Annual Earnings for High School Graduates vs.
Percent of College Graduates for U.S. Metropolitan Areas, 2005