Working Paper No. 872
Federalism, Fiscal Space, and Public Investment Spending:
Do Fiscal Rules Impose Hard Budget Constraints?*
by
Pinaki Chakraborty
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College
August 2016
* Paper presented at the workshop “Central Local Government Relations: Fiscal Sustainability,” organized by the ADB Institute (ADBI),
Tokyo, Japan, and Zhongnan University of Economics and Law, Wuhan, China, and held at Zhongnan Univerisity on October 2425,
2015. The author is grateful to ADBI for the opportunity to write this paper for the workshop. Comments received from Naoyuki
Yoshino, Jorge Martinez-Vazquez, Peter Morgan, and Fang Ying are gratefully acknowledged. The author is also grateful to Abhishek
for research assistance and to Antra Bhatt for helping with the review of literature. Lekha Chakraborty also made very useful suggestions
for improving the draft, and Usha Mathur provided able secretarial assistance. Contact: [email protected].in.
The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute
scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments
from academics and professionals.
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit,
nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service.
Through scholarship and economic research it generates viable, effective public policy
responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in
the United States and abroad.
Levy Economics Institute
P.O. Box 5000
Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000
http://www.levyinstitute.org
Copyright © Levy Economics Institute 2016 All rights reserved
ISSN 1547-366X
1
ABSTRACT
The primary objective of rule-based fiscal legislation at the subnational level in India is to
achieve debt sustainability by placing a ceiling on borrowing and the use of borrowed
resources for public capital investment by phasing out deficits in the budget revenue account.
This paper examines whether the application of fiscal rules has contributed to an increase in
fiscal space for public capital investment spending in major Indian states. Our analysis shows
that, controlling for other factors, there is a negative relationship between fiscal rules and
public capital investment spending at the state level under the rule-based fiscal regime.
Keywords: Fiscal Deficit; Revenue Deficit; Fiscal Rule
JEL Classifications: H00, H6
2
India is a federal country of 29 states and 7 centrally administered union territories. It has a
highly decentralized federal fiscal structure in which state governments spend more than 56
percent of total public spending but their share of combined revenue is only 38 percent.
Although there are multiple channels of transfers, this gap between revenues and
expenditures is met primarily through vertical transfers from the Union to the states through
the statutory Finance Commission.
1
Burgeoning fiscal deficits at the subnational level were a
major fiscal management issue for India during the 1990s and early 2000s. During this
period, piecemeal attempts were made to bring fiscal discipline to the state level, both at the
insistence of the central government and in the form of state-specific interventions by
multilateral institutions (e.g., the Asian Development Bank and the World Bank).
In order to ensure fiscal discipline, the 12th Finance Commission of India (Finance
Commission 2004) recommended rule-based fiscal controls at the state level. This also
created a mechanism for providing performance incentive–based transfers for better fiscal
management.
2
Performance incentives in the form of debt consolidation and relief were
linked to reductions in state-level fiscal and revenue deficits
3
relative to the gross state
domestic product (GSDP) within a rule-based fiscal framework.
4
This process of legislative
control over deficits was further reinforced by the 13th Finance Commission (Finance
Commission 2009) by providing separate performance incentive grants.
As per the recommendations of the 12th Finance Commission, if a state enacted a Fiscal
Responsibility Act (FRA) specifying 3 percent of GSDP as the upper bound for its fiscal
deficit and eliminated its deficit in the current account of the budget (i.e., revenue deficit)
within a specific time period (by 2008–09), the state became eligible for debt rescheduling. If
a particular state adhered to those targets specified in the act, a part of the state’s debt to the

1
The Finance Commission is a statutory constitutional body appointed by the President of India quinquennially
for the distribution of the net proceeds of taxes of the Union government between the Union and the states and
establishing principles that should govern the grants in aid of the revenues of the states out of the Consolidated
Fund of India. Apart from the Finance Commission, resources to the states are transferred through Planning
Commission and various ministries of the Union government. Finance Commission–recommended transfer
continues to be the primary channel of resource transfer to the states.
2
Prior to the recommendations of the Finance Commission in 2004, a few states introduced FRAs on their own.
A few of them did it as a part of the subnational structural adjustment lending program support provided by the
Asian Development Bank and the World Bank. A review is available in Rao and Chakraborty (2006).
3
Revenue deficit is the difference between revenue receipts and revenue expenditure and fiscal deficit is the
total borrowing or the aggregate resource gap in the budget.
4
Although state-specific FRAs have other commitments (such as reduction in guarantees given by the state
governments, the level of contingent liabilities, and in some cases, level of debt), the incentive-based transfers
from the Union government structured by the Finance Commission were linked to the reduction in revenue and
fiscal deficits. Thus we primarily focus on these two indicators.
3
federal government would be written off. All the states in India now have adopted FRAs. The
provisions included in these acts are more or less similar across states, particularly with
regard to revenue and fiscal deficit reduction. As specified in the state-specific acts, states
cannot borrow more than 3 percent of GSDP and are required to eliminate their revenue
deficit within a specified time frame. Since the primary objective of the act is to phase out
revenue deficits and to put an overall cap on borrowing, the core emphasis therefore is to
improve public capital investment. Thus, if revenue deficit is zero, public capital investment
will be equal to government borrowing. If there is revenue surplus, investment will be equal
to borrowing plus the revenue surplus. The fixed borrowing limit of 3 percent of GSDP on
the other hand is to ensure overall fiscal sustainability of subnational debt through a hard
budget constraint. State-specific acts also imposed limits on government guarantees,
associated contingent liabilities, and off-budget borrowing.
The main objective of this paper is to examine whether the application of a fiscal rule resulted
in an increase in the fiscal space for public capital investment spending in Indian states. The
focus is state-level capital spending, reflected in state budgets, although it does not include all
public sector investment in a state, as data are not readily available. For aggregate public
sector investment in a state, there are measurement issues regarding intra-public sector
transactions and investments. It is therefore difficult to arrive at a precise estimate and these
transactions are not considered in the present analysis.
Although macroeconomic stabilization is a federal government function, subnational deficit
controls have implications for both macrostabilization and overall fiscal management in
India, since the central government and the states are co-equal partners in public spending
and both the levels of governments have large fiscal imbalances. In other words, fiscal and
macroeconomic stability in a large federation like India depends not only on the fiscal deficit
of the central government but also on the states’ deficits. In India, states in the pre-FRA
period had a combined fiscal deficit almost equal to that of the federal government. The
average state fiscal deficit was 4.5 percent of GDP during 1998–99 to 2003–04, while the
central government’s fiscal deficit was 5.2 percent of GDP for the same period. Since the
combined state deficits are large, and given the multilevel fiscal structure, overall deficit
reduction may not be fully achieved if deficits are not controlled for by each level of
government. From this standpoint, this research paper adds value to understanding the
complexities of macro fiscal policies in a large federal system.
4
FISCAL RULES: ARE THEY USEFUL?
Rules may be necessary to restrain governments that engage in discretionary policies which
have a deficit bias (Buchanan and Wagner 1977), and to promote consistency in policy
commitments (Kydland and Prescott 1977). Koptis (2001) argued for a well-designed rule-
based fiscal policy for mitigating a country’s susceptibility to a crisis. According to Koptis,
an inconsistency between a country’s fiscal stance and its exchange rate regime played an
important role in the currency crises of many countries (e.g., Russia, Brazil, and Ecuador).
These crises were also due to capital outflows where foreign investors’ perceptions about
government solvency were an important factor. Khemani (2008) argued that in decentralized
economies, the implementation of fiscal rules could be useful for incentivizing better fiscal
performance by state and local governments, and thus promoting fiscal prudence. However,
the incentive structure may need to be designed in such a way that local governments do not
circumvent transfer conditionalities, and in doing so not follow fiscal rules. The extant
empirical literature, such as Krogstrup and Walti (2008), Feld and Kirchgssner (2006), and
Schaltegger (2001), shows that fiscal rules have a significant impact on budget balances. A
few studies carried out using US data show that the strength of the fiscal rule was directly
proportional to a reduction in unexpected deficits (Poterba 1995; Alt and Lowry 1994;
Alesina and Bayoumi 1996). In the case of Canadian provinces, a few studies indicate that
provincial legislation to limit deficits led to stronger budget balances, ceteris paribus (Tellier
and Imbeau 2004). The literature on the impact of fiscal rules on fiscal performance in
emerging-market economics is rather scanty (Chakraborty and Dash 2013).
WHY FISCAL RULES MAY NOT WORK
Milesi-Ferreti (2004) analyzed the effectiveness of fiscal rules in light of “creative
accounting.” Creative accounting is defined as a measure by means of which an improvement
in the fiscal balance is observed without an accompanying actual improvement in the
intertemporal budgetary position of the government. Using a two-period model developed by
Hagen and Harden (1996) and assuming that fiscal rules are being imposed on the
“measured” fiscal balance and that a penalty must be paid if creative accounting is detected, it
is observed that budget transparency is inversely proportional to creative accounting.
Additionally, even if the costs of engaging in creative accounting are large, tighter rules may
5
still induce creative accounting. Manasse (2007) discussed the incentive effects of budget
limits. According to this study, when limits are imposed on the deficit-output ratio,
governments keep the deficit just below the limit to avoid sanctions and have no incentive to
practice fiscal consolidation during “good times.” These rules then also indirectly have large
negative effects on welfare.
Apart from rule-based fiscal controls, there have been wide-ranging international experiences
with structural adjustment lending for fiscal consolidation with mixed outcomes. A World
Bank (1992) review
5
observed that adjustment lending was associated with fiscal deficit
reduction and an increase in revenue, but the general spending cuts were often at the expense
of critically important operation and maintenance and there was too much spending on
salaries relative to non-salary inputs. Mavrotas and Quattara (2003), while analyzing the
effect of development assistance on public sector behavior, observed that official
development assistance (as measured by the OECD) reduced revenues in the short run but
raised them in the long run. The study by Gupta et al. (2003) of foreign aid in 107 countries
during the period 1970 to 2000 observed that while concessional loans were associated with
higher domestic revenue, mobilization grants had the opposite effect.
APPROPRIATE STRUCTURE FOR FISCAL RULES
The key goal of a fiscal rule is to achieve higher credibility for fiscal policy by reducing
discretionary intervention in the conduct of macroeconomic policies. With regard to design, a
fiscal rule should be well defined, transparent, focused, consistent with macroeconomic
policies, simple, flexible enough to accommodate cyclical fluctuations, enforceable, and
supported by efficient policies (Kopits and Symansky 1998). It has been argued that a fiscal
rule indicator needs to be operationally simple, flexible, growth oriented, and easily
monitored.
In the case of decentralized economies, two approaches are generally adopted: an
autonomous approach and a coordinated approach. In the case of a coordinated approach, all
subnational governments are subject to the same rule. In the case of India, the fiscal rule as

5
Cited in World Bank (2005)
6
imposed is also simple and has been applied with uniform deficit reduction targets across
states. The European Union and emerging economies focused on targets that are numerical
and uniform across countries (the autonomous approach).
A key component of the design of fiscal rules is ensuring their sustainability and deciding on
an optimal level of fiscal rule indicators. The literature on sustainable fiscal rules has evolved
since the 1990s, when rules were considered to be appropriate if they respected the
intertemporal budget constraint. Spaventa (1987) finds that a design where the sustainability
of a fiscal rule is based on the satisfaction of the budget constraint does not take into account
the financial situation of the public sector. Using a sovereign debt framework (which assumes
that the government cannot choose the duration of its debt), Hatchondo, Martinez, and Roch
(2012) show that implementing a debt ceiling may prove beneficial for the government, as an
expectation of a lower debt level would lead to a decline in interest rates. They also find that
lower debt ceilings lead to less responsiveness in the interest rate to income shocks, and
consumption becomes less volatile as fiscal policy becomes less procyclical. Pappa and
Vassilatos (2007) and Poplawski Ribeiro, Beetsma, and Schabert (2008) find that debt
ceilings may be better indicators than a ceiling on the government’s deficit.
A more recent framework by Bertelsmann (2013) supports the establishment of independent
fiscal institutions (IFIs) as an important component of ensuring that the fiscal rules are
adhered to and that the mechanism includes design factors to ensure strong monitoring and
evaluation of rules on a continuous basis. These IFIs could exercise an advisory role, report
the true magnitude of government liabilities, and project the long-term implications of fiscal
policy and new fiscal policy announcements. Arguments in favor of IFIs include the
following: better transparency in public finances; at a more sophisticated level, an IFI can
also undertake the task of monitoring and ensuring compliance with a fiscal rule, as well as
include sanctions for nonobservance of a debt ceiling; and finally, IFIs can also encourage
and assist governments with publishing public finance data at regular intervals and placing
these data in the public domain.
7
SUBNATIONAL FISCAL RULES IN INDIA
In India, at the instance of the World Bank and the Asian Development Bank, fiscal rules
were introduced by a few states prior to the recommendations of the 12th Finance
Commission. This was done through multilateral structural adjustment lending to the states
by these banks (Rao and Chakraborty 2007). The 12th Finance Commission’s
recommendations became operational in fiscal year 2005–06. The states that enacted FRAs
prior to this and in accordance with the recommendation of the 12th Finance Commission are
shown in appendix table A2.
6
The incentive structure of the FRA proposed by the 12th
Finance Commission is the following:
[E]ach state should enact fiscal responsibility legislation. This
has been stipulated as a precondition for availing the debt-
relief scheme. This legislation should, at a minimum, provide
for (a) eliminating revenue deficit by 2008–09; (b) reducing
fiscal deficit to 3 percent of GSDP or its equivalent defined as
ratio of interest payment to revenue receipts; (c) bringing out
annual reduction targets of revenue and fiscal deficits; (d)
bringing out annual statement giving prospects for the state
economy and related fiscal strategy; (e) bringing out special
statements along with the budget giving in detail number of
employees in government, public sector, and aided institutions
and related salaries.
To avail themselves of the debt consolidation and relief facility under the act, all the states
(except Sikkim and West Bengal) enacted their FRAs with a uniform deficit target (both
revenue and fiscal deficits) following the submission of 12th Finance Commission report in
2004. Already existing state-specific FRAs were amended to comply with the
recommendations of the 12th Finance Commission. It is important to highlight that the 12th
Finance Commission emphasized that all states only needed to enact an FRA as prescribed to
receive debt consolidation. However, to be eligible for debt relief, states were required to
adhere to the targets of deficit reduction prescribed in the act. In addition to adhering to the
Commission’s prescription of numerical deficit targets, several states volunteered to impose
different fiscal restrictions on themselves, such as targeting outstanding liabilities,
institutional rules for expenditure management, and timely review of fiscal performance, as
summarized in Simone and Topalova (2009). The process of fiscal consolidation continued

6
The 12th Finance Commission’s report was submitted in November 2004 and the recommendations became
operational beginning in the fiscal year 2005–06.
8
for the period from fiscal years 2005–06 to 2009–10, the five-year award period of the 12th
Finance Commission.
7
The 13th Finance Commission also proposed an incentive framework
to ensure that the states remain within the FRA deficit targets. There was some apprehension
that maintaining fiscal prudence post–global financial crisis would be a challenging task.
As articulated in 13th Finance Commission Report, in 2009–10 the combined (Union and the
states) debt-to-GDP ratio remained high (82 percent) despite fiscal correction through the
implementation of fiscal responsibility frameworks during the period from 2005 to 2010. The
13th Finance Commission proposed a target of 68 percent for the combined Union and state
debt-to-GDP ratio by the year 2014–15, with the central government’s debt-to-GDP ratio
reaching 45 percent. The Commission had taken the elimination of the revenue deficit as the
long-term and permanent target for both the Union and the states. The Commission’s
prescribed fiscal consolidation path for the central government required a decline in the
revenue deficit from 4.8 percent of GDP (as projected for the fiscal year 2009–10) to a
revenue surplus of 0.5 percent of GDP by 2014–15. These prescriptions of fiscal
consolidation in turn allowed for acceleration in capital expenditures to 3.5 percent of GDP
by 2014–15. As assessed by the 13th Finance Commission, the proposed fiscal consolidation
path was growth promoting, as it focused on the elimination of the revenue deficit to ensure
that net public borrowing was exclusively used for growth-enhancing public investment.
8
As noted in the 13th Finance Commission Report, 26 states (operating under their FRA)
reached their expenditure and debt targets ahead of the scheduled timeframe proposed by the
12th Finance Commission and showed significant fiscal correction. According to the 13th
Finance Commission, the main reason behind this fiscal correction was the benefit of higher
shares of federal taxes due to the high federal tax growth and improvement in state tax
revenues. State debt-to-GSDP was also reduced sharply during this period to below 30
percent of GDP. However, there were wide variations in fiscal performance among the states
(an issue we discuss later). In order to continue to strengthen the process of fiscal

7
As per the Indian Constitution, the Finance Commission is a temporary body appointed quinquennially to
recommend devolution of taxes and grants to the states for five years.
8
The Commission recognized that states were permitted to borrow more than the Fiscal Responsibility and
Budget Management Act (FRBMA) targets in 2008–09 and 2009–10. This specific relaxation of targets for two
years was a part of the fiscal stimulus package announced by the central government to increase government
spending to contain the adverse impact of the global financial crisis. Due to this relaxation of target, the
Commission allowed one year (i.e., 2010–11) as a year of adjustment and recommended fiscal consolidation
from 2011–12 (Finance Commission 2009: 25).
9
consolidation at the state level, the 13th Finance Commission made the following
recommendations:
The Medium Term Fiscal Plan should make explicit the values
of the parameters underlying expenditure and revenue
projections and the band within which these parameters can
vary while remaining consistent with FRBMA targets.
The FRBMA should specify the nature of shocks which would
be required before any relaxation of FRBMA targets.
States should amend/enact their FRBMAs to build in the fiscal
reform adopted by the state. State-specific grants
recommended for a state should be released upon compliance
with fiscal reform goals. (Finance Commission 2010: 6)
KEY FISCAL INDICATORS: THE LONG-RUN TREND
In 1991, a large combined fiscal deficit on the order of 9.9 percent of GDP (i.e., the Union’s
fiscal deficit of 6.6 percent and combined state deficit of 3.19 percent) and a huge external
current account deficit, coupled with dwindling foreign exchange reserves, are considered to
be the factors that contributed to the macroeconomic crisis and the subsequent economic
reforms in India. One key component of the big-bang economic reform was fiscal
consolidation. Fiscal reform was a combination of tax reforms, expenditure control, and
reforms in the management of public debt. We will discuss these very briefly.
As part of the fiscal reform, a major tax reform initiative was undertaken to overhaul
the country’s complex tax system. Simplification and moderation in the tax rate and
modernization of the tax administration system were the main components of tax reform. The
peak rate of personal income tax was reduced from 50 percent in 1991 to 30 percent in 1997–
98.
9
The reform of indirect taxes was comprised of a reduction in the customs tariffs and the
Union excise duty structure. A sharp rate reduction in indirect taxes contributed to the decline
in indirect tax revenue during the 1990s, but direct tax revenue had shown commendable
growth during this period. As the share of indirect taxes was much higher than direct taxes,
the increase in the direct tax could not offset the revenue loss from indirect taxes.

9
Currently India has one of the lowest income tax rates in the world.
10
As revenues were not rising, in the initial years of economic reform fiscal consolidation was
achieved by reducing discretionary development spending through reducing capital
expenditure for public investment. However, the success achieved in containing the deficit
during first half of 1990s was short lived. The impact of the Fifth Pay Commission award
10
created an explosive fiscal imbalance at the federal level, as well as in the states, taking the
combined fiscal deficit to 9.39 percent of GDP in 1999–2000 (see figure 1). However, the
fiscal deficit started declining gradually from 2002–03 and reached an all-time low of 4
percent in 2007–08. This was a spectacular improvement in the fiscal situation of all levels of
government compared to 1991. This phase was also characterized by high growth in
revenues. During 2003–04 to 2007–08, central government revenues grew at the rate of 18.58
percent, and the states’ revenues grew at the rate of 16.46 percent. GDP growth during the
same period was 8.89 percent per annum.
In 2003, the central government enacted the Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management
Act (FRBMA). As mentioned earlier, the states also enacted their state-level Fiscal
Responsibility Acts (FRAs) on the recommendation of the 12th Finance Commission. All of
the states, except West Bengal and Sikkim, enacted their respective FRAs during this period.
Many public finance specialists attributed the decline in deficits in the years leading up to
2007–08 to FRA legislation. However, with the global financial crisis, India again
experienced high levels of fiscal imbalance (see figure 1), especially at the level of the central
government. The changes in the fiscal deficit as a percentage of GDP for the period from
1990–91 to 2014–15 (budget estimates) is given in figure 1. However, states remained
fiscally prudent during the post–global financial crisis period. The outstanding-debt-to-GDP
ratio also declined significantly in recent years and fell well below the targeted level
recommended by the 13th Finance Commission, both for the central and state governments.

10
The Fifth Pay Commission award was a pay hike for the government employees, representing a consequent
increase in government expenditure.
11
Figure 1: Fiscal Deficit as Percentage of GDP
Figure 2: Outstanding Debt as Percentage of GDP
Although key indicators of fiscal prudence (viz., deficit and debt as a percentage of GDP)
declined for the states over the years, it is important to examine the expenditure profile of the
central government and states. As evident from figure 3, the aggregate expenditure-to-GDP
ratio (all states) declined gradually until 2011–12 and started increasing in 2012–13. If we
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
Percent
Year
Combined Central State
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
Percent
Year
combined Central State
12
consider capital expenditure alone, it is evident that there has been a decline in the Union’s
capital-expenditure-to-GDP ratio from 2003–04. However, since 2002–03 the capital
expenditure of the states in relation to GDP is higher compared to the central government
(see figures 3 and 4). In other words, post-FRA, state governments have become the primary
drivers of capital spending, both for the social and economic sector, while the central
government’s capital-expenditure-to-GDP ratio continued to decline during this period. It
needs to be highlighted that in the pre-FRA period, the central government was the primary
driver of capital spending, but this is no longer true. This shift in capital spending at the state
level is an important development and one needs to examine how this shift plays out in the
medium term in terms of the composition and quality of public investment spending.
Figure 3: Total Expenditure as a Percentage of GDP
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
Percent
Year
Combined Central State
13
Figure 4: Capital Expenditure as a Percentage of GDP
Our analysis shows that the era of rule-based fiscal control witnessed a sharp reduction in the
overall fiscal imbalance at the state level. This improvement in fiscal health can be
characterized as an intertemporal reduction in both the fiscal- and revenue-deficits-to-GDP
ratios. As they evolved up to 2007–08, the fiscal positions of the state generated a revenue
surplus and brought down the gross fiscal-deficit-to-GDP ratio below the 3 percent FRA
target. This also implies that states have overadjusted their fiscal deficits. At the state level,
fiscal consolidation has been achieved through: higher state tax revenue mobilization, largely
due to introduction of a value added tax (VAT) at the state level in 2005; increased central
devolution due to the growth in federal taxes; and a reduction in the revenue- and
expenditure-to- GSDP ratios, primarily due to the decline in economic and social services
expenditures and interest burden.
11
It is argued that improved fiscal balances have also
contributed to the increase in fiscal space at the state level. Although, in the post–global
financial crisis years there was fiscal expansion at the central government level, resulting in a
sharp increase in the fiscal deficit of the central government, the states continued with fiscal
restraints and in the aggregate state fiscal deficits remained below the FRA target between
2008–09 and 2014–15 (budget estimates). However, differences were observed in the
interstate fiscal imbalance profile. Though the rate of increase of deficits varied across states,

11
It is observed that the decline in the interest burden in the last couple of years is due to the softening of
interest rates on government securities. It is also argued that measures, such as debt swap schemes in a low-
interest regime, have benefited the states in reducing the interest burden.
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
Percent
Ye a r
Combined Central State
14
most of the states were able to generate revenue surpluses and successfully reduced their
fiscal deficits below 3 percent of GSDP during the post-FRA period. It needs to be
emphasized that the states that achieved a revenue surplus and a fiscal deficit level below 3
percent of GSDP were also the ones that had a reasonably better history of fiscal management
and fiscal prudence (table 1). A comparison of the fiscal imbalance profile ex ante–FRA and
ex post–FRA is given in figures 5.1 to 5.9. In these figures states are categorized as high-,
middle-, and low-income states. Fiscal imbalance profiles for special category states are
shown in figures 5.10, 5.11, and 5.12.
12
As is evident, most states overadjusted their fiscal
deficits. Our data analysis also suggests that low-income states have adjusted their deficits
more compared to high- and middle-income states. In other words, these states have
borrowed less than the prescribed limit of borrowing under the FRAs, with exceptions in a
few states (e.g., Kerala, Punjab, and West Bengal). These three states had to borrow to
finance the deficits in their revenue accounts.

12
Special category states are the states in north east India and other hilly states in the northern part of India with
special federal fund dispensation due to their higher fiscal and cost disabilities.
15
Table 1: Major Fiscal Indicators (as a percent of GSDP)
Revenue Deficit Fiscal Deficit Primary Deficit
Average
before
FRBM
Average
after
FRBM
Average
before
FRBM
Average
after
FRBM
Average
before
FRBM
Average
after
FRBM
Group A
Goa 1.7 -0.5 4.6 2.8 1.7 0.8
Maharashtra 2.4 -0.3 4.1 1.6 2.0 -0.1
Haryana 1.4 0.5 3.3 2.3 0.9 0.9
Gujarat 3.2 0.0 5.1 2.4 2.3 0.4
Tamil Nadu 1.7 -0.2 2.8 2.0 1.0 0.4
Group B
Kerala 2.7 2.2 4.2 3.4 1.7 1.0
Punjab 3.3 2.3 4.8 3.3 1.2 0.4
Karnataka 0.9 -0.8 3.1 2.5 1.4 0.8
Andhra Pradesh 1.6 -0.4 4.1 2.4 1.3 0.5
West Bengal 4.9 2.5 5.1 3.3 1.7 0.3
Group C
Rajasthan 3.3 -0.1 5.7 2.1 2.0 -0.4
Jharkhand 1.3 -1 6.1 2.7 4.5 0.8
Chhattisgarh 0.4 -2.5 2.7 0.7 0.6 -0.4
Madhya Pradesh 2.3 -2.5 4.9 2.2 2.1 0.1
Odisha 3.7 -2.2 6.0 0.0 1.7 -1.9
Uttar Pradesh 3.0 -0.4 5.0 3.4 1.7 0.6
Biha
r
2.1 -2.6 5.6 2.2 1.2 -0.1
Special Category States
Sikkim -10.1 -6.2 5.0 1.3 1.5 -0.7
Uttarakhand 2.1 -0.7 4.7 2.7 2.2 0.6
Himachal Pradesh 5.9 -0.1 9.2 3.7 3.7 -0.5
agaland -6.1 -5.3 3.6 3.6 0.0 0.5
Tripura -0.8 -7.5 5.4 -0.1 1.7 -3.0
Mizoram 2.9 -3.3 14.5 6.4 8.3 2.0
Meghalaya -0.5 -1.6 4.3 2.7 1.8 0.9
Arunachal Pradesh -4.6 -13.5 7.8 2.9 3.2 -0.5
Jammu and Kashmir -3.2 -5.7 4.9 5.3 0.3 1.3
Manipu
r
1.8 -12.1 8.3 4.8 3.6 0.8
Assam 1.4 -1.8 3.2 0.6 0.6 -1.3
Note: The timeframe of the state-specific average differs across states, as different states introduced
their FRAs at different points in time. For details, see appendix A2.
Note: The “-” sign indicates a surplus.
Source: Reserve Bank of India Study on State Finances 2014–15

16
17
18
Our state-specific descriptive analysis of fiscal balances also suggests that the overall state-
level fiscal balance has improved with the introduction of a fiscal rule. However, state-
specific fiscal imbalances are different across states, especially with regard to revenue
deficits. A few states continued to have deficits in their revenue accounts, implying borrowed
resources were being used for financing revenue or current expenditure. On the other hand if
we consider fiscal deficits, most states remained within the prescribed 3 percent FRA target.
This descriptive analysis does not conclusively establish the exact impact of a fiscal rule on
fiscal balances, the way state-level fiscal consolidation has been achieved, or the nature of the
relationship between different state-level macro and fiscal variables. One needs to control for
such factors to examine the impact of a fiscal rule on fiscal balances and spending. The
descriptive analysis also does not help in understanding the process of fiscal adjustment in a
rule-based fiscal control regime across states. Due to multiple factors, panel data analysis,
which is well suited to the studies that deal with dynamic changes, is used to address these
issues. Our analysis used a dataset of 14 major non-special category states
13
spread over 15
years (from fiscal year 2000–01 to 2014–15) to examine the fiscal rules and public
investment spending at the state level. We have used the Arellano Bond Panel estimation.
14
THE ECONOMETRIC ESTIMATION
The final model has been defined to include two different determinants (per capita gross state
domestic product and per capita central government transfer) and two different dummies
(VAT and FRA), with the FRA dummy being the most important variable of interest.

13
These states are Andhra Pradesh, Bihar, Gujarat, Haryana, Karnataka, Kerala, Madhya Pradesh, Maharashtra,
Orissa, Punjab, Rajasthan, Tamil Nadu, Uttar Pradesh, and West Bengal. Small and/or special category states
are ignored in this study as they are overreliant on assistance from the central government. Overdependence on
transfers from the central government severely constrains the fiscal autonomy of such states, and hence, it
affects their public finance management ability.
14
Arellano and Bond (1991) suggested that if one is considering the orthogonality condition that exists between
lagged values of the dependent variable and the disturbance variable, then the additional instrument can be
obtained in the dynamic panel data model.
19
Econometrically, the model can be specified as follows:
K
i,t
= K
i,t-1
+
gpc
i.t
+
igft
i,t
+
D
1
.vat +
D
2
. fra +u
i,t
u
i,t
~ IID(0,
)
Where: K = per capita capital outlay
gpc = gross state domestic product in per capita (in nominal terms)
igft = per capita intergovernmental fiscal transfers
D
1
.vat = 0: ex ante VAT
= 1: ex post VAT
D
2
.fra = 0: ex ante FRA
= 1: ex post FRA
Table 2: Fiscal Impact on Capital Outlay
Variable Per-capita Capital Outlay
L.K
0.526
***
(5.35)
Igft
0.167
***
(6.58)
Gpc
0.00413
**
(2.52)
D
1_
VAT
164.0
***
(2.64)
D
2_
FRA
-135.6
*
(-1.91)
Const.
-34.6
(-0.88)
No of observations = 190
Wald chi2(5) = 1522.11
Prob > chi2 = 0.000
Source: Author’s computations based on Reserve Bank of India Study on State Finances
(various dates). Available at: https://rbi.org.in/scripts/AnnualPublications
Note: t-statistics in parentheses
*p < 0.1, **p<0.05, and ***p< 0.01
20
Our analysis shows that the lag of per capita capital outlay, per capita transfer (igft), and per
capita gross state domestic product (gpc) have a positive and significant impact on an
increase in per capita capital outlay, and the VAT dummy also has a positive and significant
effect on per capita capital outlay. However, we observed a negative relationship between the
FRA dummy and the capital outlay at the state level.
SPENDING INERTIA
This result is not surprising. We would like to emphasize that states in the post–FRBMA
period are extremely cautious in spending, as reflected in their overcorrection of deficits. This
has, in turn, depressed capital spending in the states. This spending inertia has also
contributed to a large accumulation of cash surplus holdings by states. The Reserve Bank of
India’s “Study on State Finances: 2011–12” observed that:
The surplus cash balances of the states stood at Rs. 852 billion
as on March 11, 2012. These cash balances get automatically
invested in the central government’s 14-day intermediate
treasury bills as well as in auction treasury bills (ATBs) where
states are non-competitive bidders, without any ceilings/
limits. Consequently, there is a spillover of the surplus
position of the states to the liquidity position of the Centre.
The build-up (and volatility) of the central government’s cash
surplus, in turn, reflects the unintended absorption of liquidity
from the banking system which poses a challenge to the
reserve bank’s monetary management.
15
The same study also pointed out that in its report submitted in fiscal year 2009–10, the 13th
Finance Commission “advised the state governments to first utilize their cash balances before
taking recourse to fresh borrowings, to finance their deficits so as to reduce the interest
burden.”
16
However, in practice, this did not happen.

15
http://rbidocs.rbi.org.in/rdocs/Publications/PDFs/7CHSF300312.pdf
16
http://rbidocs.rbi.org.in/rdocs/Publications/PDFs/7CHSF300312.pdf
21
CONCLUSIONS
Though during the post-FRA period there was a reduction in the fiscal and revenue deficits of
the states, our econometric estimates show that capital spending for public investment was
negatively related to the FRA dummy. It needs to be highlighted that a one-size-fits-all
uniform rule across states came under criticism. Since different states operated at different
levels of sustainable deficits, imposing a uniform rule implied constraining capital spending
unless large revenue surpluses were generated. Our expenditure model shows that Indian
states have contained their public investment spending to comply with a fiscal rule once the
regression has controlled for the growth of intergovernmental transfers and other state-
specific factors. However, most states have overadjusted their fiscal deficit, resulting in the
accumulation of cash surpluses. The impact of the decline in investment spending on growth
is an area for further research.
To conclude, this phenomenon of accumulation of a cash surplus under a rule-based fiscal
regime at the subnational level was addressed by the 14th Finance Commission by changing
the design of the fiscal rules. The 14th Finance Commission has proposed that for the Union
government, the fiscal deficit ceiling will be 3 percent of GDP from fiscal year 2016–17
onwards. However for the states, there is flexibility for 0.25 percent over and above 3 percent
of GSDP for a given year if the debt-to-GSDP ratio is below 25 percent. Also if the states
limit their interest obligations as a percentage of revenue receipts below 10 percent, an
additional 0.25 percent of GSDP is allowed as extra fiscal space for capital spending. States
will be eligible for these flexibilities in borrowing only if there is no revenue deficit. One
needs to see how much the 14th Finance Commission’s recommendations are going to
change state-level fiscal behavior and the utilization of borrowed resources for capital
spending within the existing federal fiscal framework of transfers.
22
APPENDIX
Table A1: Instruments and Nature of Fiscal Rule: A Cross Country Comparison
Country Year Name and Nature of
Act
Numerical
Targets
Description
USA 1986
1990
2010
2011
Gramm-Rudman-
Hollings Act (GRH)
Budget Enforcement Act
– Expenditure rule
Pay-As-You-Go
(PAYGO) Act
Balanced Budget Rule –
Expenditure based
Yes
Yes
No
No
Specified a series of annual deficits targets with
a balanced budget to be achieved in 1991 and
subsequently moved to 1993.
Annual appropriations limit adopted for
discretionary spending.
Deficit-raising policies must be financed by
other measures over a specified time period.
Exempt programs included legislation with an
“emergency” designation, Social Security, and
the Bush tax cuts for the middle class.
Discretionary spending caps were introduced.
Additional spending cuts came into effect in
March 2013. These additional cuts are expected
to reduce US$1.2 trillion over a decade with
one-half coming from defense spending and the
other half from domestic programs, excluding
Social Security, Medicaid, parts of Medicare,
and certain other entitlement programs.
Japan 1947
1997
2006
2010
Balanced Budget Rule
Fiscal Structure Reform
Act
Expenditure Rule
Fiscal Management
Strategy
No
Yes
Yes
No
Current expenditure should not exceed
domestic revenues.
Revised balance budget rule: Reduce overall
government deficit to 3 percent of GDP;
numerical targets by spending category (public
investment, Social Security).
Any major increases in expenditure or
decreases in revenue need to be accompanied
by permanent expenditure reductions/revenue-
raising measures.
Canada 1991
1998
2006
Federal Spending
Control Act
Debt Repayment Plan
Target-based Plans
Yes
No
No
C$3 billion debt reduction and limitation in
program spending except self-financing
programs.
Eliminating net general government debt by
2021 and federal debt by 2013/14
EU 1992
2005
2012
Maastricht Treaty
Stability and Growth
Pact
Golden Rule
Yes
No
Yes
Debt and deficit ceiling: 60 and 3 percent of
GDP, respectively.
Country-specific medium-term objectives are
set for structural budget balance.
Annual pace of debt reduction (no less than
1/20th of the distance between the actual debt
ratio and the 60 percent threshold) starting
three years after a country has left the current
excessive debt procedure (EDP).
23
Argentina 2000
2004
Fiscal Responsibility
Law (FRL)
Implementation of
Revised FRL
Yes
No
Balanced budget rule: Balance revenue and
expenditure excluding social and infrastructure
expenditure. Additionally, for provinces debt-
servicing costs cannot exceed 15 percent of
current revenues after transfers deduction.
Expenditure rule: Primary expenditure cannot
grow more than nominal GDP; Federal Fiscal
Responsibility Council was instated in 2000,
however its activities were suspended in 2009.
Peru 2000
2009
2013
Balanced Budget Rule
Balanced Budget Rule
Law 30099
Yes
Yes
No
Deficit ceiling for the non-financial public
sector. The ceiling was set at 2 percent of GDP
for 2000 and 2003, 1.5 percent of GDP for
2001, 2002, and from 2004–2008. Real growth
current expenditure ceiling of 2 percent (2000–
02), 3 percent (2003–08).
New limit of 2 percent for balanced budget was
set. Real growth of current expenditure limit
was at 4 percent, structural deficit limit at 1
percent of GDP.
Expenditure on maintenance of infrastructure,
goods, and services of social programs covered
by the performance-based budgeting scheme;
equipment intended for public order and
security were excluded from current
expenditure and were out of the ambit of the
stipulated limits.
Mexico 2006
2009
2013
Balanced Budget Rule –
Cash basis
Balanced Budget Rule
Expenditure Rule
No
Yes
Yes
Rule applies to the federal public sector which
includes the central government, social
security, and key public enterprises.
Status quo with exclusion of investment outlays
of the state-owned oil company, Pemex, from
the balanced-budget rule. Although sanctions
were also thought of, escape clauses also
existed.
Cap on structural current spending (SCS)
defined as current primary expenditure
including transfers to state and local
governments for capital but excluding those
outlays governed by automatic rules (pensions,
subsidies for electricity, and tax devolution);
SCS cannot grow faster than 2 percent in real
terms through 2017.
Australia 1985
1998
Expenditure Rule
Charter of Budget
Honesty Act
Yes
Yes
Expenditure Rule, Balanced Budget Rule,
Revenue Rule
Achieve budget surpluses over the medium
term; keep taxation as a share of GDP below
the level of 2007–08. Improve the
government’s net financial worth over the
medium term. Commitment to restrain real
growth in spending to 2 percent per year since
2009.
Brazil 2000 Fiscal Responsibility
Law
Yes Expenditure rule: Personnel expenditure is
limited to 50 percent of net current revenue for
the federal government, and 60 percent for
states and municipalities.
Debt rule: New borrowing must be at most
equal to public investment.
24
Cameroon 2002
2008
Balanced Budget Rule
Revised Balanced
Budget Rule
No
No
The Central African Economic and Monetary
Community (CEMAC) sets the fiscal rule.
Structural fiscal balance and non-oil basic fiscal
balance, respectively, as a percentage of
nominal GDP should be in balance/surplus.
Indonesia 1967
2004
Balance Budget Rule
Debt Rule
Yes
Yes
The consolidated national and local
government budget deficit is limited to 3
percent of GDP in any given year as per State
Finance Law and Government Regulation
23/2003.
Central and local government debt should not
exceed 60 percent of GDP.
India 2004
2009
Budget Balance Rule
Revised Budget Balance
Rule
Yes
No
Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management
Act (FRBMA): reduce the fiscal deficit to 3
percent of GDP by 2008.
FRBMA was suspended in 2009. All states
barring three had met the targets; however, the
central government had not achieved the
stipulated targets.
Kenya 1997 Debt-based Rule Yes The debt-to-GDP ratio in net present value
terms should be below 40 percent and/or total
nominal debt to be below 45 percent of GDP (a
goal of their medium-term debt-management
strategy); government overdraft at the central
bank is limited to 5 percent of previous year
revenue; revenue should be at 21–22 percent of
GDP.
New
Zealand
1994 Fiscal Responsibility
Act
The government needs to run operating
surpluses annually until “prudent” debt levels
are achieved. Once these are achieved on
average total operating balances should not
exceed total operating revenues. In case of
deviations from the principles, the government
needs to specify the reasons; specific fiscal
targets should be set by the government for
three-year and ten-year objectives, typically in
percent of GDP.
Russia 2007
2009
2012
Balanced Budget Rule
Oil-price-based Fiscal
Rule
Russia’s legal fiscal framework relied on the
non-oil balance as a key fiscal indicator. The
budget included a long-term non-oil deficit
target of 4.7 percent of GDP. This was
suspended in April 2009 as a result of the
global financial crisis, and formally abolished
in 2012.
The rule sets a ceiling on expenditures (oil
revenue at the “base” oil price, plus all non-oil
revenues, plus a net borrowing limit of 1
percent of GDP). Once the reserve fund reaches
this threshold, at least half of excess oil
revenues should go to the National Wealth
Fund, while the remaining resources would be
channeled to the budget to finance
infrastructure and other priority projects.
25
Singapore 1991
1995
2008
Debt Rule
Balanced Budget Rule
(BBR)
Amendment to BBR
Spending to not exceed 50 percent of net
investment returns on reserves held by the
Monetary Authority of Singapore (MAS) and
the Government of Singapore Investment
Corporation (GIC).
Budget to be balanced across government term
of office (usually 5 years).
The rule was amended in 2008 to change the
benchmark to “expected long-term net real
investment returns.”
26
Table A2: Date of FRBMA and Period for Calculating Average
Sl. No State
Month of
FRBM
Period before FRBM Period after FRBM
1 Karnataka Sep 2002 1992–93 to 2001–02 2003–04 to 2012–13
2 Tamil Nadu May 2003 1994–95 to 2002–03 2004–05 to 2012–13
3 Kerala Aug 2003 1994–95 to 2002–03 2004–05 to 2012–13
4 Punjab Oct 2003 1994–95 to 2002–03 2004–05 to 2012–13
5 Uttar Pradesh Feb 2004 1994–95 to 2002–03 2004–05 to 2012–13
6 Gujarat Mar 2005 1998–99 to 2004–05 2006–07 to 2012–13
7 Mahrashtra Apr 2005 1998–99 to 2004–05 2006–07 to 2012–13
8 Himachal Pradesh Apr 2005 1998–99 to 2004–05 2006–07 to 2012–13
9 Rajasthan May 2005 1998–99 to 2004–05 2006–07 to 2012–13
10 Madhya Pradesh May 2005 1998–99 to 2004–05 2006–07 to 2012–13
11 Andhra Pradesh Jun 2005 1998–99 to 2004–05 2006–07 to 2012–13
12 Odisha Jun 2005 1998–99 to 2004–05 2006–07 to 2012–13
13 Tripura Jun 2005 1998–99 to 2004–05 2006–07 to 2012–13
14 Haryana Jul 2005 1998–99 to 2004–05 2006–07 to 2012–13
15 Manipur Aug 2005 1998–99 to 2004–05 2006–07 to 2012–13
16 Chhattishgarh Sep 2005 2000–01 to 2004–05 2006–07 to 2012–13
17 Assam Sep 2005 1998–99 to 2004–05 2006–07 to 2012–13
18 Uttarakhand Oct 2005 1998–99 to 2004–05 2006–07 to 2012–13
19 Arunanchal Pradesh Mar 2006 1998–99 to 2004–05 2006–07 to 2012–13
20 Meghalaya Mar 2006 1998–99 to 2004–05 2006–07 to 2012–13
21 Bihar Apr 2006 2001–02 to 2005–06 2007–08 to 2012–13
22 Goa May 2006 2001–02 to 2005–06 2007–08 to 2012–13
23 Jammu and Kashmir Aug 2006 2001–02 to 2005–06 2007–08 to 2012–13
24 Mizoram Oct 2006 2001–02 to 2005–06 2007–08 to 2012–13
25 Jharkhand May 2007 2002–03 to 2006–07 2008–09 to 2012–13
26 Nagaland Jan 2010 2006–07 to 2008–09 2010–11 to 2012–13
27 West Bengal Jul 2010 2008–09 to 2009–10 2011–12 to 2012–13
28 Sikkim Sep 2010 2008–09 to 2009–10 2011–12 to 2012–13
Source: Reserve Bank of India Study on State Finances, 2014–15
27
REFERENCES
Alesina, A., and T. Bayoumi. 1996. “The costs and benefits of fiscal rules: evidence from US
states.” NBER Working Paper No. 5614. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Alt, J.E., and R.C. Lowry. 1994. “Divided Government, Fiscal Institutions, and Budget
Deficits: Evidence from the States.” American Political Science Review 88(04): 811–
28.
Bertelsmann, J.I. 2013. “Independent Fiscal Institutions in the Face of Rising Public
Indebtedness.” In George Kopits (ed.), Restoring Public Debt Sustainability: The Role
of Independent Fiscal Institutions. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Buchanan, J.M., and R.E. Wagner. 1977. Democracy in deficit: the political legacy of Lord
Keynes. New York: Academic Press.
Chakraborty, P., and B.B. Dash. 2013. “Fiscal Reforms, Fiscal Rule and Development
Spending: How Indian States have performed?” National Institute of Public Finance
and Policy Working Paper 2013–122. New Delhi: National Institute of Public Finance
and Policy.
Feld, L.P., and G. Kirchgässner. 2006. “Fiscal Policy and Direct Democracy: Institutional
Design Determines Outcomes.” In A.F. Ott and R.J. Cebula (eds.) The Elgar
Companion to Public Economics: Empirical Public Economics. Cheltenham: Edward
Elgar.
Finance Commission. 2004. “Report of the Twelfth Finance Commission.” New Delhi:
Finance Commission.
Finance Commission. 2009. “Report of the Thirteenth Finance Commission” New Delhi:
Finance Commission.
Finance Commission. 2014. “Report of the Fourteenth Finance Commission” New Delhi:
Finance Commission.
Gupta, S., B. Clemens, A. Pivovarsky, and E.R. Tiongson. 2003. “Foreign Aid and Revenue
Response: Does the Composition of Aid Matter?” IMF Working Paper 03/176,
September. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
Hatchondo, J.C., L. Martinez, and F. Roch. 2012. “Fiscal rules and the sovereign default
premium.” IMF Working Paper 12/130. Washington, DC: International Monetary
Fund.
Khemani, S., and W. Wane. 2008. “Populist Fiscal Policy.” World Bank Policy Research
Working Paper, 4762. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Kopits, G. 2013. Restoring public debt sustainability: the role of independent fiscal
institutions. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
28
Kopits, G. 2001. “Fiscal rules: Useful Policy Framework or Unnecessary Ornament?” IMF
Working Paper, WP/1/145. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
Kopits, G., and S.A. Symansky. 1998. “Fiscal Policy Rules.” IMF Occasional Paper 162.
Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
Krogstrup, S., and S. Wälti. 2008. “Do fiscal rules cause budgetary outcomes?” Public
Choice 136(1–2): 123–38.
Kydland, F. E., and E.C. Prescott. 1977. “Rules rather than discretion: The inconsistency of
optimal plans.” The Journal of Political Economy 85(3): 473–91.
Manasse, P. 2007. “Deficit limits and fiscal rules for dummies.” IMF Staff Papers 455–473.
Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
Mavrotas, G., and B. Ouattara. 2003. “Aid Disaggregation, Endogenous Aid, and the Public
Sector in Aid–Recipient Economies: Evidence from Cote d’Ivoire.” Working Paper
Series UNU–WIDER Research Paper. Helsinki: World Institute for Development
Economic Research (UNU–WIDER).
Milesi–Ferretti, G.M., and K. Moriyama. 2004. “Fiscal adjustment in EU countries: a balance
sheet approach.” IMF Working Paper, WP/04/143. Washington, DC: International
Monetary Fund
Pappa, E., and V. Vassilatos. 2007. “The unbearable tightness of being in a monetary union:
Fiscal restrictions and regional stability.” European Economic Review 51(6): 1492–
1513.
Poplawski Ribeiro, M., R. Beetsma, and A. Schabert. 2008. “A Comparison of Debt and
Primary–deficit Constraints.” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 6897. Washington, DC:
Center for Economic and Policy Research.
Poterba, J.M. 1995. “Balanced budget rules and fiscal policy: Evidence from the
states.” National Tax Journal 48(3): 329–36.
Rao, M.G., and P. Chakraborty. 2007, “Multilateral adjustment lending to states in India:
Hastening fiscal correction or softening the budget constraint?” The Journal of
International Trade and Economic Development 3(15): 335–57.
Schaltegger, C.A. 2001. “The Effects of Federalism and Democracy: Evidence from Swiss
Subnational Jurisdictions.” ifo–Studien 47: 145–62.
Simone, A.S., and P. Topalova. 2009, “India’s Experience with Fiscal Rules: An Evaluation
and The Way Forward.” IMF Working Paper 09/175. Washington, DC: International
Monetary Fund.
Spaventa, L. 1987. “The growth of public debt: sustainability, fiscal rules, and monetary
rules.” IMF Staff Papers 374–399. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
29
Tellier, G., and L.M. Imbeau. 2004. “Budget deficits and surpluses in the Canadian
provinces: a pooled analysis.” Paper presented at the annual conference of the
European Public Choice Society, Berlin. Available at:
http://www.diw.de/documents/dokumentenarchiv/17/41570/paper–246.pdf
Von Hagen, J., and I. Harden. 1996. “Budget processes and commitment to fiscal discipline.”
IMF Working Paper WP/96/78. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
World Bank. 2004. “State Fiscal Reforms in India: Progress and Prospects.” A World Bank
Report, No. 28849-IN. New Delhi: Macmillan India, Ltd.
World Bank. 1992. “Adjustment Lending and Mobilization of Public and Private Resources
for Growth.” World Bank Policy and Research Series 22. Washington, DC: World
Bank.