TNM/12/02
International Monetary Fund
Fiscal Affairs Department
700 19th Street NW
Washington, DC 20431
USA
Tel: 1-202-623-8554
Fax: 1-202-623-6073
Government Cash Management:
Relationship between the Treasury
and the Central Bank
Mario Pessoa and Mike Williams
Fiscal Affairs Department
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
Technical noTes and Manuals
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
Fiscal Affairs Department
Government Cash Management:
Relationship between the Treasury and the Central Bank
Prepared by Mario Pessoa and Mike Williams
Authorized for distribution by Carlo Cottarelli
November 2012
JEL Classification Numbers: E44, E58, E62, E63, H30, H60, H63, H83
Keywords: Central bank, debt management, fiscal policy, monetary policy,
public finance, public financial management, treasury, treasury
single account
Author’s E-Mail Address: [email protected] and mike.williams@mj-w.net
DISCLAIMER: This Technical Guidance Note should not be reported as representing the views
of the IMF. The views expressed in this Note are those of the authors and do not necessarily
represent those of the IMF or IMF policy.
Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012 1
Government Cash Management:
Relationship between the Treasury
and the Central Bank
Mario Pessoa and Mike Williams
I. The Importance of Formalizing the Relationship between
the Treasury and the Central Bank for better Government
Cash Management
1
The relationship between the treasury
2
and the central bank is at the heart of financial poli-
cies. This relationship operates at different levels. The coherence of monetary policy with
government financing policies (along with fiscal policy) underpins successful macroeconomic
procedures. But the management of the government’s debt and cash interacts directly with
monetary policy operations. As the sophistication of the government’s own operations devel-
ops—particularly in relation to cash management—some of these interactions intensify. Both
institutions also interact with the banking system, variously as users of the banks’ transaction
1
This note was prepared at the request of the Latin American Treasury Forum (FOTEGAL) and has benefited from
the helpful contributions of J. Mueller, R. Allen, J. Gardner, C. de Albuquerque, M. Anthony, K. Eckhold, G. Pedras,
and R. Jiménez.
2
References to the “treasury” throughout this TNM are to the function, not to any particular organizational model,
of which there is a variety.
TECHNICAL NoTEs ANd MANUALs
This technical note and manual (TNM) addresses the following main issues:
• Interaction between treasury cash management and monetary policy opera-
tions within the wider context of the respective economic responsibilities of
the ministry of finance and the central bank.
• Institutional arrangements for an effective relationship between the treasury
and the central bank.
• Contractual arrangements between the treasury and the central bank for the
provision of banking and other services.
This document will be particularly relevant to developing countries that are reform-
ing cash management operations or contemplating more active cash manage-
ment; or where there are operational policy differences between the treasury and
the central bank.
2 Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012
services, or as financial counterparty (and potentially also as owner or regulator). At the same
time, the central bank is the treasury’s banker and provides a range of services at the opera-
tional level, such as managing the treasury single account (TSA), and acting as fiscal agent
(running auctions), settlement agent, or bond registrar.
This relationship must therefore be handled with some thought. There will be differ-
ences of policy. The treasury and the central bank separately manage different parts of
the overall government sector’s balance sheet, and they will have different priorities and
perceptions of risk. Without adequate governance and planning mechanisms, and indeed,
goodwill on both sides, there will be risks of conflicting policy actions and wider eco-
nomic damage. A framework is vital to policy understanding, operational coordination,
and service provision on issues ranging from the high-level coordination of fiscal, financ-
ing, and monetary policies, to the management of Treasury bill (T-bill) auctions and the
government’s banking arrangements.
This note addresses these issues, and how best to manage the relationship in order to
further the objectives of cash (and debt) management on the one hand, and monetary policy
(and reserves management) on the other. There is a particular focus on the interaction be-
tween cash management and monetary policy operations, as recent reforms have changed
both respective responsibilities and the policy approach. After a summary of the modern cash
management framework, within the wider context of the greater operational separation of
monetary policy, fiscal policy, and debt and cash management policy (Section II), the paper
outlines the reform process and its implications for the treasury, central bank, and commer-
cial banks (Section III). After a fuller discussion of some specific policy challenges (Section
IV), the manual considers how the interaction should be institutionally and administratively
structured (Section V). Section VI discusses service level agreements (SLAs) and Section VII
concludes. The note is particularly relevant for developing countries.
II. The Modern Framework
The wider context is the high-level policy relationship between the ministry of finance and
the central bank. One of the lessons from the financial crises of the 1980s and 1990s has
been that debt management, and fiscal and monetary policy should be treated as separate
arms of macroeconomic policy with specific objectives. There has to be coherence in the
overall policy mix, as outlined in Box 1, but the use of different instruments to meet differ-
ent objectives facilitates greater transparency and predictability, enhancing the credibility
and effectiveness of policy. In turn, credible policies produce superior overall outcomes
compared to less credible ones. The weak links between debt management choices (that
is, the choice of instrument) and monetary conditions or liquidity, and between monetary
conditions and inflation, allow for a greater separation between monetary policy operations
and the management of debt and cash. For most practical purposes, control over short-term
Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012 3
rates is sufficient for meeting the central bank’s objectives, although some central banks also
influence the monetary aggregates more directly.
3
A key feature of the modern framework is therefore the independence of the central bank
with respect to monetary policy. However, the precise nature of this independence varies and
is determined by national constitutional structures and practices. In most countries, govern-
ments retain some responsibilities, such as for the appointment of board or monetary policy
committee members, and possibly a theoretical override.
3
For a summary of the background history and past assessments, see Nunes (1999) and Turner (2011). Blommes-
tein and Turner (2011) note that the financial and economic crisis has also led to some blurring of the line between
public debt management and monetary policy in developed countries. Debt management offices (DMOs) have
operated more extensively at the short end of the yield curve, and central banks have been increasingly active in the
same long government bond markets as DMOs. Even in developed markets therefore there cannot be an unqualified
separation of debt management and monetary policy operations. On the importance of policy coherence, and the
role of an asset-liability management framework in securing it, see Togo (2007).
Box 1: The Importance of High-Level Policy Coherence
The effectiveness of policy decentralization and the credibility of the respective
authorities hinges on the coherence of the overall policy mix. Many countries emphasize
the separation of operational roles between the treasury and the central bank. However,
completely separate policies only work if there are separate policy instruments that
are independent of each other, which may not be the case in emerging market
countries. Thus, financing plans may put an undue strain on domestic monetary policy
operations, or the introduction of a new inflation-linked bond may have implications for
monetary policy. A more specific example, discussed further below, is a central bank’s
issuance of securities in order to absorb liquidity in the money market. The mode in
which central banks accomplish this has implications for the securities market and for
the governments’ own sales of short-term securities. Unless executed in a manner
sensitive to respective objectives, there is a danger of weakening the credibility of the
government’s ability to achieve its policy goals.
Debt/cash management and monetary policy should therefore be integrated into a
broader macroeconomic framework of analysis that ensures a consistent policy mix.
Different countries coordinate their policies in different ways. Some countries have fiscal
responsibility laws that include target or ceiling deficits and debt levels. Many countries
have internal public debt committees (PDCs), or similar arrangements, which facilitate
coordination. These bodies bring together representatives of the main macroeconomic
policy functions to ensure that debt management decisions, and, more generally, asset-
liability decisions, are properly embedded in wider macroeconomic policies. The role of a
PDC or other institutional mechanism is discussed further below. It should be stressed,
however, that the focus of the interaction discussed here is high-level and strategic.
It should not extend to short-term policy decisions, such as treasury involvement in
changes in the central bank’s policy rate, or in the central bank’s involvement in individual
debt issuance decisions. In these cases, operational independence is important.
4 Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012
This greater policy separation has been paralleled over the last two decades by a progressive
reform of the respective operational roles of the treasury and the central bank. At the risk of
some oversimplification, under the traditional model:
• Thetreasury’smainrolewasasgovernmentpaymentofce. It either managed all
government payments centrally, or it would release cash to spending ministries, de-
partments, and agencies (MDAs), usually to their bank accounts in the central bank or
commercial banks. The TSA was incomplete, with government agencies often holding
many accounts both in central and commercial banks. Management of cash was essen-
tially passive. The treasury would monitor cash balances, maintaining a cash buffer to
handle both volatility and unanticipated outflows. If necessary, it would ration cash by
restraining or slowing expenditures or delaying bill payments, often causing arrears to
accumulate.
• Thecentralbankhadanumberofroles. It would manage domestic monetary condi-
tions, drawing on a range of tools (the setting of policy interest rates, open market oper-
ations [OMOs], reserve ratios, etc.). In so doing, it sought to take account of the govern-
ment’s own cash flows. As fiscal agent for the government, it would not only run bond
and bill auctions, but it would also significantly influence issuance and financing policies
(a reflection of the treasury’s limited capacity) with government debt often issued with
a view to both the government’s cash requirements, and the bank’s liquidity manage-
ment purposes. In practice, this tended to entail the issuance of bonds for financing
budget deficits, and of T-bills for liquidity purposes and the financing of short-term cash
needs.
4
The central bank would also provide a range of services to the government as
banker (which might extend to being cashier, processor of payments, and lender of last
resort), and variously as settlement agent, supplier of registry services, and so on. The
central bank would retain wider responsibilities for the financial system, notably as the
manager or regulator of the payment (and settlement) systems, overseer of the interbank
and money markets, and in many cases prudential regulator of the commercial banks
and other financial institutions. In some countries, the central bank, in effect, had some
budget execution responsibilities through its control over the MDAs’ bank accounts.
• ThecommercialbanksprovidedbankingservicestoMDAs. In the process, they held
substantial government cash balances (both demand and term deposits).
This traditional approach has had the following consequences:
• Therecouldbeexcessgovernmentliquidity. Idle balances in the banking sector are
costly to the government and profitable for the banking sector. Because balances usually
have not been remunerated, or have been remunerated at a lower rate than the bor-
4
In some countries, golden rules were established to allow new debt only in order to finance capital investment.
T-bills were to be used only to cover temporary gaps between the receipts of revenues and the outflow of expendi-
tures during the month.
Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012 5
rowing needed to finance them, there typically has been an implicit subsidy from the
government. The lack of a market-related interest rate also gives both the government
and banks the wrong incentives.
• Governmentcashowshavebeenamajorcauseofshort-termvolatilityinmoney
marketsandbankliquidity. This has complicated both commercial banks’ liquidity
management and the central bank’s monetary policy operations. The need to mop up
excess liquidity in the banking system can be costly to the central bank.
• Thecentralbank’simplementationofgovernmentcashanddebtmanagementcan
conictwithitsmonetarypolicygoalsandoperations. This has been the case par-
ticularly in relation to interest rate setting and signaling.
5
• Centralbanklendingtothegovernmentincreasesthemonetarybase. This has po-
tential consequences for inflation.
In consequence, the modern institutional framework has a clear separation of roles:
• Thecentralbankfocusesonmonetarypolicy. One result of the central bank’s greater
independence is that its objectives have narrowed, with the emphasis being on the con-
trol of inflation. It may still provide services to the government, such as managing the
TSA, although transaction-banking services increasingly tend to be left to commercial
banks.
6
Where it is still a fiscal agent, the central bank’s role has been more clearly that
of an agent, and not as a driver of policy.
• Thetreasurybecomesafully-edgedfunction.
7
It pools all government liquidity,
takes full responsibility for debt management, and manages cash actively. There is a
spectrum of practices, but effective cash management facilitates unrestricted execution of
the budget. If executed well, it lowers average cash balances, thereby reducing costs, and
moderates money market volatility. MDAs may manage their own expenditures, but the
treasury manages the government’s overall cash through the TSA.
• ThebankingsectorprovidesbankingservicestothetreasuryandMDAs,as
required, onatransparently-costedbasis. This should be done through competi-
tively tendered minimum standard SLAs. The role of the banks depends on the degree
to which government payment processing is centralized in the treasury, or dispersed
to MDAs. In more decentralized payment systems, there is more room for commercial
banks to provide specific services, such as the placement of short-term excess cash in a
fixed-term investment.
5
For example, the higher interest rates needed to meet monetary policy objectives may conflict with the objective
to hold down the cost of debt servicing. Or, the market may see the coupons set on new debt issues as a signal of
interest rate intentions.
6
Central banks that have a retail-banking role are often reluctant to expand; it is costly and rests beyond their
core responsibilities; the commercial banks with wider networks are better placed to realize economies of scale.
7
Institutional arrangements will vary. As stressed above, the focus here on treasury functions (primarily budget
execution and cash management) is independent of whether they lie in a unit denominated “treasury” or an inte-
grated “debt and cash management office.”
6 Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012
III. Development of a Modern Treasury System
A. Governmental Requirements
The requirements of a modern treasury management function have been well understood.
8
These should include:
• AcomprehensiveTSA. It consolidates all government cash balances into a single ac-
count, usually and preferably at the central bank.
9
All government revenues are trans-
ferred immediately upon receipt to the TSA, including so-called own-revenues that are
received by MDAs.
• Anefcientgovernmentpaymentssystem.It may either be centralized through a
treasury-managed TSA, or decentralized to MDAs, as summarized in Box 2. If it is de-
centralized, all MDA bank accounts should be connected to the TSA and zero-balanced
overnight, with any cash balances swept back to the TSA. Commercial banks must have
the capacity to perform sweeping operations with the central bank, and provide elec-
tronic payments and reconciliation services.
• Alinkedtreasury-managedintegratednancialmanagementinformationsystem
(IFMIS). This allows for the management, monitoring, control, reconciliation, accounting,
and reporting of budget execution and bank account balances, in particular the TSA.
• Acashowforecastingsystemwiththeabilitytomakeaccurateprojectionsof
short-termcashinowsandoutows. The separation between the permission to
spend and actual cash payments means that flows through the TSA must be the focus
of the forecast. Good cash flow forecasts underpin active cash management. Ideally,
forecasts of daily cash flows across the TSA should be available for at least three months
ahead on a rolling basis, including at the end of the fiscal year. This must be coupled
with an ability to monitor actual changes in the aggregate balance of the TSA top ac-
count, preferably in as close to real time as possible.
• Activecashmanagement. This includes the use of short-term financial instruments,
both on the liability and asset sides (T-bills, repos and reverse repos,
10
collateralized
term deposits, etc.), to help manage balances and timing mismatches.
11
By both ensur-
ing the availability of cash and avoiding unnecessary idle cash balances, net borrowing
costs are minimized. Lower volatility of the government’s cash balance also facilitates the
8
See, for example, Lienert (2009).
9
For a more detailed description of requirements and options, see Pattanayak and Fainboim (2011).
10
A repo (short for sale and repurchase agreement) is the sale of securities tied to an agreement to buy them back
later. A reverse repo is the purchase of securities tied to an agreement to sell them back later. A repo is best thought
of as a collateralized loan. Thus, a government cash manager may decide to borrow by way of repo, raising cash
against a temporary transfer of assets. Conversely, a reverse repo may best be thought of as a collateralized invest-
ment. For repo transactions, government debt and cash managers almost invariably use or require T-bills or T-bonds
as collateral assets. Repos are often also a central bank’s chosen instrument by for monetary policy operations.
11
Active cash management and its interaction with other policies are described more fully in Williams (2010).
Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012 7
central bank’s monetary policy task.
12
As capabilities develop, it is possible to target a
low and stable TSA balance, which should be remunerated (discussed below).
There are a number of institutional and market underpinnings to these characteristics of
modern cash management:
12
Changes in the government’s cash balance at the central bank (changes in the main operational TSA account)
are usually the largest autonomous influence on a domestic banking system’s liquidity (credit institutions’ net hold-
ings of deposits at the central bank).
If the government is able to moderate the fluctuations in balances at the central
bank, then the central bank’s domestic liquidity management task is reduced accordingly.
Box 2: The TSA and Payment Systems
The TSA can work with a variety of payment systems that are centralized, decentralized,
or hybrid, whether in relation to approval, transaction processing, or accounting control.
There is, in effect, a two-by-two matrix, as shown below.
Processing Payments: the Options
Central Bank responsible for
banking operations
Commercial banks
responsible for banking
operations
Treasury responsible for
payment processing
Spending units responsible for
payment processing
The devolution of payment responsibility tends to be associated with the use of
commercial banks to manage transactions. Most countries fall either into the top left cell
of the matrix (such as France, Russia) or the bottom right (UK, Australia), although there
are other examples (South Africa is mostly in the bottom left cell). Several nations have
mixed arrangements (China, India, USA). Centralization of payments is relatively more
common in smaller or less developed countries, often as part of reform processes.
Centralized transaction processing implies a concentration of authority in the treasury
to process transactions, and to access and operate the TSA. The treasury (in some
countries with a network of regional treasuries, or with treasury officials embedded in
ministries) may approve, as well as process, payments. In other cases (for example,
Belarus, Argentina, and Georgia), the MDAs may be responsible and accountable for
payments, although the treasury will process the payments.
In the case of decentralized payment and accounting systems, each MDA processes
its own transactions and directly operates each respective claim on cash. The key
requirement under arrangements that use commercial banks is that any cash balances
left with the banking system at the end of the day should be swept back into the TSA;
any transactional accounts should be opened as zero-balance accounts. There is a
separation of cash from the permission to spend, and cash does not leave the TSA until
the payment is finally discharged. The requirements apply to accounts that are used for
disbursements or for the collection of government revenues. Ultimately, all revenues are
deposited in the TSA.
8 Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012
• Treasury capacities (systems, staffing) and organizational structures often need to be
substantially enhanced, not least to support financial transactions.
• Newcoordinationstructuresareneededtocover:
Information sharing between the cash managers, revenue-collecting agencies, and
spending MDAs (and any relevant ministry branch offices), in relation to payment
and revenue flows, and cash flow forecasting.
—The close coordination (or integration) of debt and cash management operations.
Agreements between the treasury and the central bank on information flows, respec-
tive responsibilities, and any operational interactions, including the development of
the financial markets.
• Financialmarketsrequireacertainlevelofdevelopmentandliquidityifcashisto
bemanagedactively. A reasonably liquid money market is especially important.
These sound practice elements apply equally to developed and to developing countries.
However, the development of active cash management in low-income countries is inevitably
constrained by thin financial markets and, in particular, poor liquidity in the money market.
In those cases, reform efforts tend to focus on the TSA and developing cash flow forecasts.
Many emerging market and middle-income countries, however, are increasingly using T-bills
or bank deposits to smooth cash flows, building on improved forecasts.
B. Implications for the Central Bank
The development of modern treasury functions and, in particular, improvements in the
government’s cash management have implications for the central bank. In the first place, the
modern framework will be underpinned by the central bank having the operational respon-
sibility for the conduct of monetary policy. This is a reform that, in most cases, will have pre-
dated the development of cash management. The precise nature of this responsibility varies
and is determined by specific legal frameworks and practices.
As a government begins improving its cash management, there will be a number of im-
plications for the central bank’s operations. Initially, as the TSA develops and cash is repatri-
ated from MDAs’ balances in commercial banks to the TSA, liquidity will move away from
the banking system. This is often helpful to the central bank, since the drain of liquidity will
improve its ability to control domestic monetary conditions over this period. Moreover, if the
government has not been receiving a full market rate on its cash balances, the implicit subsi-
dy, in essence, will be removed from the commercial banks. The withdrawal of deposits from
banks will, of course, also have implications for the banks, as discussed in the next Section.
As more active cash management develops, there may be implications for monetary policy
management. As the government starts to manage any surplus cash by transferring it out of
the central bank—whether by spending, by retiring domestic debt, or through short-term
investment in the banking system—there will be a monetary easing, other things being equal.
Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012 9
A better cash plan will allow the treasury to hold smaller cash buffers to insure against an un-
expected shortage of cash.
13
Additionally, if the balances are unremunerated, the central bank
will lose the benefit of cheap deposits. There will be a further negative impact on the central
bank’s profits if it is required to drain cash to offset the monetary easing, either by issuing its
own bills or borrowing through repo.
In the medium term, however, there will be a clear benefit to the central bank as the trea-
sury improves the quality of the cash plan projections and becomes better able to hold its
cash balances at a low and stable level. This reflects the fact that the government no longer ex-
erts a significant influence on domestic monetary conditions. The moderation of fluctuations
in the government deposits in the central bank will provide a more stable environment for the
central bank’s monetary policy operations. There will remain other autonomous influences on
domestic liquidity—such as the change in the public’s demand for bank notes and net foreign
currency inflows—but these are, respectively, more predictable or more directly controlled by
the central bank. Even when the treasury is not able to smooth cash balances completely, the
central bank should benefit from an improved flow of forecast information from the treasury
on future changes in the TSA.
The central bank may continue to act as fiscal agent for the conduct of auctions. However,
as the number of money market transactions increases, there is a risk of confusion between
the central bank’s and the treasury’s operations, particularly where the same group of market
counterparties is involved. In practice, most active cash managers develop their own front
office capabilities, such as directly managing the issuance of T-bills and T-bonds, conducting
auctions, and promoting an active relationship with market operators. In any event, it is im-
portant that there is no misunderstanding in the market as to which institution is responsible
for which activity, and their respective aims.
There needs to be clarity concerning respective policy responsibilities. This entails that the
government cash managers usually have no contact with the central bank regarding inter-
est rate decisions or prospective interest rate changes. Nor should they receive from within
the government any advance notice of policy statements or data releases that might affect the
market’s short-term interest rate expectations.
As to policy cooperation, the development of the domestic financial market, particularly
the money market, is an especially important area of cooperation between the treasury and
the central bank. A well-functioning money market both supports the conduct of monetary
control through market-based instruments (including repos), and facilitates a more active
management of the government’s short-term cash flows (see Box3).
13
The buffer will still need to take account of market volatility and rollover risk, as well as potential errors in cash
flow forecasts. It can also be a useful signal to the market of the treasury’s preparedness.
10 Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012
In order to provide clarity and avoid market disruptions relating to operations, tenders
associated with the central bank’s OMOs should be held at a different time of the day than
those of the treasury. There should also be an understanding that the treasury will not do
anything that might appear to undermine OMOs, such as the treasury putting cash into the
banking sector at exactly the same time that the central bank is trying to drain cash as part of
its control of interest rates.
14
The two institutions may also need to cooperate in the handling
of exceptional payment and receipt flows; for example, an unusually large tax payment could
14
For example, the UK Debt Management Office (DMO) agreed with the Bank of England—and explained to
the market—that it would not hold weekly bill tenders or ad hoc tenders at times when the Bank of England was
conducting its money market operations. Similarly, the DMO would not enter into loan transactions of a maturity
that could be perceived as competing with the Bank’s structured repo operations.
Box 3: The Importance of the Money Market
A functioning money market, usually defined as transactions across all instruments of
less than one year, is the cornerstone of a competitive and efficient system of market-
based financial intermediation. A country’s money market must be operating well before
a government bond market (including an efficient primary market and a liquid secondary
market) can be fully developed. A well-functioning money market plays several important
roles: (i) it facilitates the conduct of monetary policy through market-based instruments,
anchoring the short end of the yield curve and supporting the development of the
foreign exchange market; (ii) it provides the authorities with better signals of market
expectations; (iii) it allows banks and their customers to better manage their liquidity;
and (iv) it strengthens competition in financial intermediation.
The development of a well-performing money market, however, requires three key
conditions:
1
• Market-based methods of implementing monetary policy.
• Adequate management systems that provide reliable estimates of future govern-
ment cash flows and forecasts of aggregate bank liquidity.
• The presence of banks and other financial institutions with incentives to develop
efficient liquidity and risk management services.
An efficient money market stimulates the development of more active debt securities
markets, by lowering liquidity risk premiums and enabling investors to hold larger
portfolios of longer-term instruments. It should evolve parallel to the government
securities market. Access to liquidity and securities, with a well-functioning repo market
and securities lending arrangement, is important for proper secondary trading activities.
A well-developed money market also helps promote private issuance of negotiable
certificates of deposit, promissory notes, and commercial papers. As in the case of
government debt, active markets in short-term instruments support the development of
longer-term corporate bond markets.
1
World Bank (2007). The authors also note that the development of an active money market might be
held back by the failure to adopt a master repo agreement, netting and close-out mechanisms, and from
the lack of transparency concerning money market indices and activity volumes.
Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012 11
potentially distort the interbank market, which suggests that the transfer to the TSA be made
in tranches throughout the day to allow banks to restore their balance sheets.
In relation to information exchange, there should be three main regular requirements:
• The treasury should provide cash flow forecasts to the central bank so that it can take
these into account in its own forecasts of banking sector liquidity.
• The central bank should keep the treasury informed of flows and balances across the
TSA, ideally in real time, and facilitate the reconciliation with the accounting system
managed by the treasury.
• Arrangements for information exchange should also cover developments in the money
market.
15
The treasury will often also have responsibility for ownership of the central bank. It needs
to manage the corporate relationship with the central bank, which will be either directly
owned by the government, or set up as some form of statutory corporation under law, but
clearly part of the public sector. Regular discussions about the central bank’s financial per-
formance may be needed, especially concerning the dividend to be paid. To this end, clear
and transparent rules should be implemented so that the mechanics are known by the parties
involved. Discussions will also be needed on such issues as how the central bank’s pay and
personnel policies should relate to the government’s policies, if at all. Other major policy is-
sues with budgetary implications might be the possible need to recapitalize the central bank
or to compensate it for the costs of running monetary policy. Normally, it would be preferable
to maintain some separation between this ownership role and the interactions related to debt
and cash management policy or to the treasury’s role as a customer of the central bank, pos-
sibly transferring the ownership function elsewhere in the ministry of finance.
C. Implications for Commercial Banks
The reform of cash management somewhat changes the treasury’s relationship with the bank-
ing system. It also imposes requirements on the banks. It is difficult to modernize government
payment arrangements without the banks being internally fully electronically integrated, with
collective access to a modern automated system for the clearing and settlement of payments.
16
This system should either be, or be linked to, a real time gross settlement system (RTGS),
to allow low risk real-time settlement of high-value payments across accounts at the central
bank. Such arrangements would, in turn:
• Allow revenues to be passed from a peripheral rural branch to the bank’s head office and
the TSA on the same day.
15
In general, cash managers should not be given market-sensitive information (for example, on a bank in finan-
cial trouble), lest that affect its own actions and the market’s perception of those actions.
16
Sometimes referred to as “core banking”; this entails allowing a transaction in any branch to be reflected in real
time in the bank’s central data and accounts systems.
12 Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012
• Make it possible, under dispersed payment systems, to use zero balance accounts, with
any balances being swept into the TSA at the end of the day (and, if necessary, returned
the next day).
• Enable same-day crediting of the bank accounts of suppliers or employees. For central-
ized systems, this can be done without the need for intermediary transactions accounts,
but where they are still used, they will often be able to clear with the TSA on the same
day.
• Remove the requirement for expenditures to be prefinanced, or any government float or
“seed financing”, except perhaps to handle residual inefficiencies at the periphery.
17
The development of core banking and the RTGS is also usually a priority of the central
bank. In many countries, the modernization of the banking system has preceded the mod-
ernization of cash management. However, where the banking system is lagging, it is important
that the treasury takes the initiative with the central bank to map out a program for develop-
ment, using regulation or incentives, as necessary, to cajole the banks.
This model has implications for the commercial banks’ finances. The ability to hold onto
tax revenues for a time without paying interest before remitting them to the government has
been a traditional source of income in many countries, with lags of up to two weeks being
common. Also, as the government becomes more conscious of the need to repatriate balances
held by MDAs under dispersed payment systems, a further source of profits disappears. In
return for this largesse, the banks may be willing to waive fees for services, but the two costs
rarely offset, and this cross-subsidy may not support efficient pricing.
For these reasons, banks’ transactions services should be remunerated. The payment of
charges for collecting revenues and operationalizing retail payments—preferably a unit fee for
each transaction based on a formal contract or SLA—means that there is no need to compen-
sate the banks, for example through tax collection or expenditure payment holding periods. If
they exist at all, they should reflect only technological constraints.
The fees paid should not simply be cost-plus calculation, or read off the publicly avail-
able tariff. A competitive process is necessary, to be repeated at three- to five-year intervals.
The government should request bids against specified minimum standards. The government
always will be a major customer, and this gives it competitive strength. But it also may be
up against a banking system with a tendency to behave collusively. Another problem may be
that there is only one large bank with branches across the whole of the country. Competi-
tion therefore has to be organized imaginatively, and it may be that the business must be split
between more than one bank. In practice, governments often have been pleasantly surprised
by the results of competition. Banks want this business; for example, handling the payment of
17
This may not be strictly the case even in a developed fully integrated system. There may be a need for an in-
traday float to ensure that the banks have the liquidity needed to lubricate the payment systems, to enable them to
meet all obligations in real time. But any float occurring at the start of the day should be swept back at the end.
Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012 13
civil service salaries potentially gives them access to a large number of middle-class customers
to whom they can sell other banking services. There have been examples in Asia where, fol-
lowing a competition, the government pays close to nothing for the services offered, and even
receives a profit. This is also the case in Brazil, as demonstrated by the auctions that manage
civil servants’ payroll accounts in some states.
Under dispersed payment arrangements, the negotiation with the banks may be left to in-
dividual MDAs. Australia provides an example in this regard. However, the treasury will want
to insist on some core requirements, not the least of which will be end-of-day sweeping. Even
where there is a central contract, there will usually be some arrangements to allow MDAs to
negotiate specific requirements.
Payment for services makes the cost of banking more transparent. One corollary is that the
fees paid should be included explicitly in the budget. The implied cost will no longer be lost
in the net debt interest line (although the interest saved will typically offset the fees paid).
The same principles apply to the services supplied by the central bank, as discussed more
fully below. There may also need to be discussions with the central bank on issues such as the
service standards required by the bank’s government. This will ensure that they are consistent
with wider banking sector reforms.
As active cash management develops, the relationship between cash managers in the
treasury and the banks will develop a new dimension. The banks may already be the ma-
jor purchasers of T-bills. Nevertheless, the more flexible use of T-bills will put more weight
behind the consultative machinery. As cash managers start using repos or other money market
instruments, there will need to be direct contractual relationships with the banks (and other
counterparties), usually based on respective market standards.
18
The market should set the
price of transactions, whether sales and purchases are done through auctions, tenders, or
deals over the counter, or across trading exchanges.
IV. Some Policy Challenges in the Relationship Between the
Treasury and the Central Bank
D. Treasury Bills and Central Bank Bills
Although the needs of cash management and monetary policy normally coincide, there can be
strains between them. These arise particularly when the central bank does not have sufficient
means (collateral) to mop up excess domestic liquidity through repo operations. The liquid-
ity might be generated by foreign currency inflows, although there are other mechanisms that
18
Thus, the Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association, and the International Capital Markets Associa-
tion, have jointly developed a Global Master Repurchase Agreement. This agreement is used widely internationally,
although there may be an annex to cover the specific circumstances of the market concerned.
14 Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012
also have this effect. The need to absorb liquidity in the banking system may lead the central
bank to issue its own bills (CB-bills).
The use of different, but comparable, instruments for monetary policy and cash manage-
ment potentially risks market fragmentation. It could also lead to a loss of the benefits derived
from a larger and more liquid T-bill market. Essentially, the same demand is spread over two
types of instruments, implying that the volume of each issue is likely to be smaller than might
otherwise be the case, which would tend to reduce liquidity.
There are different ways to mitigate the problem of market fragmentation.
19
The central
bank and the treasury may agree to issue paper of different maturities; for example, the cen-
tral bank might issue CB-bills of two weeks or less, while the treasury would issue T-bills of
three months or more. They may be marketed differently, with T-bills also aimed at nonbanks.
Although such measures reduce the problem, they may not eliminate it. Another approach is
for the treasury to overfund the borrowing requirement, by issuing extra T-bills or T-bonds,
depositing the surplus cash in a sterilized account at the central bank, and allowing the cen-
tral bank to conduct monetary policy through repo or outright government securities transac-
tions in the secondary market. Mexico and Singapore offer past examples in this regard.
Under a more tailored approach, the treasury can sell additional T-bills at the central bank’s
request. This would be done as an add-on to the normal auction, but the proceeds would
be sterilized by holding them in a separate account at the central bank, remunerated at the
discount rate set in the bill auction. The treasury cannot draw on this account, but the bills
will be redeemed from it. This arrangement, and the amounts involved in each auction, must
be explained to the market.
These targeted arrangements require trust between the treasury and the central bank. In
particular, they would rely on the treasury’s constant willingness to accept requests from the
central bank to issue additional T-bills for monetary policy reasons. There may also be dif-
ficulties when the central bank’s borrowing requirements are much greater than the treasury’s.
In such cases, the central bank may want more control over the choice of maturities or the
conduct of auctions, rather than accepting a simple add-on to the treasury’s issuance plans.
In some countries (as was the case in New Zealand in the past), the central bank can issue
T-bills at its own discretion, with the proceeds passed directly to the government’s account.
This must be done within a framework agreed with the treasury, and should be transparently
explained to the market.
Another difficult issue that arises is how the cost should be shared. In the first instance, this
cost of open market operations falls to the central bank and is part of the cost of discharg-
ing its monetary policy operations. By paying interest on the treasury’s sterilized account at
19
For a more detailed discussion, see Williams (2010). The benefits of using T-bills to money market develop-
ment, and potentially to the central bank, are also discussed in Nyawata (2012).
Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012 15
the same rate of interest as materialized in the auction, the treasury is left unaffected, and the
central bank has to pay broadly the same rate as would have been the case if it had issued
CB-bills instead. The need to drain cash puts pressure on the central bank; it is expensive
compared to lending into the market to relieve a cash shortage which earns income. Some
countries have developed arrangements to reimburse the central bank for the cost of mon-
etary policy, whether directly or by foregoing a dividend. Certainly, where liquidity surpluses
are driven by credit to the government, the ministry of finance should be prepared to pay for
the costs of sterilizing that liquidity. But not paying interest on a sterilized account is a rather
crude approach, as the transfer depends on other money market developments and may also
undermine the treasury’s willingness to use the mechanism. In the long run, if the central
bank is chronically in deficit, it should be recapitalized from the budget or from long-term
government securities issued to it.
E. The TSA outside the Central Bank
In some countries, notably, but not only, in Latin America, government balances are partially
or totally held outside the central bank, in a government-owned commercial bank. Such a
bank can provide the pooling function of the TSA and help to protect the central bank from
fluctuations in the government’s cash position (although in practice the effect of the daily
fluctuation may be passed onto the market or to the central bank via the intermediary bank’s
transactions
20
).
However, implementation of this model requires some safeguards:
• A clear agency agreement giving the treasury unambiguous control over all government
balances, backed by timely and detailed information on those balances.
• Good coordination and information sharing.
• A market-based risk assessment of the bank, reducing any potential exposure of the
government to credit risk and moral hazard.
• Financial and cost transparency, covering the costs and activities performed on behalf of
the government.
Government-imposed requirements on the intermediary bank’s business model may also
leave the bank ill equipped to compete with more conventional banks. The bank may have
become heavily dependent on government deposits or collection lags to finance its business.
It may already be stretched financially, possibly as a result of having to meet social obligations
imposed by government. In other respects, competition may be affected by the bank having
inside information about government business.
This model cannot be unwound overnight. If the withdrawal of excess balances is too
rapid, the bank’s balance sheet may have to shrink significantly, notwithstanding the payment
20
In Peru, the central bank does not allow the Banco de la Nación to use the interbank market, in order to pre-
vent a government’s excess or shortage having an impact on the overnight interbank rate.
16 Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012
of transactions fees. This may require a phased withdrawal of balances to give the govern-
ment-owned commercial bank some room to adjust.
21
The government may, of course, wish
to continue using the bank for transaction purposes, particularly where it is the only one with
a presence in smaller towns and rural areas. In turn, this might constrain its ability to hold
unrestricted competition, but over time it is important to remove internal cross-subsidies, and
if there are social obligations, they should be subsidized more transparently.
F. Remuneration of Treasury Deposits by the Central Bank
Agreement is also needed on the rates of interest paid on the TSA balance and any other gov-
ernment deposits at the central bank.
It is good practice to pay a market-related interest rate:
• This improves transparency and avoids the implicit cross-subsidy associated with ad-
ministered rates.
• It removes the incentive for the treasury to make economically inappropriate decisions
in relation to its balances, such as placing funds in commercial banks with low credit
ratings.
As emphasized above, a corollary is that, in the interests of transparency and proper fi-
nancial incentives, the treasury should pay transaction-related fees. The main benefit of such
reciprocal arrangements between the treasury and the central bank is the avoidance of poten-
tial distortion to treasury choices about how best to invest surplus cash. For example, if the
central bank does not remunerate the deposits in the TSA, the treasury and MDAs may tend
to invest cash surpluses in commercial banks even without adequately evaluating the risk.
It is not always easy to move completely in this direction. There may be legislative con-
straints or pressures on the central bank’s balance sheet. In the short term, it may be expedi-
ent for the treasury to forego interest on a portion of the balances (although if it foregoes the
part lying below a certain threshold, the correct incentives will still apply to balances above
the threshold).
International practice varies. Interest is paid by central banks in proportionately more
developed countries than in emerging market or low-income countries.
22
Some examples are
21
Some counties, however, have adjusted their arrangements in recent years to mitigate some of the problems
that can arise. In Peru, only a modest balance is left at the end of the day in the government’s account in the Banco
de la Nación, with cash surpluses or deficits being settled with the government’s main account in the central bank.
In Chile, the government now deploys surplus short-term cash across a wider range of investments in the domes-
tic market, which may include putting term deposits in the central bank, rather than leaving it all with Banco del
Estado. In addition, the Chilean central bank is to be given notice of any one-off movement of substantial balances
from a commercial bank to the central bank to allow it to take into account the impact on liquidity; the central bank
may also prefer a staged process.
22
There are some notable exceptions, including the USA, although there market interest is paid on revenue
receipts held in Treasury Tax and Loan accounts.
Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012 17
provided in Box 4. A sound practice would be for the interest rate paid to the treasury to be at
the same level as the market overnight rate or the central bank’s policy rate.
G. Other Issues
In countries with less developed money markets, the constraints on liquidity management
may force the TSA held at the central bank into overdraft. Limitations on the use of the over-
draft should be defined, and the treasury should give reasonable notice to the central bank
of any drawdown. The payment of a market interest rate should act as a disincentive to use
it. Any overdraft should be used only for very limited short-term borrowing, and be repaid
before the end of the fiscal year.
Countries with a structural surplus of cash, such as from natural resources, may hold it
in the central bank, but outside the TSA in some form of sovereign wealth fund. The rules
to create and operate these accounts should be clearly defined, particularly in relation to the
treasury’s ownership of the resources, even if, in practice, the management of the account is
Box 4: Interest Paid on the TSA: Some International Experience
The payment of interest by the central bank is relatively rare among sub-Saharan African
countries, where there are often legislative constraints (South Africa and Ethiopia are
exceptions). This has also been the case in the past in Latin America, although interest
is now paid on balances in Peru and Mexico, and Chile currently earns a market rate on
most of its cash balances.
The benchmark rates that are used vary. They include the rates available for nonbank
deposits at commercial banks (Peru, Belarus, China) or for interbank deposits (Mexico);
the rates received on recent T-bill or related tenders (Italy, South Africa, Canada);
and the rates on counterpart assets held by the central banks (Brazil, Trinidad and
Tobago, countries in the Eastern Caribbean Currency Union). Benchmark rates also
include those linked to the central banks’ policies or corridor rates (the case for several
Eurozone countries, although different rates may be paid according to whether or not
the balances exceed target levels. Some other countries operate a similar size-related
schedule, such as in Mauritius). There are other examples where the interest paid is at
rates below the market’s rates (Philippines, Macedonia, and Vietnam), although currently
low international interest rates often make the differential negligible. The use of the rate
on counterpart assets when the balances are large helps to protect the central bank’s
balance sheet, although, arguably, it is then acting as agent, and the treasury should
have a role in identifying the assets. The same general point applies to those wealth
or stabilization funds held on central banks’ balance sheets (for example, Botswana
and Peru). In Brazil, the counterpart assets mirror the outstanding stock of debt in the
market. This gives the monetary authority a range of instruments to use as collateral,
and also remunerates the treasury at a rate that reflects the overall cost of debt.
Many central banks that do not pay market interest rates on the main TSA current
account are willing to do so on term deposits.
18 Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012
provided by the central bank. Transparent governance mechanisms should be defined, includ-
ing those for investments and reporting.
V. Coordination Structures
As discussed above, the coordination between the treasury and the central bank should
encompass both policy and operational aspects. On policy, it is important to ensure the
coherence of fiscal and monetary policies; this is high-level coordination. For operations, the
main aspects would be related to the functioning of the TSA, issuance of bonds and bills, and
market development.
The relationship should operate at different levels, reflecting the nature of the issues being
addressed. It is helpful to distinguish between:
• Meetings at the level of minister/governor, which may be shadowed by meetings be-
tween senior ministry and central bank officials.
• Standing committees, for example, a public debt committee and treasury liquidity, or
cash coordination committees.
• Technical working groups.
• Day-to-day operational interactions.
The overall relationship between the treasury and the central bank needs to be clarified at a
high level. This will, in turn, depend on the respective roles and responsibilities. They may be
specified in legislation. At the other end of the spectrum, there may simply be an exchange of
letters. Nonetheless, there are two types of issues that need to be addressed at the senior level:
• How to ensure policy coherence, as discussed above. This needs some formal mecha-
nism that does not compromise the central bank’s operational independence. It might be
done through a monetary policy committee on which the ministry of finance is repre-
sented as an observer,
23
or through some other forum, such as a PDC. A PDC, chaired
by a minister or senior official, would consider the debt (and cash) management strategy
that integrates the asset-liability management analysis of the government’s balance sheet
into a broader macroeconomic framework. It would then delegate the execution of the
strategy and monitor its achievement. Such a committee can ensure that all relevant
interests and experts are consulted (macro and fiscal teams in the ministry of finance and
23
The observer should not have any role in relation to monetary policy decisions, which are the prerogative of
the central bank. An arrangement along these lines operates in the UK, where a representative from the Treasury
acts as an observer at the Bank of England’s Monetary Policy Committee. He or she takes no part in setting interest
rates, but this mechanism provides an opportunity for the Treasury to set out its latest fiscal and debt management
policies, and for the Bank of England to offer its comments. In addition, the objectives of the UK Debt Management
Office include consistency with the aims of monetary policy.
Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012 19
the central bank), and agree on a strategy.
24
At the same time, the PDC will help buttress
the operational independence of the debt and cash management functions by reducing
the risk that other functions might try to second-guess, or intervene in, operational deci-
sions once the strategy has been set.
• These formal mechanisms need to address policy clashes or other misunderstandings
that threaten to damage the effectiveness of either institution. When needed, such issues
might conveniently be added to the agendas of the regular meetings—that happen in
most countries with varying degrees of formality—between the governor of the central
bank and the minister of finance. Such arrangements will do more than fire fight prob-
lems. There may be areas of coordination to be explored, such as those related to sharing
the investment in new databases, where a high-level stimulus might be needed.
• Such mechanisms can also guide major one-off decisions. One example is central
bank recapitalization, which needs to address the form of remuneration. If securities
are used, as is typically the case, they should be made marketable, with the maturity
profile adjusted to take account of the central bank’s collateral requirements, the gov-
ernment’s own refinancing profile, and the nature of the market’s demand in the event
that they are sold.
Some form of protocol, terms of reference, or memoranda of understanding may cover
operational interaction. It would set out the relevant issues and the route for consultation,
covering, for example:
• The joint program for the development of the money market.
• The manner in which the central bank should report its perspective on the views of the
market and investors regarding the debt and cash management program for the coming
period (although this might be covered by the PDC).
• The central bank’s own views on new cash management operations that could have
liquidity implications.
• Policies and operations for bill issuance, given the need for an agreed strategy for the
development of the bill market and the respective roles of CB-bills and T-bills.
• The agreement between the central bank and the ministry of finance on a common list
of primary dealers or auction counterparties (although more commonly that is left to
each institution).
25
24
The strategy needs to analyze the risks inherent in the government’s aggregate balance sheet, including both
assets and liabilities. This involves taking into account the size and composition of the foreign currency reserves.
Similarly, investment objectives for the reserves—notably liquidity, safety, and return—should be considered in the
context of strategic objectives for other parts of the government balance sheet, including the debt portfolio. The
PDC would have an important role in ensuring a full asset-liability management analysis, as well as developing
policy in that context.
25
In Brazil, the treasury and the central bank have agreed on a common set of criteria, although the treasury
determines who participates in its auctions.
20 Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012
• The payment of interest on government balances at the central bank. This has to be
agreed at the policy level, but the basis of interest—maturity, relevant market analogues,
etc.—should also be identified.
• The arrangements for the exchange of information about cash flow forecasts (responsi-
bilities and frequency).
• The mechanism of communication and the issues covered (for example, the prospective
auction schedule).
• Determinants of such issues as the timing within the day or week of respective auctions
or tenders, and the associated market announcements and any prior warnings.
• In countries where the treasury is able to borrow from the central bank, the protocols
regarding the limits (sums, maturities, roll-over capabilities, etc.) of such borrowing.
The published agreement between the Ministry of Finance and the Central Bank of Iceland
sets out the central bank’s functions as fiscal agent and debt manager, and could therefore
serve as a useful example for how the official interaction could be defined.
26
It does not cover
all the above issues in detail, but ranges widely across issues regarding the management of
domestic government securities; the management of foreign debt; government guarantees and
relending; information disclosure; risk management and liquidity management; and consulta-
26
See http://eng.fjarmalaraduneyti.is/media/finances/Agreement_between_MoF_and_CBoI.pdf.
Box 5: Cash Coordinating Committee
Members
• Head of Treasury (chair).
• Head of Debt Management Office (DMO [if not integrated with treasury]).
• Head of Fiscal and/or Budget Directorate.
• Representative of the Central Bank.
• As required: representatives of the revenue administration, customs, and/or repre-
sentatives of larger line ministries.
• Secretary from the Treasury or DMO.
• Other units on a need basis.
Responsibilities
• Reviewing cash flow outturns, and the comparison with forecasts.
• Reviewing cash flow forecasts for the period ahead.
• Deciding on the action needed to ensure cash adequacy over the coming time
frame, or how to use surpluses to best effect.
• Making recommendations and/or instructing the front office accordingly, setting
parameters for delegated authority.
Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012 21
tion arrangements between the ministry and the bank. Although there is no published SLA,
the aggregated service payment is specified in the arrangement.
In practice, the issues listed may be captured in more than one protocol. There often will
be separate protocols, as specific policy decisions have been codified. The arrangements for
handling auctions will often be separately prepared along with published guidance or regu-
lations. In Peru, there is a detailed memorandum (in the form of a ministerial resolution)
covering the terms and conditions, and procedures applying to treasury deposits at the central
bank (although it does not cover the rate to be paid on domestic currency deposits, which is
separately determined by the central bank).
Several countries have found it convenient to establish some form of cash coordinating
committee (CCC) or liquidity committee. It might meet weekly or monthly to consider cash
management requirements and consequent activity for the period immediately ahead. A typi-
cal example is illustrated in Box 5. The CCC might be the mechanism which exchanges cash
flow forecasts with the central bank, and reviews the cash management operations for the
coming period. Separate technical committees may need to be established to handle specific
issues, such as the introduction of a new instrument.
VI. Service Level Agreements
The central bank will supply a number of services to the treasury. The most important of
these will be as banker, although the central bank will also provide some services that fall un-
der the general heading of debt and cash management. These may include fulfilling the roles
of fiscal agent, settlement agent, and/or registrar/paying agent. At the same time, the treasury
will provide services to the central bank; some examples have already been mentioned above,
notably the cash flow forecasts.
Although the general nature of the services may be covered by a memorandum of under-
standing, if there is an identifiable service of a quasi-contractual nature being supplied, this
fact should be made explicit. Having a full-fledged contract between two organizations that
are guaranteed by the central government may be inappropriate. However, some form of SLA
would be expected to give weight to the expectations on both sides.
Issues covered by the SLA might include:
• The notice that both sides would give of any impending changes in the auction pattern
or timetable.
• The central bank’s turnaround times in handling any relevant transactions as fiscal or
settlement agent.
• Details of information flows in both directions, with the intended timing schedule (for
example, cash flow forecasts or transactions across the TSA).
22 Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012
• Details to be supplied by the central bank, specifically in its role as banker, on move-
ments through the TSA during the day (or how it is otherwise to give the treasury some
visibility). These arrangements will also cover the formal statement at the end of the day
on opening and closing balances, as well as transactions.
• The basis of the calculation of fees paid for services. This might include compensation
arrangements for any failure to meet the specified level of service.
• Details of the rate of interest to be paid on government accounts, including the use of
any reference rate, and the circumstances in which it might be changed.
• The exchange of risk-related information. Increasingly in the financial services sector, a
significant supplier of services is required to present external audit evidence of the ap-
propriateness and adequacy of its internal control system to the principal. If that is not
possible in the case of the central bank, some analogue should be explored.
• The handling of any business continuity problems.
• The arrangements for handling disputes, reviewing the central bank’s performance under
the SLA, and for future review or renegotiation of the SLA.
Some SLAs are published. In France, the agency with the responsibility for debt and cash
management (Agence France Trésor) has published the details of its agreement with the cen-
tral bank concerning the TSA.
27
It specifies the instruments used by the bank to ensure that
the French Government can keep track of the transactions in its account in real time, and use
that visibility to reduce the average unused account balance. In addition to details of infor-
mation flows and execution deadlines, it also specifies service availability covering technical
incidents and the implementation of backup procedures. Finally, it requires compensation for
investment opportunities that are missed as a result of the central bank’s inability to honor its
contractual commitments. In Romania, the Ministry of Public Finance has an extensive SLA
with the central bank. It covers the operation of the TSA (both domestic and foreign currency
accounts including interest paid); the roles of the bank as fiscal agent, government bond
registrar, and settlement and paying agent; and the participation of the ministry in the pay-
ments systems. It sets out the rights and obligations of both parties, including those relating
to operational risk management, and lists the transaction-based fees in detail.
The arrangements with the transactions banks should normally be covered by a more
conventional contract.
27
See http://www.aft.gouv.fr/article_787.html.
Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012 23
VII. Conclusion
The development of a modern cash management function potentially affects the operations,
finances, and balance sheets of the government, central bank, and commercial banks. The
implications and management of this function depend on the wider relationship between the
treasury and the central bank, the characteristics of monetary policy operations, the gover-
nance structures, and any prior monetary conditions:
• The reforms will usually move government cash from the banking sector into the central
bank. This reduction in idle cash will benefit the treasury, but at a cost to the commer-
cial banks.
• There may be a cost to the central bank if it pays interest (as it should) on the treasury’s
balances. At the same time, the drain of cash from the banking system should in most
circumstances support the central bank’s monetary policy operations.
• As the treasury builds its capability for managing cash more actively, there will be ben-
efits both to the government and to the central bank’s monetary policy operations, flow-
ing from the reduced fluctuations in the government’s balances in the TSA.
• Structural reforms to remove cross-subsidies and improve transparency, including the
introduction of transaction fees, may have further effects, although net additional costs
could fall on either the treasury or the central bank. There may be also a presentational
challenge for the government as, for the first time, payments are put more transparently
into the budget.
There will be transitional issues that need to be addressed. The central bank must accept a
change in roles and responsibilities, and any one-off shift in financial flows should be phased
over a period if it would otherwise complicate monetary policy operations. Implications for
balance sheets will need to be monitored.
The institutional relationship between the treasury and the central bank needs to be struc-
tured at different levels. There will be points of contention regarding where market or liquid-
ity risks should fall; on respective operational requirements; and on how best to meet interest
or transactions costs. At the same time, there are benefits from operational coordination, and
also common policy interests, especially in creating an efficient money market. Memoranda of
understanding will need to be put in place. The services supplied by the central bank to the
treasury should be covered by an SLA. None of these measures should jeopardize the inde-
pendence of the central bank in relation to monetary policy.
24 Technical Notes and Manuals 12/02 | 2012
References
Blommestein, Hans J., and Turner, Philip, 2011, “Interactions between Sovereign Debt
Management and Monetary Policy under Fiscal Dominance and Financial Instabil-
ity,” (Social Science Research Network), Available via the Internet: http://ssrn.com/
abstract=1964627
Lienert, Ian, 2009, “Modernizing Cash Management,” IMF Technical Notes and Manuals
(Washington: International Monetary Fund), Available via the Internet: http://www.
imf.org/external/pubs/ft/tnm/2009/tnm0903.pdf
Nunes, Selene Peres Peres and Nunes, Ricardo, 1999, “Relacionamento entre Tesouro Na-
cional e Banco Central: Aspectos de Coordenação entre Política Fiscal e Monetária no
Brasil,” (Brasilia: ESAF), Available via the Internet: http://www.tesouro.fazenda.gov.br/
Premio_TN/ivpremio/divida/2afdpIVPTN/NUNES_Selene_NUNES_Ricardo.pdf
Nyawata, Obert, 2012, “Treasury Bills and/or Central Bank Bills for Absorbing Surplus
Liquidity: The Main Considerations,” IMF Working Paper WP/12/40 (Washington: In-
ternational Monetary Fund). Available via the Internet at: http://www.imf.org/external/
pubs/cat/longres.aspx?sk=25697.0
Pattanayak, Sailendra, and Fainboim, Israel, 2011, “Treasury Single Account: An Essential
Tool for Government Cash Management,” IMF Technical Notes and Manuals. (Wash-
ington: International Monetary Fund). Available via the Internet: http://www.imf.org/
external/pubs/ft/wp/2011/tnm1104.pdf
Togo, Eriko, 2007, “Coordinating Public Debt Management with Fiscal and Monetary Poli-
cies: An Analytical Framework,” Policy Research Working Paper No. 4369 (Washing-
ton: World Bank). Available via the Internet: http://www-wds.worldbank.org/external/
default/WDSContentServer/WDSP/IB/2007/09/28/000158349_20070928133057/
Rendered/PDF/WPS4369.pdf
Turner, Philip, 2011, “Fiscal Dominance and the Long-Term Interest Rate,” Special Paper
Series 199 (London: London School of Economics). Available via the Internet: http://
www2.lse.ac.uk/fmg/workingPapers/specialPapers/SP199.pdf
Williams, Mike, 2010, “Government Cash Management: Its Interaction with Other Financial
Policies,” IMF Technical Notes and Manuals 19. (Washington: International Monetary
Fund). Available via the Internet: http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/tnm/2010/
tnm1013.pdf
World Bank, 2007, “Developing the Domestic Government Debt Market: from
Diagnostics to Reform Implementation” (Washington: World Bank).
Available via the Internet: http://publications.worldbank.org/index.
php?main_page=product_info&cPath=0&products_id=22542
TNM/12/02
International Monetary Fund
Fiscal Affairs Department
700 19th Street NW
Washington, DC 20431
USA
Tel: 1-202-623-8554
Fax: 1-202-623-6073
Government Cash Management:
Relationship between the Treasury
and the Central Bank
Mario Pessoa and Mike Williams
Fiscal Affairs Department
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
Technical noTes and Manuals